Saskatchewan s carbon tax numbers are in and the answer is reporting errors

Similar documents
New Study Shows that Returning Carbon Revenues Directly to Households would be Net Financially Positive for the Vast Majority of Households

IS BRITISH COLUMBIA S CARBON TAX GOOD FOR HOUSEHOLD INCOME? WORKING PAPER

What Should the Fed Do?

The Impact of a Pan- Canadian Carbon Pricing Levy on PBO s GDP Projection. Ottawa, Canada 22 May

Part 3: Debt Sustainability Framework for Low- Income Countries

EVERY ASSET HAS A FAIR VALUE EVEN THE FORGOTTEN ONES

The yellow highlighted areas are bear markets with NO recession.

4 BIG REASONS YOU CAN T AFFORD TO IGNORE BUSINESS CREDIT!

Gauging Current Economic Momentum. Dennis Lockhart President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

THE 2018 MANITOBA PROSPERITY REPORT. Are We There Yet? MANITOBA EMPLOYERS COUNCIL

Discounting the Benefits of Climate Change Policies Using Uncertain Rates

Canadian Taxpayers Federation. May 17, 2018

11 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1

Scenic Video Transcript End-of-Period Accounting and Business Decisions Topics. Accounting decisions: o Accrual systems.

Top 7 IFRS Mistakes. That You Should Avoid. Silvia of IFRSbox.com

IB Interview Guide: Case Study Exercises Three-Statement Modeling Case (30 Minutes)

Inter-Provincial Exports

Costs for the USA of Compliance with the Kyoto Protocol: a Critical Assessment of Official US estimates.

AN INTERNATIONAL CLIMATE CHANGE CONVENTION: WHO CUTS? WHO PAYS?

Fossil-Fuel Subsidies: At What Cost? Fossil-Fuel Subsidies in the Canadian Oil Sector

Economic Impact Analysis: Washington s Initiative 732

The Multiplier Effect

Comments on Foreign Effects of Higher U.S. Interest Rates. James D. Hamilton. University of California at San Diego.

How to Handle FASB s Unfair Value Standard

10 Errors to Avoid When Refinancing

EXECUTIVE OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT COUNCIL OF ECONOMIC ADVISERS WASHINGTON, DC 20502

REVIEW REPORT

After studying this chapter you will be able to

Economic and Fiscal Outlook

THE AD (AGGREGATE DEMAND) / AS (AGGREGATE SUPPLY) MACRO MODEL

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Objectives for Class 26: Fiscal Policy

Republic of Kazakhstan. Director Climate Change Department. Ministry of Energy

Management and Operations 340: Exponential Smoothing Forecasting Methods

Economy Is Weaker Than It Seems & Scary Facts On National Debt

Valuation Public Comps and Precedent Transactions: Historical Metrics and Multiples for Public Comps

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

CLIMATE. Q&A on accounting for transfers from outside of NDCs under Article 6 of the Paris Agreement to avoid double counting

ECONOMICS U$A 21 ST CENTURY EDITION PROGRAM #18 FISCAL POLICY Annenberg Foundation & Educational Film Center

APPENDIX A: FINANCIAL ASSUMPTIONS AND DISCOUNT RATE

MEDIA RELEASE. The road to Copenhagen. Ends Media Contact: Michael Hitchens September 2009

JOHN MORIKIS: SEAN HENNESSY:

FOUNDATION SERIES ON DEMAND. Fraud Red Flags Workbook

Tax Alert Canada. Alberta budget

Bridgewater Daily Observations March 25, 2003

Further Reflections on Alberta s Capital Spending and Its Finance: Comments on the Dodge Report to the Government of Alberta, October 2015

GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONS: RISKS AND CHALLENGES FOR PORTFOLIOS JANUARY 2016

Commentary: Achieving Growth Amid Fiscal Imbalances

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES U.S. GROWTH IN THE DECADE AHEAD. Martin S. Feldstein. Working Paper

W I N T E R W A R N I N G

Real Estate Private Equity Case Study 3 Opportunistic Pre-Sold Apartment Development: Waterfall Returns Schedule, Part 1: Tier 1 IRRs and Cash Flows

FISCAL POLICY. Objectives. Government Budgets. Balancing Acts on Parliament Hill. Government Budgets. Government Budgets CHAPTER

