Homework 3. Due: Mon 9th December

Similar documents
Homework 3: Asymmetric Information

Homework Nonlinear Pricing with Three Types. 2. Downward Sloping Demand I. November 15, 2010

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Practice Problems. U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

PhD Qualifier Examination

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Auction Theory Lecture Note, David McAdams, Fall Bilateral Trade

Problem Set 2: Sketch of Solutions

Independent Private Value Auctions

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Practice Problems. w U(w, e) = p w e 2,

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Homework 1: Basic Moral Hazard

The Myerson Satterthwaite Theorem. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Answer for Q1. a i : (b) So P I. P I i=1 e i: This can be regarded as the demand of the representative consumer with utility function P L

Auctions in the wild: Bidding with securities. Abhay Aneja & Laura Boudreau PHDBA 279B 1/30/14

Where do securities come from

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

(v 50) > v 75 for all v 100. (d) A bid of 0 gets a payoff of 0; a bid of 25 gets a payoff of at least 1 4

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Lecture 3: Information in Sequential Screening

Basic Assumptions (1)

Relational Incentive Contracts

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Strategy -1- Strategic equilibrium in auctions

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Day 3. Myerson: What s Optimal

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Auctioning a Single Item. Auctions. Simple Auctions. Simple Auctions. Models of Private Information. Models of Private Information

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Game Theory Solutions to Problem Set 11

Auctions 1: Common auctions & Revenue equivalence & Optimal mechanisms. 1 Notable features of auctions. use. A lot of varieties.

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Up till now, we ve mostly been analyzing auctions under the following assumptions:

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Optimal Auctions with Ambiguity

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization

Strategy -1- Strategy

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

In Diamond-Dybvig, we see run equilibria in the optimal simple contract.

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution.

Microeconomics Comprehensive Exam

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Optimal Mixed Spectrum Auction

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

1 Theory of Auctions. 1.1 Independent Private Value Auctions

CHAPTER 1: Moral Hazard with Single Agent

MFE Macroeconomics Week 8 Exercises

1 The principal-agent problems

EXTRA PROBLEMS. and. a b c d

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Debt Contracts. Ram Singh. April 1, Department of Economics. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Debt Contracts April 1, / 14

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

The Benefits of Sequential Screening

Lecture 7: Ex-ante Vs Ex-post Contracts

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

Revenue Management with Forward-Looking Buyers

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

Extensive-Form Games with Imperfect Information

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Two-Dimensional Bayesian Persuasion

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

Implicit Collusion in Non-Exclusive Contracting under Adverse Selection

1 Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Instructor: Songzi Du

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions.

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty

Optimal Incentive Contract with Costly and Flexible Monitoring

Characterization of the Optimum

Debt Contracts and Cooperative Improvements

JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e

Transcription:

Homework 3 Due: Mon 9th December 1. Public Goods Provision A firm is considering building a public good (e.g. a swimming pool). There are n agents in the economy, each with IID private value θ i [0, 1]. Agents valuations have density f(θ) and distribution F (θ). Assume that MR(θ) = θ 1 F (θ) f(θ) is increasing in θ. The cost of the swimming pool is cn, where c > 0. First suppose the government passes a law that says the firm cannot exclude people from entering the swimming pool. A mechanism thus consists of a build decision P (θ 1,..., θ n ) [0, 1] and a payment by each agent t i (θ 1,..., θ n ) R. The mechanism must be individually rational and incentive compatible. [Note: When showing familiar results your derivation can be heuristic.] (a) Consider an agent with type θ i, whose utility is given by θ i P t i Derive her utility in a Bayesian incentive compatible mechanism. (b) Given an build decision P ( ), derive the firm s profits. (c) What is the firm s optimal build decision? (d) Show that E[MR(θ)] = 0. (e) Show that as n, so the probability of provision goes to zero. [You might wish to use the Chebyshev inequality, which says that Pr( Z E[Z] α) Var(Z) for a random variable α 2 Z.] Next, suppose the firm can exclude agents. A mechanism now consists of a build decision P (θ 1,..., θ n ) [0, 1], a participation decision for each agent x i (θ 1,..., θ n ) [0, 1] and a pay- 1

