Herding and Contrarian Behavior in Financial Markets

Similar documents
Herding and Contrarian Behavior in Financial Markets

Discussion Paper Series. Herding and Contrarian Behavior in Financial Markets : An Experimental Analysis. Andreas Park & Daniel Sgroi

Bid-Ask Spreads and Volume: The Role of Trade Timing

Social learning and financial crises

Essays on Herd Behavior Theory and Criticisms

Cascades in Experimental Asset Marktes

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Herding and Contrarianism in a Financial Trading Experiment with Endogenous Timing

Herd Behavior and Contagion in Financial Markets

Sequential Financial Market Trading: The Role of Endogenous Timing

Bubbles and Crashes. Jonathan Levin. October 2003

Herd Behavior in Financial Markets: An Experiment with Financial Market Professionals

Herd Behavior and Contagion in Financial Markets

Supplementary Appendix for Liquidity, Volume, and Price Behavior: The Impact of Order vs. Quote Based Trading not for publication

Transaction Costs and Informational Cascades in Financial Markets

Herd Behavior in Financial Markets: A Field Experiment with Financial Market Professionals

New product launch: herd seeking or herd. preventing?

Inside Outside Information

Efficiency and Herd Behavior in a Signalling Market. Jeffrey Gao

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Irrational Exuberance or Value Creation: Feedback Effect of Stock Currency on Fundamental Values

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

Internet Trading Mechanisms and Rational Expectations

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCIAL CRISES AS HERDS: OVERTURNING THE CRITIQUES. V. V. Chari Patrick J. Kehoe

A Theory of Asset Prices based on Heterogeneous Information and Limits to Arbitrage

Herd Behavior in Financial Markets: An Experiment with Financial Market Professionals

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

University of Toronto Department of Economics. Intraday Trading Patterns: The Role of Timing

Stock Price Behavior. Stock Price Behavior

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Herd Behavior in a Laboratory Financial Market

Essays on Financial Market Structure. David A. Cimon

Asset Pricing under Asymmetric Information Rational Expectations Equilibrium

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports. Estimating a Structural Model of Herd Behavior in Financial Markets. Marco Cipriani Antonio Guarino

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring.

Measuring and explaining liquidity on an electronic limit order book: evidence from Reuters D

Herding and Contrarianism: A Matter of Preference

An Ascending Double Auction

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Dynamic Trading and Asset Prices: Keynes vs. Hayek

G R E D E G Documents de travail

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

1. Information, Equilibrium, and Efficiency Concepts 2. No-Trade Theorems, Competitive Asset Pricing, Bubbles

Information and Learning in Markets. Chapter 9

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

Voluntary Disclosure and Strategic Stock Repurchases

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market

Indexing and Price Informativeness

Adverse Selection, Reputation and Sudden Collapses in Securitized Loan Markets

Department of Finance and Risk Engineering, NYU-Polytechnic Institute, Brooklyn, NY

Estimating a Structural Model of Herd Behavior in Financial Markets

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

International Finance. Investment Styles. Campbell R. Harvey. Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc.

Herding and Contrarianism: A Matter of Preference?

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

The impact of information risk and market stress on institutional herding

Credible Ratings. University of Toronto. From the SelectedWorks of hao li

Lecture Note 23 Adverse Selection, Risk Aversion and Insurance Markets

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

A Market Microsructure Theory of the Term Structure of Asset Returns

Comparative Statics in an Informational Cascade Model of Investment

Liquidity and Asset Prices in Rational Expectations Equilibrium with Ambiguous Information

Trading Volume in Dealer Markets

Liquidity skewness premium

Informational Losses in Rational Trading Panics

Finitely repeated simultaneous move game.