Policy Alternatives for a Return to Full Employment in Spain

ECO155L19.doc 1 OKAY SO WHAT WE WANT TO DO IS WE WANT TO DISTINGUISH BETWEEN NOMINAL AND REAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT. WE SORT OF

FREQUENTLY ASKED QUESTIONS (FAQs) ON LAPP/PSPP Labour Coalition on Pensions January 21, 2014

Making work pay. Presentation to Minimum Wage Review Panel September 28, 2012 By Lana Payne, President NL Federation of Labour

By 2028, New Brunswick will reverse the negative trend in real non-residential private sector investment and will reach 2008 levels once more.

Final Exam Macroeconomics Winter 2011 Prof. Veronica Guerrieri

Text transcription of Chapter 5 Measuring a Nation s Income

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

The Expenditure-Output

How Do You Calculate Cash Flow in Real Life for a Real Company?

Budget. Opportunities for Growth

Third Biennial Report of Luxembourg under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change

What is wrong with Belgian growth?

THE POTENTIAL ROLE OF A CARBON TAX IN U.S. FISCAL REFORM

General Economic Outlook Recession! Will it be Short and Shallow?

Carbon Tax a Good Idea for Developing Countries?

Oral History Program Series: Civil Service Interview no.: S11

Thinking Through the Economic Consequences of Higher Taxes

Carbon Dividends Would Benefit New Brunswick Families. October 17th Study: Carbon Dividends would benefit Canadian families

MAY Carbon taxation and fiscal consolidation: the potential of carbon pricing to reduce Europe s fiscal deficits

Introduction. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame. Sims (ND) Introduction Fall / 26

Exam Number. Section

Chapter 5 THE AUDIT REPORT

Derived copy of The Expenditure-Output Model *

Venture Capital 4% Strategy. Mega/Large Buyout 29% Highlights from the 2016 GP Dashboard include:

T A B L E 17.CS1 Summary Results for YoY Sales Growth Decile Analysis of All Stocks Universe, January 1, 1964 to December 31, 2009.

THE QUEEN on the application of PLAN B EARTH & OTHERS. - and - THE SECRETARY OF STATE FOR BUSINESS, ENERGY AND INDUSTRIAL STRATEGY.

Will The Fed Raise Rates Tomorrow? Probably Not

The Global Recession of 2016

The Aggregate Expenditures Model. A continuing look at Macroeconomics

INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS: DISCUSSION

Building your Bond Portfolio From a bond fund to a laddered bond portfolio - by Richard Croft

Foreign Exchange Market (FOREX)

Using Balance Sheets for Fiscal Analysis and Policymaking Amanda Sayegh Fiscal Affairs Department International Monetary Fund

charts to also be in the overbought area before taking the trade. If I took the trade right away, you can see on the M1 chart stochastics that the

An Overview of the Clinton Budget Plan

Macroeconomics II. The Open Economy

Some Simple Deficit Reduction Arithmetic

I m going to cover 6 key points about FCF here:

Building Your Future. with the Kohl s 401(k) Savings Plan. Kohl s supports planning for your financial future with increased confidence.

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

The Cross-Canada Impacts of Developing the Oil and Gas Industry of the Energy Sector

Classroom Etiquette. No reading the newspaper in class (this includes crossword puzzles). Attendance is NOT REQUIRED.

ECONOMICS U$A 21 ST CENTURY EDITION PROGRAM #24 FEDERAL DEFICITS Annenberg Foundation & Educational Film Center

SEATTLE S BEST COFFEE? Using ZRS and the Zacks Valuation Model to identify factors impacting equity valuations in 3 minutes or less

Liquidity Trapped! The Fed s Policy Nightmare

Remarks on Interchange Fees: Central Bank Perspectives and Options

Transcription:

