Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring?

Similar documents
Market Liquidity and Performance Monitoring The main idea The sequence of events: Technology and information

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Imperfect Competition, Information Asymmetry, and Cost of Capital

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Moral Hazard: Dynamic Models. Preliminary Lecture Notes

Indexing and Price Informativeness

REPORTING BIAS AND INFORMATIVENESS IN CAPITAL MARKETS WITH NOISE TRADERS

Strategic Trading of Informed Trader with Monopoly on Shortand Long-Lived Information

Stock Price, Earnings, and Book Value in Managerial Performance Measures

Market based compensation, trading and liquidity

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Solution Guide to Exercises for Chapter 4 Decision making under uncertainty

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

D.1 Sufficient conditions for the modified FV model

Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Algorithmic and High-Frequency Trading

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information

Research Article Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

Accounting Conservatism, Market Liquidity and Informativeness of Asset Price: Implications on Mark to Market Accounting

Market based compensation, trading and liquidity

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Managerial risk reduction, incentives and firm value

Executive Compensation and Short-Termism

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

FIN 6160 Investment Theory. Lecture 7-10

Internet Appendix to. Glued to the TV: Distracted Noise Traders and Stock Market Liquidity

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Liquidity and the cost of market-based compensation in informationally efficient markets

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Liquidity and Asset Prices in Rational Expectations Equilibrium with Ambiguous Information

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

BACKGROUND RISK IN THE PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama. and. Paul D. Thistle University of Nevada Las Vegas

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

Liquidity and Asset Prices: A Unified Framework

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Insider Trading in Sequential Auction Markets with Risk-aversion and Time-discounting

Characterization of the Optimum

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LIQUIDITY AND ASSET PRICES: A UNIFIED FRAMEWORK. Dimitri Vayanos Jiang Wang

Financial Economics: Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012

A Model of Portfolio Delegation and Strategic Trading

Public Information and Effi cient Capital Investments: Implications for the Cost of Capital and Firm Values

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

A Market Microsructure Theory of the Term Structure of Asset Returns

Liquidity, Asset Price, and Welfare

Moral Hazard. Two Performance Outcomes Output is denoted by q {0, 1}. Costly effort by the agent makes high output more likely.

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

Risk Aversion, Strategic Trading and Mandatory Public Disclosure

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

Dynamic Asset Pricing Models: Recent Developments

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

Technical Analysis, Liquidity Provision, and Return Predictability

Enhancing Insurer Value Via Reinsurance Optimization

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Insider trading with partially informed traders

trading ambiguity: a tale of two heterogeneities

Pricing Prices. Alex Boulatov and Martin Dierker C.T. Bauer College of Business, University of Houston, Houston, TX March 1, 2007.

Optimizing Portfolios

Optimal Credit Limit Management

Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets

An estimated model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints

Background Risk and Trading in a Full-Information Rational Expectations Economy

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013

Growth Options, Incentives, and Pay-for-Performance: Theory and Evidence

An Introduction to Market Microstructure Invariance

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

A New Informativeness Principle: Managerial Incentives Decline in Stock Price Informativness * Version: May 24, 2012 Brandon Chen. Peter L.

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Aquaculture Technology and the Sustainability of Fisheries

Specific Knowledge and Input- vs. Output-Based Incentives. Michael Raith University of Rochester and CEPR

Transcription:

Why Do Agency Theorists Misinterpret Market Monitoring? Peter L. Swan ACE Conference, July 13, 2018, Canberra UNSW Business School, Sydney Australia July 13, 2018 UNSW Australia, Sydney, Australia 1 / 24

Introduction Separation of ownership and control is the main governance problem facing the modern corporation (Adam Smith, 1776, Berle and Means, 1932, Jensen and Meckling, 1976); With no one to care for passive outside investors, large and liquid companies should not exist. I hypothesize that informed speculators fulfill this role by monitoring management; Indeed, in the managers optimal contract, I show that pay sensitivity (inside ownership) must fall with more informative stock prices and scale, which is what one observes; To establish my case, I identify the reasons why the extant literature mistakenly believes that incentives move in the opposite direction. Jensen and Murphy (1990) show that empirically, incentives decline drastically with firm size. 2 / 24

Model Set-Up In common with Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) (HT), the model has three dates, an initial date, t = 0, in which the firm is founded by a risk-neutral insider, and the appointed risk-averse manager signs his contract (not subject to renegotiation). The manager makes effort choice according to his contractual incentives. Risk-neutral speculators trade on an imperfect signal of the managers effort with the stock price determined at date t = 1. At the final date, t = 2, the firm is liquidated with gross proceeds, π, used to compensate the manager Proceeds become: π = e + θ, (1) where e is the actual level of effort, and the intrinsic volatility in the stock price, θ N (0, σ 2 θ ). 3 / 24