Endogenous Information Acquisition with Sequential Trade

Momentum in Imperial Russia

A Quantitative Theory of Unsecured Consumer Credit with Risk of Default

Advanced Macroeconomics I ECON 525a - Fall 2009 Yale University

Information Aggregation in Dynamic Markets with Strategic Traders. Michael Ostrovsky

Optimal Disclosure and Fight for Attention

Optimal Incentive Contract with Costly and Flexible Monitoring

A Decentralized Learning Equilibrium

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

A TALE OF TWO LEMONS: MULTI-GOOD DYNAMIC ADVERSE SELECTION

Strengthening the resilience of the banking sector consultative version Impact of amended counterparty risk measures on corporate hedging

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Alternative sources of information-based trade

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Advanced Micro 1 Lecture 14: Dynamic Games Equilibrium Concepts

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

SONDERFORSCHUNGSBEREICH 504

Principles of Banking (II): Microeconomics of Banking (3) Bank Capital

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Comparison of U.S. Stock Indices

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Market Survival in the Economies with Heterogeneous Beliefs

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Speculative Bubbles, Heterogeneous Beliefs, and Learning

Transcription:

Herding and Contrarian Behavior in Financial Markets Andreas Park & Hamid Sabourian Presentation at Penn State October 22, 2010

Market Turmoil in the Autumn of 2008: from end September to mid-november I On 8 days the Dow changed by more than 5% in absolute terms. Since WWII there have been only 16 other days with changes > 5%. On 6 days the Dow declined, but on 2 days it increased by more than 10%. (Since WWII this has happened only once, on the day after the 1987 crash.) Intra-day fluctuations were even more pronounced: 14 days when max and min prices levels were more than 10% apart (7 with max(t)-min(t-1) 10%, 7 times with min(t)-max(t-1) -10%).

Market Turmoil in the Autumn of 2008: from end September to mid-november II Such extreme price fluctuations are possible only if there are dramatic changes in behaviour (from buying to selling or the reverse). Such behaviour and the resulting price volatility is often claimed to be inconsistent with rational traders and informationally efficient prices. Commentators often attribute dramatic swings to investors animal instincts. However, appealing to animal spirits or irrationality is not necessary. We argue that it can be the result of fully rational social learning where agents change their beliefs and behavior as a result of observing the action of others.

Rational Herding in a Nutshell

Rational Herding in a Nutshell Herding (following others) may of course be the result of irrationality; however, here we concentrate on traders rationally following others.

Rational Herding in a Nutshell

Rational Herding in a Nutshell he knows what he s doing!

A crude herding example I A single asset world: Two values, V {0,1}, Pr(V = 1) = Pr(V = 0). Traders arrive in sequence, observe what predecessors did, and can buy or sell. Each receive privates (c.i.i.d.) informative signal S h or S l : Pr(S h V = 1) = Pr(S l V = 0) = q > 1/2. If asset price p t is always a constant then analogous to BHW (1992) model with herding cascade possible: after a finite number of buys (sales) all will do the same.

A crude herding example II Suppose asset price is efficient: p t = E(V H t ) = expected value given all public info. Since E(V H t,s h ) > E(V H t ) > E(V H t,s l ), H t, it follows that p t is always between the private expectations. Consequence: S h types always buy and S l types always sell; hence herding (or social learning) not possible!

A refined herding example I Situation: the competitor of financial institution FI has recently failed. Three states of the world, V 1 < V 2 < V 3 : V 1 : FI will also fail because it has deals with the failed bank that will not be honored and/or that the business model of FI is as bad as that of the failed bank; V 2 : FIs situation is entirely unrelated to the bank and the latters collapse will not affect FI. V 3 : FI may benefit greatly from the bank s collapse as it is able to attract the failed bank s customers and most capable employees. Now consider two announcements: A good news public announcement G that rules out the worst state, Pr(V 1 G) = 0. A bad news public announcement B that rules out the best state, Pr(V 3 B) = 0.

A refined herding example II After each announcement, we are left with a 2-state world. In 2-state models, an investor has a higher (lower) expectation than the market if and only if his private information is more (less) favourable towards the better state than towards the worse state. E[V G] E[V S,G] Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 3 ) E[V S,B] E[V B] Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 ). E.g.: after good news G, an investors buys (sells) if he thinks, relative to the market, that it is more (less) likely that FI will thrive than being unaffected.

A refined herding example III Key observation: 1. Investor buys after G and sells after B Pr(S V 3 ) > Pr(S V 2 ) and Pr(S V 1 ) > Pr(S V 2 ). Interpretation: herds in the sense that he acts like a momentum trader, buying with rising and selling with falling prices. Structure of private information: U shape. 2. Investor sells after G and buys after B Pr(S V 3 ) < Pr(S V 2 ) and Pr(S V 1 ) < Pr(S V 2 ). Interpretation: trades contrary to the general movement of prices. Structure of private information: Hill shape.

