Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter IV

Similar documents
Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

Risk Neutral Valuation

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Risk Neutral Measures

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Lecture 11: Ito Calculus. Tuesday, October 23, 12

Advanced Stochastic Processes.

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

3 Ito formula and processes

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Hedging under Arbitrage

Lévy models in finance

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Martingale representation theorem

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

The stochastic calculus

Remarks: 1. Often we shall be sloppy about specifying the ltration. In all of our examples there will be a Brownian motion around and it will be impli

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

1 Math 797 FM. Homework I. Due Oct. 1, 2013

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

European call option with inflation-linked strike

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Multi-Asset Options. A Numerical Study VILHELM NIKLASSON FRIDA TIVEDAL. Master s thesis in Engineering Mathematics and Computational Science

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

The Black-Scholes Model

The Black-Scholes Model

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Estimating the Greeks

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Option Pricing. 1 Introduction. Mrinal K. Ghosh

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

Numerical schemes for SDEs

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Finance II. May 27, F (t, x)+αx f t x σ2 x 2 2 F F (T,x) = ln(x).

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

Monte Carlo Simulations

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Introduction to Affine Processes. Applications to Mathematical Finance

Arbitrage, Martingales, and Pricing Kernels

Introduction Taylor s Theorem Einstein s Theory Bachelier s Probability Law Brownian Motion Itô s Calculus. Itô s Calculus.

Path Dependent British Options

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Financial Economics & Insurance

Chapter 14. The Multi-Underlying Black-Scholes Model and Correlation

Option Pricing Formula for Fuzzy Financial Market

Pricing Barrier Options under Local Volatility

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Using of stochastic Ito and Stratonovich integrals derived security pricing

King s College London

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

The Black-Scholes Equation using Heat Equation

- 1 - **** d(lns) = (µ (1/2)σ 2 )dt + σdw t

Stochastic Volatility

1 The continuous time limit

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Geometric Brownian Motion

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Non-semimartingales in finance

18. Diffusion processes for stocks and interest rates. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Hedging under arbitrage

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Pricing Variance Swaps under Stochastic Volatility Model with Regime Switching - Discrete Observations Case

5. Itô Calculus. Partial derivative are abstractions. Usually they are called multipliers or marginal effects (cf. the Greeks in option theory).

The Valuation of Bermudan Guaranteed Return Contracts

(Informal) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Transcription:

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter IV Matthias Thul Last Update: June 9, 25 Exercise 4. This proof is fully analogous to the one of Theorem 4.2.. We want to show that for s t T E[I(t) F(s) I(s). Assume again, that the s [t l, t l+ ) and t [t k, t k+ ) for l k. We start by splitting up the sum into an F(s) measurable part and a part independent of F(s) and obtain I(t) l (t j ) [M (t j+ ) M (t j ) + (t l ) [M (t l+ ) M (t l ) j + k jl+ (t j ) [M (t j+ ) M (t j ) + (t k ) [M(t) M (t k ) The first sum is F(s) measurable. The conditional expectation of the second term is E [ (t l ) [M (t l+ ) M (t l ) F(s) (t l ) [E [M (t l+ ) F(s) M (t l ) (t l ) [M(s) M (t l ). Here we have used that M (t l ) is F(s) measurable. Furthermore, the martingale property of M(t) implied that E [M (t l+ ) F(s) M(s). The conditional expectation of each element of the second sum is The author can be contacted via <<firstname>>.<<lastname>>@gmail.com and http://www.matthiasthul.com.