ment t i (θ 1,..., θ n ) R. Agent i s utility is now given by θ i x i P t i The cost is still given by cn, where n is the number of agents in the population. (f) Solve for the firm s optimal build decision P ( ) and participation rule x i ( ). (g) Suppose n. Show there exists a cutoff c such that the firm provides the pool with probability one if c < c, and with probability zero if c > c. 2. Costly State Verification There is a risk neutral entrepreneur E who has a project with privately observed return y with density f(y) on [0, Y ]. The project requires investment I < E[y] from an outside creditor C. A contract is defined by a pair (s(y), B(y)) consisting of payment and verification decision. If an agent reports y they pay s(y) y and are verified if B(y) = 1 and not verified if B(y) = 0. If the creditor verifies E they pay exogenously given cost c and get to observe E s type. The game is as follows: E chooses (s(y), B(y)) to raise I from a competitive financial market. Output y is realised. E claims the project yields ŷ. If B(ŷ) = 0 then E pays s(ŷ) and is not verified. If B(ŷ) = 1 then C pays c and observes E s true type. If they are telling the truth they pay s(y); if not, then C can take everything. Payoffs. E gets y s(y), while C gets s(y) cb(y) I. (a) Show that a contract is incentive compatible if and only if there exists a D such that s(y) = D when B(y) = 0 and s(y) D when B(y) = 1. 2

Consider E s problem: max E[y s(y)] s(y),b(y) s.t. s(y) y (MAX) E[s(y) cb(y) I] 0 (IR) s(y) D y B V (IC1) s(y) = D y B V (IC2) where B V is the verification region (where B(y) = 1). (b) Show that constraint (IR) must bind at the optimum. [Hint: Proof by contradiction.] Now E s problem becomes min E[cB(y)] s(y),b(y) s.t. (MAX), (IC1), (IC2) E[s(y) cb(y) I] = 0 (IR) (c) Show that any optimal contract (s(y), B(y)) has a verification range of the form B V = [0, D] for some D. [Hint: Proof by contradiction.] (d) Show that any optimal contract (s(y), B(y)) sets s(y) = y when B(y) = 1. [Hint: Proof by contradiction.] (e) A contract is thus characterised by D. Which D maximises E s utility? Can you give a financial interpretation to this contract? 3. Ironing Consider the continuous type price discrimination problem from class, where the principal chooses q(θ) to maximise E[q(θ)MR(θ) c(q(θ))] subject to q(θ) increasing in θ. 3

For v [0, 1], let H(v) = 0 MR(F 1 (x))dx be the expected marginal revenue up to θ = F 1 (v). Let H(v) be the highest convex function under H(v). Then define MR(θ) by H(v) = Finally, let (θ) = H(F (θ)) H(F (θ)). 1 0 MR(F 1 (x))dx (a) Argue that (θ) > 0 implies MR(θ) is flat. Also argue that (θ) = (θ) = 0. (b) Since q(θ) is an increasing function, show that θ E[q(θ)MR(θ) c(q(θ))] = E[q(θ)MR(θ) c(q(θ))] (θ)dq(θ) θ (c) Derive the profit maximising allocation q(θ). 4. Negotiations and Auctions Assume all bidders have IID private valuations v i F (v) with support [V, V ]. Define marginal revenue as MR(v) = v 1 F (v) f(v) (a) Show that E[MR(v)] = V. (b) In terms of marginal revenues, what is the revenue from 2 bidders with no reservation price? (c) Let the sellers valuation be v 0. In terms of marginal revenue, what is the revenue from 1 bidder and a reservation price? (d) Assume V v 0, i.e. all bidders are serious. How is revenue affected if one bidder is swapped for a reservation price? 1 Note, it is important that we take the convex hull in quantile space. If we use θ space, then (θ) > 0 implies MR(θ)f(θ) is flat, which is not particularly useful. 4