A refined herding example IV Some comments B and G are degenerate but idea applies generally. Herding arise endogenously because of trading histories which generates effects similar to B and G. Key task: generate/show existence of the right histories

Our contribution and main points 1. Rational herding can emerge in models with a richer state space. 2. We identify necessary and sufficient conditions on traders private information that allow for herding and contrarian behavior in an informationally efficient financial market. 3. The conditions themselves are intuitively appealing and lend meaning to the emergence of herding. 4. Herd behavior has exactly the features that one expects during herding prices can move substantially herding can induce lower liquidity and higher price volatility than if there were no herding

Definition of Herding I Literature on informational herding deals with observational learning, i.e. models in which agents observe actions of predecessors. Herding has several aspects: learning from others change of behavior + following others mass-uniform behavior Literature developed from settings without a price mechanism. Our general framework: continuous trading in a Glosten-Milgrom style model prices move only if trades reveal information.

Definition of Herding II Imagine all traders act alike (= mass-uniform) all informed take same action trades reveal no new information prices won t move Such behavior can t explain excess volatility or the like. We use a behavior-based definition that captures the social learning aspect of herding. Herding one signal-type changes behavior. Prevalence/Importance? Depends on how many people have the herding signal. (I ll come back to this later.)

Formal Definition of Herding and Contrarianism 1. A trader rationally engages in herd-buying after a history of trade H t if and only if he would sell at the initial history H 1, he buys at history H t, prices at H t are higher than at H 1. 2. A trader rationally engages in contrarian buying after a history of trade H t if and only if he would sell at the initial history H 1, he buys at history H t, prices at H t are lower than at H 1.

Other Issues Herd behavior = history induced switching in the direction of the crowd momentum trading. Contrarianism = history induced switching against the direction of the crowd mean reversion trading (Also: contrarian behavior is natural counterpart of herding.) There is a large empirical literature that studies contrarian and momentum investment strategies and their profitability. (Contrarian: Jegadeesh (1990), Lehmann (1990), Bondt and Thaler (1985); Momentum: Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), Jegadeesh and Titman (2001).)

Characterization Result I The simplest possible model that allows for herding and contrarianism is one with 3 states. For this we show: 1. Herding Necessity: Herding can occur only if the signal likelihood function (LF) for some signal is U-shaped in liquidation values. This implies that the signal is more likely to be the result of extreme values/states; Sufficiency: Herding occurs if the LF for some signal is U-shaped and the proportion of informed insiders is not too large enough noise (not always needed).

Characterization Result II 2. Contrarianism Necessity: Contrarian behaviour can occur only if the LF for some signal is Hill-shaped in liquidation values: extreme values generate this signal with smaller probability relative to middle values Sufficiency: Contrarian behaviour can occur if the LF for some signal is Hill-shaped and the proportion of informed insiders is not too large enough noise (not always needed).

Interpretation I Conditions on signals that allow herding/contrarianism have intuitive appeal ( relevance and applicability): 1. Herding People believe that extreme outcomes occurred with higher probability than moderate ones: fat-tailed posterior distribution. For posteriors, signal recipient shifts weight away from the centre to extreme values faster than an agent who receives only the public information (market maker). This makes the recipient s expectation more volatile and prone to changing behaviour and following the crowd even if prices reflect all public information.

Interpretation II 2. Contrarian Contrarian behavior occurs if traders signals generate thin-tailed distribution relative to the prior, indicating that moderate states are more likely than extreme states. The signal recipient shifts weight to the center expectation more stable. Thus, he may act against the general movement of prices (contrarian). 3. We also show that no social learning (no change of behaviour) if the signal likelihood function is neither U nor Hill (is monotonic)

Technical Aside Literature on asymmetric information often uses MLRP signals. Restrictive! But: Does it prohibit social learning? No! Our conclusions are general and valid with or without MLRP: Both U shape and Hill shape are consistent with MLRP and therefore, both herding and contrarian can occur with MLRP Moreover: results sharper and proofs significantly simpler with the well behaved MLRP here concentrate on MLRP. Characterisation robust for more than 3 signals/states (incl. continuum).