Saskatchewan s carbon tax numbers are in and the answer is reporting errors Jotham Peters, Navius Research, Inc. January, 2019 The Government of Saskatchewan is challenging the federal government in court over its plan to implement a tax on greenhouse gas emissions. Saskatchewan opposes the federal plan in part because it claims the economic costs of the carbon tax would be catastrophic. We took a close look at Saskatchewan s analysis, and the numbers simply don t add up. Our best guess is that Saskatchewan s own modelling suggests that the impacts of a carbon tax have been overstated by multiple orders of magnitude! Saskatchewan claims the federal carbon tax would end economic growth in the province and cause a near permanent recession. While provincial gross domestic product is expected to grow by one per cent each year in the absence of the tax, the government claims a carbon tax would shrink the province s economy by 1.43 per cent every year between 2022 and 2030. The figure from Saskatchewan s news release is shown in Figure 1. Figure 1: Saskatchewan s news release on the economic impact of the federal carbon tax Source: Government of Saskatchewan, 2018, Federal Carbon Tax Could Reduce Saskatchewan GDP By Almost $16 Billion By 2030, available from: http://www.saskatchewan.ca/government/news-andmedia/2018/june/27/fed-carbon-tax, last accessed on December 19, 2018.

This kind of GDP contraction would be unprecedented in any developed countries in recent times. In Canada, we would need to go back to the 1930s Great Depression to see an equivalent. In the past 100 years, only the world wars and the Spanish Civil War caused a more devastating recession in any European country. What is behind Saskatchewan s incredible projections? I suspect that the answer is much less dreadful for Saskatchewan s economy: The Government of Saskatchewan simply reported the wrong numbers! How did this happen? It appears that two big reporting errors compounded into an even larger error. First, the Government of Saskatchewan appears to have confused GDP growth with total GDP. While the news release claims that a carbon tax "would reduce provincial GDP by 2.43 per cent", their figure (see Figure 1) shows that the tax would instead reduce the provincial GDP growth rate by 2.43 per cent. Reductions in GDP and GDP growth are not the same: either the statement or figure must be wrong. The analysis behind the figure focuses on a GDP change, not GDP growth, so the figure is likely incorrect. If the Government of Saskatchewan corrected this mistake, the carbon tax would cease to be recessionary. Second, the numbers in the University of Regina s underlying analysis prepared for the government don t add up. In one section, their analysis shows that a carbon tax would reduce GDP in 2022 by 2.43 per cent. In another section, they report the change in each GDP component. No component even approaches a decline of 2.43 per cent. This is a big red flag. The largest change in any component of GDP is reported as a decline of 1.1 per cent in 2022. Some major components, such as household consumption, are only shown to decline by 0.2 per cent. So how can the total decline be so much more than its components? Correcting for both the Government of Saskatchewan and the University of Regina s suspected errors, we get a reduction in economic growth of a much smaller and far more realistic 0.13 per cent from 2017 to 2022. While I m casting stones, let me acknowledge that I ve made plenty of mistakes. In my first analysis using a computable general equilibrium model in 2008, I also misreported GDP but not to this extent. I caught my error and owned up to it. Mistakes are made but the important next step is to acknowledge and correct them.

Disclaimers The focus of this review is on how the University of Regina translated the numbers from their model into the report and news release, not on the analysis itself. Neither Navius Research nor I are advocates for any specific policy or climate policy in general. Our job is to analyze the effect of climate policies so that the public, government, industry and non-governmental organizations can make informed decisions. Saskatchewan s analysis drew my attention because it is, at best, highly misleading.

Appendix: A deep dive into the news release numbers The Government of Saskatchewan references a 2.43 per cent reduction in GDP growth. 1 The number appears to come from a report by the University of Regina. 2 Section 5.2 of the report ( Impacts on Macro Economy [sic] ) shows GDP change (%) over time under three different scenarios. I m pretty sure that the government s news release is based on scenario S3, which appears to show a 2.43 per cent GDP change in 2022. To maintain consistency with this the underlying analysis and the news release, I ve likewise focused on 2022. Scenario S3 represents applying a carbon tax to Saskatchewan s transportation and building sectors. The tax rises to $50 per tonne in 2022. Revenues from the tax are transferred to households. It should be a decent representation of the levy on fossil fuels mandated by the federal government. Figure 2: A figure from the University of Regina s report entitled The impacts of carbon tax on GDP and GHG emission [sic] 1 Government of Saskatchewan, 2018, Federal Carbon Tax Could Reduce Saskatchewan GDP By Almost $16 Billion By 2030, available from: http://www.saskatchewan.ca/government/news-and-media/2018/june/27/fed-carbon-tax, accessed on December 19, 2018. 2 University of Regina (Institute for Energy, Environment and Sustainable Communities), 2018, Economic modeling to support the development of climate change regulations, available from: http://www.saskatchewan.ca/government/newsand-media/2018/june/27/fed-carbon-tax (see IEESC Full Report in the Related Items), accessed on December 19, 2018.