The Speculator s Problem, continued Each speculator in receipt of the same imperfect signal, η, and subject to a normally distributed observational error, η N (0, σ 2 η). Each speculator can reduce the observational error by reducing the error variance, σ 2 η, with a fixed informational cost c I = g(1/σ 2 η), The function g(1/σ 2 η) is increasing in 1/σ 2 η and convex, for example, the quadratic function, c I = (1/2)c η (1/σ 2 η) 2, with a positive constant, c η, and where the volatility, σ 2 η, is understood to fixed at its optimal value, σ 2 η, with the accent no longer shown. 4 / 24

The Speculator s Problem Liquidity is provided by noise trader demand given by ỹ N (0, σ 2 y ). These traders do not receive an informative signal and are not strategic. The market makers linear pricing rule: p( q) = α Ap( q) + λ q, (2) where p( q) is stock price, coefficient α intercept on the price axis, q signed order flow that alters price at the rate λ, representing Kyle s lambda measure of illiquidity. A represents the magnitude of the managers stock appreciation right. Grossed-up stock price equation: p ( q) = α + λ q (1 + A). (3) 5 / 24

The Speculator s Problem, cont. Each of the n strategic traders conjectures a linear trading strategy: x i ( s i ) = β ( s i α), i = 1,..., n, (4) Where the accent on x i indicates the optimum solution, and β represents the positive coefficient of trader aggressiveness. Only the total signed order flow is visible to the market maker, q = nx i ( s i ) + ỹ = nβ ( s i ) + ỹ. Order-flow is dependent on the sum of actions of all n strategic traders plus noise trader demand. σ y β = ( ) n 1 2 σ 2 θ + ση 2 1. (5) 2 6 / 24

Solution to Optimisation Problem HTs (p.691) stock price informativeness coefficient, µ, generalized to multiple informed traders, becomes: σ 2 θ µ λnβ = n ( n + 1 σ 2 θ + ση) 2 1. (6) The first proposition can now be stated: Proposition Stock price informativeness, µ λnβ, is increasing in the number of informed speculators and improvements (i.e., reductions) in the speculators forecast error. As the volatility of the speculator s forecast error approaches infinity, the informativeness of the stock price approaches zero. 7 / 24

Derivation of Kyle s Lambda and Stock Price Kyles lambda measure of illiquidity becomes: λ = nβσθ 2 (nβ) 2 ( σθ 2 + ). (7) σ2 η + σ 2 y Evaluating the grossed-up linear pricing rule incorporating the managers stock appreciation right allocation, Ap, yields: [ ] α + λ q q = q p ( q) = E 1 + A 8 / 24

Stock Price Hence: p ( q) = 1 1 + A { } Cov (α + λ q, q) E (α + λ q) + [ q E ( q)]. Var ( q) (8) Hence, on simplification: [ ] p ( q) = 1 nβσθ 2 ē + 1 + A n 2 β ( 2 σθ 2 + ) ( q), (9) σ2 η + σ 2 y where, once again, ē = α represents the managers equilibrium action. 9 / 24

Derivation of Price On solving equations (5) and (9) for β by eliminating λ, I obtain the representative partially-informed traders demand: ( ) σ ( ) y x = β e + θ + η ē ( ) n 1 2 σ 2 θ + ση 2 1 e + θ + η ē. 2 (10) Kyles lambda, specified by equation (7), becomes, λ = σ 2 θ n 1 2 σ y (n + 1) ( σ 2 θ + σ2 η ) 1, (11) 2 10 / 24

The Model: Theory of Managerial Incentives The manager faces a standard linear incentive contract with income, I = W + Ap, (12) Fixed wage W, plus stock appreciation rights Ap, where p is the stock price and A is the incentive weight; There are n 1 partially informed homogenous strategic traders (speculators); These subject to a normally distributed observational error, η N (0, σ 2 η) The firm is naturally risky: θ N (0, σθ 2 ) and λ, represents Kyle s lambda measure of illiquidity Stock price informativeness, µ, is: σ 2 θ µ λnβ = n ( n + 1 σ 2 θ + ση) 2 1; (13) 11 / 24

- 12 / 24

Stock price informativeness is represented by the product of n, informed trader aggressiveness, β, and Kyle s Lambda, λ: Stock price is increasing in director effort, e, at the rate µ 1+A < 1, i.e., with: p = 1 [ ( (1 µ) ē + µ e + (1 + A) θ ) ] + η + λỹ. (14) Inside shareholder maximizes the expected liquidation value of the firm, E [ π] = ē = A 1+A Max A 1+A µ c A µ E [I ]. (15) 1 + A c 13 / 24