Related Literature Closest: Avery-Zemsky (AER 1998) known for their negative result. Argue that no herding with efficient prices unless signals are non-monotonic and risk multi-dimensional ( investors have a finer information structure than the market). present an appealing example with herding alas very little price movements during herding episode. Survey literature interpretation (e.g. Brunnermeier (2000), Bikhchandani-Sumil (2000), Chamley (2004)) 1. With monotonic signals, herding is impossible. 2. For herding one needs multidimensionality of risk. 3. Herding does not involve violent price movements except in the most unlikely environment. 4. Herding only with very special signals not so relevant for explaining behaviour/outcomes in efficient financial market.

Conformism and informational cascades caused by important, additional elements (e.g. transaction costs, reputation concerns): Lee (1998), Cipriani-Guarino (2009), Chari-Kehoe (2004), Dasgupta-Pratt (2008). Overweighing of public information Public signals can have a larger influence on stock price fluctuations than warranted by their information content. He and Wang (1995), Allen, Morris, and Shin (2006), Bacchetta and Wincoop (2006), Bacchetta and Wincoop (2008), Ozdenoren and Yuan (2007), Goldstein, Ozdenoren and Yuan (2010)

Glosten-Milgrom Sequential Trade Three liquidation values: V {V 1,V 2,V 3 } {0,V,2V}. Symmetric prior, Pr(V 1 ) = Pr(V 3 ). Risk neutral traders arrive in exogenous sequence. Trader can be 1. Noise (probability 1 µ): trade for reasons outside the model (liquidity, diversification, inventory rebalancing). 2. Informed (probability µ): receives one of three c.i.i.d. signals S {S 1,S 2,S 3 } (not necessarily ordered) that have distribution or likelihood function Pr(S V) V 1 V 2 V 3 S 1......... S 2......... S 3.........

Properties of the Signal Likelihood Function 1. Increasing: Pr(S V 1 ) < Pr(S V 2 ) < Pr(S V 3 ). 2. Decreasing: Pr(S V 1 ) > Pr(S V 2 ) > Pr(S V 3 ). 3. U-shape: Pr(S V 1 ) > Pr(S V 2 ),Pr(S V 3 ) > Pr(S V 2 ). 4. Hill-shape: Pr(S V 1 ) < Pr(S V 2 ),Pr(S V 3 ) < Pr(S V 2 ).

More on Signals Pr(S V 1 ) < Pr(S V 3 ) positive bias. Pr(S V 1 ) > Pr(S V 3 ) negative bias. U shape and negative bias nu shape etc. Informative Private Signals/no cascade condition. At each history H t there exists S S such that E[V H t,s] E[V H t ] (1)

Glosten-Milgrom Sequential Trade (cont d) Market maker (MM) sets bid-ask price. He sells at the ask. He buys at the bid. World is perfectly competitive MM makes zero expected profits and sets prices ask t = E[V H t,a buy at time t at ask t ], bid t = E[V H t,a sale at time t at bid t ]. Call public expectation, E[V H t ] the average price, bid t < E[V H t ] < ask t. ask t bid t increases in µ (probability that a trader is informed).

Useful first insights I For buy herding: sell at H 1 : E[V S,H 1 ] E[V H 1 ] < 0. buy at H t : E[V S,H t ] E[V H t ] > 0. plus: E[V H t ] > E[V H 1 ].

Useful first insights II Lemma For any signal S, E[V S] is less than E[V] if and only if S has a negative bias. Must have Pr(S V 1 ) > Pr(S V 3 ). Lemma If E[V H t ] > E[V] then q t 3 > qt 1. Must have q t 3 > qt 1.

Useful first insights III Lemma For any S, t and H t, E[V S,H t ] E[V H t ] has the same sign as q 2 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 2 )]+q 1 q 2 [Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 )] +2q 1 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 1 )] For switch from E[V S] < E[V] to E[V S,H t ] > E[V H t ] cannot have increasing or decreasing signal.

Proposition (Necessary Conditions) (a) Type S buy herds only if S is nu shaped and sell herds only if S is pu shaped. (b) Type S acts as a buy contrarian only if S is nhill shaped and acts as a sell contrarian only if S is phill shaped. Suppose S buys herds can t be increasing/decreasing. Suppose S is nhill shaped: LF puts less weight on the tails of and more on the center relative to the public belief. Shift from the tails towards the center is more for value V 3 than for V 1 because of the negative bias. Buy herding q t 1 < qt 3. Redistribution of probability ensures that S s expectation is less than public expectation. Hence an nhill shaped S cannot be buying S must be nu.