E [ (t j ) [M (t j+ ) M (t j ) F(s) E [E [ (t j ) [M (t j+ ) M (t j ) F (t j ) F(s) E [ (t j ) [E [M (t j+ ) F (t j ) M (t j ) F(s) E [ (t j ) [M (t j ) M (t j ) F(s). Here, we first used the tower law of iterated conditioning, then took out all F (t j ) measurable terms from the inner conditional expectation and finally used the martingale property of M(t) again. The same steps can be used to show that It follows that E [ (t k ) [M(t) M (t k ) F(s). l E [I(t) F(s) (t j ) [M (t j+ ) M (t j ) + (t l ) [M(s) M (t l ) j I(s) (q.e.d.) Exercise 4.4 (Stratonovich integral) (i) Since the elements in the sum are independent, we start by computing the mean and the variance of ( W ( tj) W (tj ) ) 2. This is completely analogous to the proof of Theorem 3.4.3. [ (W ( E t [ (W ( t E Var [ (W ( t j j) W (tj ) ) 2 Var [ W ( tj) W (tj ) t j t j j) W (tj ) ) [ 4 (W ( ) 3E t j W (tj ) ) 2 2 ( ) 3 t 2 j t j ) W (tj ) ) 2 3 ( ) t 2 ( ) j t j t 2 ( ) j t j 2 t 2 j t j Here, we have used that the forth moment of a normal random variable is three times its variance squared. The mean and variance of Q Π/2 are then given by E [ n [ (W ( ) Q Π/2 E t j W (tj ) ) 2 j n t j t j j 2 n j t j+ t j 2 2 T

Var [ Q Π/2 lim Var [ Q Π/2 Π n [ (W ( ) Var t j W (tj ) ) 2 j n j Π 2 2 ( ) t 2 n j t j n j j 2 (t j+ t j ) 2 T (q.e.d.) 2 (t j+ t j ) 2 Since the expected value of Q Π/2 is the same for all partitions, but the variance as limit zero when the maximum partition size gets smaller, we can conclude that Q Π/2 has limit T. 2 (ii) We expand the sum in the definition of the Stratonovich integral and add the terms necessary to obtain an Itô integral over the partition Q Π/2. T W (t) dw (t) n lim W ( tj) (W (tj+ ) W (t j )) Π j+ n { lim W ( tj) W (tj+ ) W ( tj) W (tj ) ± W ( t 2 j) ± 2W (tj ) W ( ) t j ± W (tj ) 2} Π j+ n { lim W ( tj) W (tj+ ) W ( ) } t 2 n { j + lim W (tj ) W ( tj) W (tj ) 2} Π Π j+ j+ j+ n { + lim W (t j ) 2 2W (t j ) W ( ) ( ) } t j + W t 2 j Π T n ( W (t)dw (t) + lim W (t j ) 2 W ( ) ) t 2 2 j Π 2 W 2 (T ) (q.e.d.) j+ In the last step, we have used the result that T W (t)dw (t) 2 W 2 (T ) 2 T, as e.g. shown in Example 4.3.2 and the quadratic variation of the Stratonovich integral that we calculated in part (i). 3

Exercise 4.5 (Solving the generalized geometric Brownian motion equation) Let f(t, x) ln x. We have and t, x x, 2 f x 2 x 2 (ds(t)) 2 σ 2 (t)s 2 (t)dt. Applying Itô s lemma, the differential of the log stock price d ln S(t) becomes In integral form, we get d ln S(t) df(t, S(t)) S(t) ds(t) 2 S 2 (t) (ds(t))2 ln S(t) ln S() + Taking the exponential yields α(t)dt + σ(t)dw (t) 2 σ2 (t)dt ( α(t) ) 2 σ2 (t) dt + σ(t)dw (t). { S(t) S() exp ( α(s) ) 2 σ2 (s) ds + ( α(s) ) 2 σ2 (s) ds + The distribution of S(t) will in general not be log-normal. σ(s)dw (s). () } σ(s)dw (s). In order to have lognormality for S(t), we require ln S(t) to be normally distributed. By Theorem 4.4.9, the Itô integral in Equation () is only guaranteed to be normally distributed if α(t) and σ(t) are deterministic functions of time. In this case ( ln S(t) N ( α(s) ) 2 σ2 (s) ds, ) σ 2 (s)ds. Note that this includes the less general case of a Geometric Brownian Motion with α(t) ᾱ and σ(t) σ, i.e the drift and diffusion coefficient being a constant as it is assumed in the Black-Scholes model. 4