GDP growth and GDP change are two very different concepts that the Government of Saskatchewan appears to confuse. The University of Regina uses the concepts in confusing ways. GDP growth refers to how GDP changes from one period to the next. You will often hear that GDP grew by a given percentage per year. If an economy experiences a recession, it experiences negative growth in GDP over a period of time (usually more than six months). GDP change refers to how total GDP changes from one scenario (e.g., Saskatchewan without a carbon tax) to another (e.g., Saskatchewan with a carbon tax). The comparison between the two concepts is somewhat abstract. I find it easier to translate our understanding of the University of Regina s analysis into actual GDP numbers (e.g., GDP in Saskatchewan is X $ in 2022) instead of growth or change. As the University of Regina did not provide total GDP in its report, I ve converted GDP into an index in which GDP in 2017 is one (please refer to Figure 3): It appears that the University of Regina and the Government of Saskatchewan assume the province s economy will grow at a one per cent annual rate until 2026 if the carbon tax is not implemented (i.e., the baseline scenario in Figure 3). And, regardless of whether Figure 2 shows GDP growth or change, it captures a change relative to the baseline. If the University of Regina s analysis refers to a decline in GDP growth, GDP would follow the path shown in the bottom line of Figure 3. This shows that by 2022, GDP would be about seven per cent lower than it would have been in the absence of a carbon tax, and by 2026, GDP would be 22 per cent lower. If the University of Regina s analysis refers to a decline in GDP from a baseline scenario, as I suspect is the case, the impact on GDP would be more modest (shown in the middle line of Figure 3). Under this scenario, GDP would be lower than the baseline by 2.43 per cent in 2022, and 5.45 per cent by 2026.

Saskatchewan's GDP (2017 = 1) Figure 3: Saskatchewan GDP under different interpretations of the University of Regina s data 1.10 Baseline 1.05 1.00 UoR shows reduction in GDP 0.95 0.90 0.85 UoR shows reduction in GDP Growth 0.80 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025 Admittedly, the macroeconomic section of the University of Regina s report is confusing. The report sometimes uses GDP change and GDP growth interchangeably, making it difficult for the reader to know which metric is being reported. The GDP change figure (see Figure 2) is actually titled The impacts of carbon tax [sic] on GDP and GHG emission [sic], leading me to sincerely wonder if they accidentally reported GHG emissions instead of GDP (more on the validity of the numbers in this figure below). The text describing the figure reads the GDP change shown reflects the impacts of carbon tax on macro economy in Saskatchewan [sic]. It is seen from this figure that the carbon tax has negative impacts on economic growth. Despite the confusing text, I think we have to take the figure at face value because it reports a GDP change (i.e., a change in GDP from the baseline) and not a change in GDP growth. Specifically: 1. Lower GDP attributed to a carbon tax would reduce GDP growth, so this interpretation is not inconsistent with the text. 2. Text referring to specific numbers indicates a GDP reduction or GDP change, and not GDP growth. 3. If the figure does indeed refer to GDP growth, the University of Regina has some explaining to do. A result in which a $50 per tonne carbon tax on transportation and buildings reduces GDP growth by 2.43 per cent (and by 5.45 per cent in 2026!) would be vastly misaligned with the results from any other computable general equilibrium (CGE) model.