Sufficiency: Insight Number One I S is nhill or nu buy herding/ buy contrarianism candidates. To illustrate the mechanism, consider two extreme outcomes: 1. The occurrence of state V 1 can be ruled out. 2. The occurrence of state V 3 can be ruled out. How will nu and nhill types trade?

Sufficiency: Insight Number One II Suppose there is a history so that, relative to V 3 and V 2, state V 1 does not occur q 1 0 q 2 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 2 )]+q 1 q 2 [Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 )]+2q 1 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 1 )] q 2 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 2 )] for all practical purposes, two state world (V 2,V 3 ). 1. Hill shaped type has a signal favouring the lowest state (V 2 ). Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 2 ) < 0 Should sell no contrarianism or herding! 2. U shaped type has a signal favouring the highest state (V 3 ). Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 2 ) > 0 Should buy Herd buying!

Sufficiency: Insight Number One III Suppose there is a history so that, relative to V 1 and V 2, state V 3 does not occur q 3 0 q 2 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 2 )]+q 1 q 2 [Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 )]+2q 1 q 3 [Pr(S V 3 ) Pr(S V 1 )] q 1 q 2 [Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 )] for all practical purposes, two state world (V 1,V 2 ). 1. Hill shaped type has a signal favouring the highest state (V 2 ). Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 ) > 0 Should buy Buy Contrarian! 2. U shaped type has a signal favouring the lowest state (V 1 ). Pr(S V 2 ) Pr(S V 1 ) < 0 Should sell no contrarianism or herding!

Sufficiency: Insight Number Two The formal model uses bid and ask prices with ask t > E[V H t ] > bid t. Herding/contrarianism requires type S to trade. Need to ensure that bid-ask spread is tight enough so that S trades. Specifically, µ must be small enough at two points: 1. At H 1 so that E[V S,H 1 ] < bid 1. 2. At H t when E[V S,H t ] > E[V H t ] must also have E[V S,H t ] > ask t. Intuition: As µ ց 0, bid t ր E[V H t ] and ask t ց E[V H t ].

Lemma (Possibility of Herding and Contrarian Behavior) 1. Suppose that signal S is nu shaped. Then there exist µ i and µ s bh (0,1] such that S buy herds if µ < µ bh min{µ i,µ s bh } and if the following holds: For any ǫ > 0 there exists a history H t such that q1 t/qt l < ǫ for all l = 2,3. 2. Suppose signal S is nhill shaped. Then there exist µ i and µ s bc (0,1] such that S acts as a buy contrarian if µ < µ bc min{µ i,µ s bc } and if the following holds: For any ǫ > 0 there exists a history H t such that q3 t/qt l < ǫ for all l = 1,2.

Causes for Pain and Suffering I 1. Finding the right noise level Initial noise level µ i is unique. But: µ bh and µ bc may not be unique. Depends on which other signal type trades with the herding/contrarian candidate. For some parametric configurations, no restriction on µ is needed (namely, if the herding/contrarian candidate is the only type to trade).

Causes for Pain and Suffering II 2. Is there a history with q 1 sufficiently small relative to q 2 and q 3? For some signal structures: no problem (sufficiently many more buys than sales will do the trick); example: MLRP signals Other signal structures: very involved (2-stage histories needed). But bottom line: it can be done (terms and conditions apply). Easiest case: There exists a trade such that both q 1 /q 3 and q 1 /q 2 or both q 3 /q 1 and q 3 /q 2 decrease uniformly (independent of time). Example: for some ǫ β t t > β t i +ǫ for any i > j and any t. Holds with MLRP distributions (coming up).

Proposition (Sufficient Conditions) (a) Let S be nu shaped. Assume also that if one other signal is pu shaped then the third signal has a non negative bias. Then there exists µ bh (0,1] such that S buy herds if µ < µ bh. (b) Let S be pu shaped. Assume also that if one other signal is nu shaped then the third signal has a non positive bias. Then there exists µ sh (0,1] such that S sell herds if µ < µ sh. (c) Let S be nhill shaped. Assume also that if one other signal is phill shaped then the third signal has non positive bias. Then there exists µ bc (0,1] such that S is a buy contrarian if µ < µ bc. (d) Let S be phill shaped. Assume also that if one other signal is nhill shaped then the third signal has a non negative bias. Then there exists µ sc (0,1] such that S is a sell contrarian if µ < µ sc.