5. Dynamic Mechanism Design A firm sells to a customer over T = 2 periods. There is no discounting. The consumer s per-period utility is u = θq p where q R is the quantity of the good, and p is the price. The agent s type θ {θ L, θ H } is privately known. In period 1, Pr(θ = θ H ) = µ. In period 2, the agent s type may change. With probability α > 1/2, her type remains the same; with probability 1 α her type switches (so a high type becomes a low type, or a low type becomes a high type). The firm chooses a mechanism to maximise the sum of its profits. The per-period profit is given by π = p 1 2 q2 A mechanism consists of period 1 allocations q L, q H, period 2 allocations q LL, q LH, q HL, q HH, and corresponding prices, where q LH is the quantity allocated to an agent who declares L in period 1 and H in period 2. (a) Consider period t = 2. Fix the first period type, θ. Assume in period 2 that the lowtype s (IR) constraint binds, the high type s (IC) constraint binds and we can ignore the other constraints. Characterize the second period rents obtained by the agents, U θl and U θh, as a function of {q LL, q LH, q HL, q HH } (b) Consider period t = 1. Assume the low-type s (IR) constraint binds, the high type s (IC) constraint binds and we can ignore the other constraints. Derive the lifetime rents obtained by the agents, U L and U H, as a function of {q L, q H, q LL, q LH, q HL, q HH }. (c) Derive the firm s total expected profits. (d) Assume the firm does not want to exclude, i.e. that := θ H θ L is sufficiently small. Derive the profit-maximizing allocations {q L, q H, q LL, q LH, q HL, q HH }. In particular, show that q HL is first-best. Can you provide an intuition for this result? (Bonus) Suppose T is arbitrary. Can you derive the form of the optimal mechanism? 5

6. Robust Trading Mechanisms. Myerson and Satterthwaite (1982) characterize the set of Bayesian (IC) and Interim (IR) mechanisms with balanced budgets. What allocations could we achieve if we insisted that the mechanism be robust to agents holding a range of beliefs about their opponent? There is a buyer with value v [0, 1] and seller with cost c [0, 1]. A mechanism consists of a allocation q(v, c) {0, 1} and a transfer t(v, c) 0. The assumption that q {0, 1} will make part (d) easier. Payoffs are U B (v, c) = q(v, c)v t(v, c) U S (v, c) = t(v, c) q(v, c)c Rather than specify beliefs about their opponent s payoffs, we insist on ex-post (IC): q(v, c)v t(v, c) q(ˆv, c)v t(ˆv, c) t(v, c) q(v, c)c t(v, ĉ) q(v, ĉ)c (ICB) (ICS) and ex-post (IR) q(v, c)v t(v, c) 0 t(v, c) q(v, c)c 0 (IRB) (IRS) (a) Show that the (IR) constraints imply q(v, c) = t(v, c) = 0 if v < c. To avoid trivialities, we hereafter assume that v c. (b) Show that q(v, c) is increasing in v and decreasing in c. (c) Using the envelope theorem, show that (ICB) and (ICS) and part (a) imply q(v, c)v t(v, c) = t(v, c) q(v, c)c = c c q(x, c)dx q(v, x)dx 6

And therefore that q(v, c)(v c) = c [q(x, c) + q(v, x)]dx (ICBS) (d) Show that (ICBS) implies that any implementable mechanism take the form of a posted price mechanism. That is, there exists a price p such that q(v, c) = 1 iff v p c To prove this, it s easiest to use a graphical approach. Since allocations are bang-bang, one can plot the trade region in (v, c) space. Under a price mechanism, it should look like a rectangular block. With any other trade region, there should be a point that contradicts (ICBS). 7