Exercise 4.6 Let f(t, x) S()e x. We have Now define t, x f(x), 2 f x 2 f(x). X(t) (α 2 σ2 ) t + σw (t). By the Itô formula, the differential of S(t) is given by ds(t) df(t, X(t)) S(t)dX(t) + 2 S(t)dX(t)dX(t) αs(t)dt 2 σ2 S(t)dt + σs(t)dw (t) + 2 σ2 S(t)dt αs(t)dt + σs(t)dw (t). Now let f(t, x) x p such that t, x pxp, 2 f x 2 p(p )xp. Using the Itô formula to compute the differential of d (S p (t)) yields d (S p (t)) d (f(t, S(t))) ps p (t)ds(t) + 2 p(p )Sp 2 (t)ds(t)ds(t) αps p (t)dt + σps p (t)dw (t) + 2 σ2 p(p )S p (t)dt (α + 2 ) (p ) ps p (t)dt + σps p (t)dw (t). Exercise 4.7 (i) Let f(t, x) x 4. We have t, x 4x3, 2 f x 2 2x2. 5

Using the Itô formula to compute the differential of d (W 4 (t)) yields d ( W 4 (t) ) 4W 3 (t)dw (t) + 6W 2 (t)dt W 4 (t) 4 T W 3 (t)dw (t) + 6 T W 2 (t)dt Note that there is in general a constant of integration in the second equation. But since W 4 (), we omitted it directly. (ii) Taking expectations on both sides and using that an Itô integral is a martingale that starts at zero yields E [ W 4 (t) [ T 4E (iii) Let f(t, x) x 6. We have [ T W 3 (t)dw (t) + 6E T 6 E [ W 2 (t) T dt 6 tdt T 6 3T 2 (q.e.d.) 2 t2 W 2 (t)dt t, x 6x5, 2 f x 2 3x4. Using the Itô formula to compute the differential of d (W 6 (t)) yields d ( W 6 (t) ) 6W 5 (t)dw (t) + 5W 4 (t)dt W 6 (t) 6 T W 5 (t)dw (t) + 5 T W 4 (t)dt Taking expectations on both sides and using the result in part (ii) yields E [ W 6 (t) [ T 6E 5 T 5 t 3 T 5T 3 [ T W 5 (t)dw (t) + 3E E [ W 4 (t) T dt 5 3t 2 dt W 4 (t)dt 6

Exercise 4.8 (Solving the Vasicek equation) (i) Let f(t, x) e βt x. We have t βf(t, x), x eβt, 2 f x 2. Using the Itô formula, we can compute the differential of d ( e βt R(t) ) to be d ( e βt R(t) ) df(t, R(t)) βe βt R(t)dt + e βt dr(t) βe βt R(t)dt + e βt αdt βe βt R(t)dt + e βt σdw (t) e βt αdt + e βt σdw (t) (2) (ii) Integrating Equation (2) yields e βt R(t) R() + e βu αdu + t R() + α + σ R() + α β Thus, R(t) is given by β eβu e βu σdw (u) e bu dw (u) ( e βt ) + σ e bu dw (u) R(t) e βt R() + α ( ) e βt + e βt σ e bu dw (u) β This is the same expression as given in Example 4.4.. Note that the solution strategy employed is very common for stochastic differential equations with a geometric drift term. Let X ( t) α(t)x(t)dt +.... Then by computing the differential of e α(t)t X ( t), we can remove the geometric drift. 7