All things considered, the general result is Theorem (Herding and Contrarianism Characterisation Result) (a) Herding. (i) Necessity: If type S herds, then S is U shaped with a non-zero bias. (ii) Sufficiency: If there is a U shaped type with a non-zero bias, there exists µ h (0,1] such that when µ < µ h some informed type herds. (b) Contrarianism. (i) Necessity: If type S acts as a contrarian, then S is Hill shaped with a non-zero bias. (ii) Sufficiency: If there is a Hill shaped type with a non-zero bias, there exists µ c (0,1] such that when µ < µ c some informed type acts as a contrarian.

The literature on asymmetric information often assumes that the information structure satisfies the Monotone Likelihood Ratio Property (MLRP). MLRP: for S l < S h and V l < V h, Pr(S h V l )Pr(S l V h ) < Pr(S h V h )Pr(S l V l ) Theorem (Herding and Contrarianism with MLRP) Assume signals are ordered, S 1 < S 2 < S 3, and that the signal structure satisfies the MLRP. Then the following holds: (a) Let S 2 be nu. Then there exist µ bh (0,1] such that S buy herds if and only if µ < µ bh. (b) Let S 2 be nhill. Then there exist µ bc (0,1] such that S acts as a buy contrarian if and only if µ < µ bc.

Implications of social learning: Overview I 1. Prices can move substantially during herding and contrarian episodes even with MLRP. Surprising! (Loose but wrong intuition: little information revealed during a herding episode). 2. To measure impact on liquidity and price volatility compare price paths: when agents know public information (transparent market) hypothetical economy in which herding/contrarian does not occur (e.g. agents are naïve and ignore the public information). 3. Result: price rises and falls are more extreme in transparent market Liquidity (measured by bid-ask spreads) declines when herding/contrarianism starts.

Implications of social learning: Overview II Implications for market transparency : (traders in hypothetical world do not use/have access to past public data less transparent). Social learning causes transparent markets to be more volatile, less stable, and less liquid. Possible empirical implication: serial correlation of trading activities (buys beget more buys) as a measure of social learning should go hand in hand with an relative increase in price volatility and bid-ask-spreads.

Persistent Herding and Self-Defeating Contrarianism Assume MLRP. Consider any history H r = (a 1,...,a r 1 ) and suppose that H r is followed by b 0 buys and s 0 sales in some order; denote this history by H t = (a 1,...,a r+b+s 1 ). 1. If there is buy herding by S at H r then there exists an increasing function s( )>1 such that S continues to buy herd at H t if and only if s < s(b). 2. If there is buy contrarianism by S at H r then there exists an increasing function b( ) > 1 such that S continues to act as a buy contrarianism at H t if and only if b < b(s).

Proposition: Social Learning and the Price Range Let signals obey MLRP. 1. Consider any history H r = (a 1,...,a r 1 ) at which there is buy herding (contrarianism). Then for any ǫ > 0, there exists history H t = (a 1,...,a t 1 ) following H r such that there is buy herding (contrarianism) at every H τ = (a 1,...,a τ 1 ), r τ t, and the average price E[V H r+τ ] exceeds V 3 ǫ (is less than V 1 +ǫ). 2. Let µ admit buy herding (contrarianism). Then for every ǫ > 0 there exists a δ > 0 such that if Pr(V 2 ) > 1 δ there is a history H t = (a 1,...,a t 1 ) and a date r < t such that (i) there is buy herding (contrarianism) at every H τ =(a 1,...,a τ 1 ), r τ t, (ii) E[V H r ]<V 2 +ǫ (E[V H r ] >V 2 ǫ) and (iii) E[V H t ] > V 3 ǫ (E[V H t ] > V 1 +ǫ).

Establishing a Benchmark for Volatility Three questions. Once herding/contrarian behaviour starts: 1. Will liquidity, as measured by the difference between the bid and ask prices, be less with social learning than in the case with no social learning (no types changing behaviour)? 2. Will further buys move prices more/less with social learning than without? 3. Will sales move prices more/less with social learning than without? For the comparison, we compare to hypothetical economy in which 1. t each informed trader takes the same action as that he would take at the initial history. 2. MM sets prices taking into account that the informed behaves as above.