Contractual weight given by: 1 Ā = µ 1 + γcσθ 2, (16) with the incentive weight, Ā, unambiguously falling in informativeness, µ; This is because the optimal contract must minimize product of volatility coming from informative signal and from noise; Proposition The manager/director s pay sensitivity with respect to stock price, Ā, always falls with increased stock price informativeness, µ. Additionally, a higher CARA risk coefficient, γ, greater productivity uncertainty for given stock price informativeness, θ, and higher effort cost, c, all reduce managerial pay-for-performance sensitivity, Ā. The solution to the model, is illustrated in Figure 1. The figure shows the lowering of the equilibrium values of the directors pay for performance sensitivity as stock price informativeness increases. 14 / 24

15 / 24

Since equilibrium effort is: ē = Ā µ 1 + Ā c = 1 ( µ ) µ + γcσθ 2, (17) c a rise in informativeness increases effort despite the fall in incentives. The directors expected pay is equal in value to half the value of the effort put in: E [I ] = 1 ( ) 2 Ā µ ( ) µ + γcσ 2 1 2 1 + Ā c θ = (18) 2ē, Hence expected pay is increasing in informativeness, µ as compensation for additional effort. Equilibrium stock price is: p = Ā ( ) µ 2 1 + Ā c ē µ 1 + γcσ2 θ µ + γcσθ 2 Hence stock price is also increasing in the degree of informativeness.. (19) 16 / 24

Where did Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) (HT) go wrong? HT make identical assumptions to mine but reach opposite conclusion-incentives must always rise, not fall, with information; HT begin by mistakenly attempting to base a contact on stock price when the manager s effort is already at its optimum level; They then mistook the incentive weight in their normalized contract for actual incentive contract weight that they began with; They chose a new incentive weight because their aim was to maximize the signal-to-noise ratio based on an idealized normalized stock price free of the contaminating effect of the equilibrium contract weight itself; 17 / 24

Where did Holmstrom and Tirole (1993) (HT) go wrong? Continued HT began with a false belief that agency theory is about maximizing the signal to noise ratio (Holmstrom (1979); By increasing the incentive weight when signal stronger, they give more weight to the signal when it is stronger; HT begin by correctly deriving the actual stock price volatility, but fail to notice it is the product of volatility due to information in the stock price and volatility due to noise; Aim of the inside shareholder (principal) is to minimize the product of these two sources of volatility as manager has to be compensated for volatility; HT s incentive weight turns out to move in precisely the opposite direction, up not down, in response to information in stock price. 18 / 24

Does HT s error matter in 2018? Yes. A generation of economists have been taught false doctrine that information in stock price implies large liquid stocks must have high inside ownership but actually mostly have negligible ownership; Means that existence of the modern corporation remains a mystery; Obvious: once error corrected the existence of the modern corporation must be due to market monitoring; Private equity has nearly all the features of public equity but much smaller because there is no stock price and hence no market monitoring. 19 / 24

HT s Approach HT devote much of their analysis to a normalized performance measure, z, z (1 + A) p (1 µ) e, (20) µ with z = e + θ + η + 1 nβ ỹ, Variance of z is given by: var (z) = (1 + n) n ( σ 2 θ + ση 2 ) σ 2 θ µ, (21) with (1+n) n = 2 when n = 1. σ2 θ µ represents the noise-to-signal ratio in the normalized price by construction, equation (??) shows, volatility is given by the product of noise, σ 2 θ, and information, µ. 20 / 24

The manager s income becomes: I = Ap + W = sµ E(z) + d, (22) where the fixed wage, W = d sµē (1 µ) µ, and expected normalized price equals equilibrium effort, E(z) = ē. Variance of managerial income: var(i ) = b 2 var(z) = b2 σ 2 θ µ = (sµ)2 σ2 θ µ = s2 µσ 2 θ, (23) where HT (p.692, equation (20)) denote incentive weight for normalized contract by b sµ 21 / 24

The manager maximizes his expected income net of his (quadratic) effort cost: Max E [I ] 1 e [0, ) 2 ce2 = d + sµe 1 2 ce2, (24) same solution ē = sµ c. Max s HT s equilibrium effort: sµ c E [I ] = sµ c s2 µ [( )] µ + ρcσ 2 2c θ, (25) ē = b c, (26) Informativeness appears to have no effect on the equilibrium level of effort; 22 / 24

Equation(25), yields: b sµ = µ µ + ρcσθ 2, (27) HT s incentive weight, d b dµ > 0. HT (p.693, equations (22a) to (22c)) justify their program and focus on their assumed incentive weight, b, on the grounds that it minimizes the noise-to-signal ratio, b2 σθ 2 µ, given in equation (23) above. At its face value and contrary to my Proposition??, HT (pp. 693-694 and equation (24)) conclude that the manager s actual incentive weight (which they mistakenly treat as their normalized incentive sensitivity parameter, b ), is always increasing, not diminishing, in stock price informativeness. 23 / 24

24 / 24