It therefore seems likely that the Government of Saskatchewan mistook GDP change for a change in GDP growth. I do sympathize to some extent because the macroeconomic section of the University of Regina s report is poorly written and confusing. Nevertheless, I d be surprised if the figure refers to GDP growth and not a GDP change from the baseline. But even a 2.43 per cent reduction in GDP is a massive response to a carbon tax that amounts to a 12 cents per litre increase in gasoline prices. This impact is also contingent on there being no additional reporting errors in the University of Regina s report. Segue to the next suspected reporting error. In addition to reporting the aggregate impact on GDP, the University of Regina identifies how a carbon tax affects each component of GDP in section 5.3, titled GDP decomposition analysis. For a quick review of first-year macroeconomics, GDP is the sum of consumption ( C ), government expenditures ( G ), investment ( I ), changes in inventories ( STO ) and exports ( EX ), minus imports ( IM ): GDP = C + G + I + +STO + EX IM In the University of Regina s analysis, none of these components change by more than 1.1 per cent, with some major components of GDP (e.g., consumption) only changing by 0.2 per cent. See Table 1 for the University of Regina s GDP decomposition in 2022. Table 1: University of Regina s decomposition of GDP results for scenario S3 in 2022 GDP components 2022 C -0.22% G -0.24% I -1.09% STO -0.76% EX -0.19% IM 0.13% If a carbon tax indeed reduces GDP by 2.43 per cent, but none of the components change by more than 1.1 per cent, you have a big red flag. I tried to reconcile the values in Figure 2 with the values in Table 1. The most reasonable way I found (which is completely unreasonable) was by inflating exports and imports so they both account for about 600 per cent of Saskatchewan s GDP by 2022 (about 10 times greater than

what exports and imports have been historically) 3. Let s just say that, even if this is theoretically possible, it is extremely unlikely. (If I saw this result in my model, I d immediately start looking for the error.) The University of Regina does not report the relative composition of GDP in 2022 in the absence of a carbon tax. For example, they don t say whether consumption accounts for 40 per cent of GDP or something different. This means that I can t say for sure how the University of Regina weighed each component of GDP to get an aggregate value. To translate the decomposition into an aggregate impact, I used the share of each component of GDP in 2011 from Statistics Canada s Supply-Use tables 4. I used this year to be consistent with the University of Regina s analysis, which claims to use a 2011 benchmark year. Using the GDP decomposition in Table 1 and the contribution of each component to GDP in 2011, the carbon tax reduces GDP by closer to 0.64 per cent in 2022. Now, the University of Regina s report suggests two different things in two different sections. In the aggregate GDP section, GDP declines by 2.43 per cent in 2022. And we can infer that aggregate GDP declines by about 0.64 per cent in the GDP decomposition section. Which is a correct representation of the University of Regina s analysis? The short answer is I can t say for sure. What I can say is that, absent some unreasonable assumption about GDP composition (e.g., imports account for 600 per cent of GDP), one of these sections is wrong. My strong suspicion is that the aggregate GDP section is wrong and the GDP decomposition is right. For one, it s easier to screw up one figure than multiple. The aggregate GDP section only has one figure, which could plausibly have used incorrect data. And, remember that the figure was even titled The impacts of carbon tax on GDP and GHG emission [sic]. So, maybe the figure shows GHG emissions after all! The GDP decomposition section has 10 figures and tables. It would have been a massive screw-up to get all these wrong. A second reason why I suspect the aggregate GDP section is wrong is that even a 2.43 per cent reduction in aggregate GDP is misaligned with everything I ve seen from a 3 In 2011, exports accounted for about 70 per cent of Saskatchewan s GDP, while imports accounted for 57 per cent. Imports have a negative effect on GDP, so exports and imports partially cancel each other out. Net exports then account for about 13 per cent of GDP. Source: Statistics Canada, 2017, Supply and use tables, summary level, provincial and territorial, CANSIM Table 381-0035. 4 Statistics Canada, 2017, Supply and use tables, summary level, provincial and territorial, CANSIM Table 381-0035.

Saskatchewan's GDP (2017 = 1) CGE model. The results from the GDP decomposition section are more plausible based on the tool used. In conclusion, using my expert judgment to interpret the University of Regina s own analysis, a carbon tax most likely reduces GDP growth by 0.13 per cent each year from 2017 to 2022. So, instead of GDP growing by one per cent, it would grow by 0.87 per cent (a big difference from -1.43 per cent). For a disclaimer, I m not endorsing this finding, but this is what I think the University of Regina s analysis actually says. By 2022, the cumulative effect of lower growth is that GDP is 0.64 per cent lower than it would have been in the absence of the carbon tax. Figure 4 shows a corrected projection based on my review. While the impact of a carbon tax would still be noticeable, it is a far cry from the Government of Saskatchewan s current understanding. Figure 4: GDP projection with corrected estimates 1.10 Baseline 1.05 1.00 UoR analysis (corrected by Navius) 0.95 0.90 0.85 0.80 2017 2019 2021 2023 2025