Exercise 4.9 (i) { Ke rτ N (d ) Ke rτ exp 2π { K exp 2π d2 2σ 2 τ K { exp 2π 2 } ( ( x ) ln K 2σ 2 τ + (r 2 ) )} 2 σ2 τ 2 + 2rσ 2 τ 2 K { exp 2π 2σ 2 τ (r + 2 ) ) 2 σ2 τ 2 + + (r 2 ) } 2 τ) σ2 rτ ( ( x ) ( x ) ( ln 2 + 2 ln r ) K K 2 σ2 τ ( ( x ) ( x ) ( ln 2 + 2 ln r ) K K 2 σ2 τ ( x ) } ± ln K K { ( x )} { exp ln exp 2π K ( x ) ( +2 ln r + ) K 2 σ2 τ + { x exp 2π 2σ 2 τ xn (d + ) (q.e.d.) ( ( x ) ln 2 2σ 2 τ K (r + 2 ) )} 2 σ2 τ 2 ( ( x ) ln + (r + 2 ) ) } 2 K σ2 τ (ii) c x [ xn (d+ ) Ke rτ N (d ) x N (d + ) + xn (d + ) d + x Ke rτ N (d ) d x N (d + ) (q.e.d.) Here, we used that as well as the result from (i). (iii) First, note that d + x d x xσ τ 8

d ± t [ ( x ) t σ ln + (r ± 2 ) T t K σ2 [ ( x ) 2σ ln + (T t) 3 K (T t) (r ± 2 σ2 ) (T t) (r σ ± 2 ) T t σ2 and consequently d + t d t σ 2 T t. We thus get c t t [ xn (d+ ) Ke r(t t) N (d ) xn (d + ) d + t rke r(t t) N (d ) Ke r(t t) N (d ) d ( t xn d+ (d + ) t d ) rke r(t t) N (d ) t σx 2 T t N (d + ) rke r(t t) N (d ) (q.e.d.). (iv) We first need to compute c x x, i.e. the gamma of the option. Substituting into the PDE yields c xx N (d + ) d + x xσ τ N (d + ) c t (t, x) + rxc x (t, x) + 2 σ2 c xx (t, x) rc(t, x) σx 2 τ N (d + ) rke rτ N (d ) + rxn (d + ) + σx 2 τ N (d + ) rxn (d + ) +rke rτ N (d ) (q.e.d.). (v) (vi) (vii) 9

Exercise 4. When dynamically replicating an mispriced option in the Black-Scholes model, we have to decide upon which volatility to use to compute the hedge ratio. In this case, the market uses a volatility of σ to price the option at all times t [, T. Knowing that all model assumption hold but with the actual volatility of the underlying diffusion being σ 2 > σ, we will enter a long position in the underpriced european call option and dynamically delta hedge it by shorting (t) c S shares of the underlying. But since the delta itself depends upon the volatility, there are two possibilities to do this: Either we use the market implied volatility (σ ) or the actual volatility (σ 2 ) to compute the hedge ratio. These two approaches will in general lead to different returns. As implicitly suggested by the exercise, we will use the delta calculated based upon the implied volatility to hedge the long position in the european call option. Let f(t, x) e rt x. We have t rf(t, x), x e rt, 2 f x 2. Apply Itô s lemma to the differential of the discounted portfolio value d (e rt X(t)) d ( e rt X(t) ) df(t, X(t)) re rt X(t)dt + e rt dx(t) e rt ( rx(t)dt + dx(t)). (3) We furthermore note that the differential of the call option price dc(t, S(t)) evolves according to dc(t, S(t)) c c dt + t S ds(t) + 2 c 2 S 2 (ds(t))2 ( c t + ) 2 σ2 2S 2 (t) 2 c dt + c ds(t). (4) S 2 S Plugging the given differential of the portfolio value and the differential of the call option price in Equation (4) back into Equation (3) yields