Volatility I Proposition (The Impact of Herding and Contrarian Behavior on Volatility) 1. Once buy herding starts the average price in the transparent world is larger after any number of buys than in the opaque world. 2. Once buy herding starts the average price in the transparent world is lower for a certain number of sales than in the opaque world (while herding lasts). 3. An analogue of this holds for buy contrarianism.

Volatility II Proposition (Formally: Relative Volatility) Assume MLRP. Consider any finite history H r = (a 1,...,a r 1 ) at which the priors in the two markets coincide: q r i = qr i,o for i = 1,2,3. Suppose that H r is followed by b 0 buys and s 0 sales in some order; denote this history by H t = (a 1...,a r+b+s 1 ). Assume that there is buy herding at H τ, for every τ = r,...,r +b+s. 1. Suppose s = 0. Then E[V H t ] > E o [V H t ] for any b > 0. 2. Suppose b = 0. Then there exists s 1 such that E[V H t ] < E o [V H t ] for any s s. 3. For any s there exists b such that E[V H t ] > E o [V H t ] for any b > b.

Liquidity Proposition (The Impact of Herding and Contrarian Behavior on Liquidity) Consider any history H t at which type S engages in buy herding or buy contrarianism. 1. The ask price when the buy herding or buy contrarian candidate S rationally buys exceeds the ask price when he chooses not to buy. 2. The bid price when the buy herding or buy contrarian candidate S rationally buys is lower than the bid price when he chooses to sell.

Volatility 18 16 14 herding starts and the rational price increases above the naïve price 12 rational price drops below naïve price 10 0 50 100 150 200 250

More States, More Signals Results don t hinge on 3-everything setting extend to N state world. Assume values of the asset are on an equal grid, {V 1,V 2,...,V N } = {0,V,2V,..., (N 1)V} prior probability distribution is symmetric, Pr(V i ) = Pr(V N+1 i ). Buy herding/contrarian: candidate must sell at the initial history (E[V S] < E[V] is necessary). E.g. E[V S] < E[V] if signal S is negatively biased in the sense that Pr(S V i ) > Pr(S V N+1 i ) for all i < (N +1)/2.

N-States: Results have same flavour I E[V S,H t ] E[V H t ] has the same sign as N 1 j=1 N j (V i+j V i ) q i q i+j [Pr(S V i+j ) Pr(S V i )]. i=1 Lemma With N states, a signal type S with an increasing or decreasing LF will never switch from buying to selling or vice versa.

N-States: Results have same flavour II Lemma (Possibility of Herding and Contrarian Behavior) (i) Let S be negatively biased & Pr(S V N 1 ) < Pr(S V N ) & for all ǫ > 0 exists H t such that qi t/qt l < ǫ for all l = N 1,N and i < N 1. Then there exists a µ bh (0,1] such that S buy herds if µ < µ bh. (ii) Let S be negatively biased & Pr(S V 1 ) < Pr(S V 2 )& for all ǫ > 0 exists H t such that qi t/qt l < ǫ for all l = 1,2 and i > 2. Then there exists a µ bc (0,1] such that S is a buy contrarian if µ < µ bc.

N-States: Results have same flavour III Theorem (Herding and Contrarianism with N States) Assume that signals satisfy the MLRP and let signal S be negatively biased. (a) If Pr(S V N 1 ) < Pr(S V N ) then there exists µ bh (0,1] such that S buy herds if µ < µ bh. (b) If Pr(S V 1 ) < Pr(S V 2 ) there exists µ bh (0,1] such that S is a buy contrarian if µ < µ bh.

Is herding economically significant? Answer: Depends on the prevalence of herding types. Example 1 Pr(S V) V 1 V 2 V 3 S D.01.009 0 S U.99.98.985 S I 0.011.015 Signal S U is the herding-u-shaped signal. At least 98% of informed traders switch behavior when herding begins. Herding may have large effect.

Conclusion Herding and contrarianism does not arise under all circumstances. But: the conditions under which is it does arise have very intuitive interpretations. (e.g. when there is great uncertainty (many U shaped signals) in markets.) Herding and contrarianism has noticeable effects on prices and liquidity. Herding is self-sustaining, contrarianism is self defeating.