d ( e rt X(t) ) ( c e [ rx(t)dt rt + t + ) 2 σ2 2S 2 (t) 2 c dt + c S 2 S ds(t) c c ds(t) + rx(t)dt rc(t, S(t))dt + rs(t) S 2 ( σ 2 2 σ) 2 S 2 (t) 2 c S dt 2 [ c e rt t + 2 σ2 S 2 (t) 2 c c + rs(t) S2 S S dt rc(t, S(t)) dt. We note that the call price c(t, S(t)) is a specific solution to the Black-Scholes PDE where the volatility is equal to σ c c + rs(t) t S + 2 σ2 S 2 (t) 2 c rc(t, S(t)) S2 for the payoff-specific terminal condition c(t, S(T )) max(s(t ) K, ), S(T ) and the boundary conditions c(t, ), t T and lim S(t) { c(t, S(t)) ( S(t) Ke r(t t) )}, t T. Using this result, it directly follows that d (e rt X(t)). Exercise 4.3 (Decomposition of correlated Brownian motions into independent Brownian motions) The differential form of B (t) and B 2 (t) are given by db (t) dw (t) db 2 (t) ρ(t)dw (t) + ρ 2 (t)dw 2 (t). This allows us to express the differentials of W (t) and W 2 (t) in terms of the changes in the correlated Brownian motions B (t) and B 2 (t) dw (t) db (t) dw 2 (t) ρ(t) ρ2 (t) db (t) + ρ2 (t) db 2(t). (5) We have to show that these two processes are independent Brownian motions. While it is obvious that W (t) is a Brownian motion since it is just equal to B (t), we have to check if this also holds for W 2 (t). According to Lévy s theorem, any continuous martingale M(t) with M() and quadratic variation equal to [M, M(t) t (i.e. dm(t)dm(t) dt) is a

Brownian motion. Furthermore, according to the extended Lévy theorem, two Brownian motions, with zero cross variation (i.e. dw (t)dw 2 (t) ) are independent. (i) Continuity: The continuity of W 2 (t) follows from the continuity of the two Brownian motions B (t) and B 2 (t). To see this explicitly, we write down the integral form of Equation (5) to get W 2 (t) W 2 () ρ(s) t ρ2 (s) db (s) + ρ2 (s) db 2(s). (6) Since an Itô integral is a continuous function of its upper limit of integration, W 2 (t) is continuous as well. (ii) Martingale property: The martingale property of W 2 (t) directly follows from the absence of a drift term in Equation (5) or its representation as an Itô integral in Equation (6). (iii) Starting at zero: Given the information in the exercise, we can t show that W 2 (). When integrating Equation (5), we have to add a constant of integration that might take any value in R. Similarly, we could argue that in the equation for db 2 (t), only the differential dw 2 (t) and thus its initial value does not matter. (iv) Unit quadratic variation: The quadratic variation of W 2 (t) can be computed as dw 2 (t)dw 2 (t) and it follows that [W 2, W 2 (t) t. ρ 2 (t) ρ 2 (t) dt + ρ 2 (t) dt 2 ρ2 (t) ρ 2 (t) dt ρ2 (t) dt dt (q.e.d.). ρ 2 (t) 2

(v) Zero cross variation: Using db (t)db (t) dt and db (t)db 2 (t) ρ(t)dt, the instantaneous cross variation between W (t) and W 2 (t) can be computed as ρ(t) dw (t)dw 2 (t) ρ2 (t) dt + ρ(t) dt. ρ2 (t) This establishes that W (t) and W 2 (t) have zero cross-covariance. An alternative proof of this result directly computes db (t)db 2 (t) db (t)db 2 (t) ρ(t)dt + ρ 2 (t)dw (t)dw 2 (t). This equation is only equal to ρ(t)dt as given in the exercise, when ρ2 (t)dw (t)dw 2 (t). Since ρ (, ), the square root term can never be equal to zero and we conclude that dw (t)dw 2 (t). Exercise 4.5 (Creating correlated Brownian motions from independent ones) (i) Similar to Exercise 4.3, we use Lévy s theorem to show that B i (t) is a Brownian motion for each i,..., m. Since W j () for each j,..., d, it directly follows from the definition of B i (t) that B i (). Furthermore, due to its representation as a sum of Itô integrals, we obtain both the continuity and the martingale property. It remains to show that B i (t) has quadratic variation [B i, B i (t) t or equivalently that db i (t)db i (t) dt. In differential form, B i (t) is db i (t) σ i (t) d σ ij (t)dw j (t). j 3

Using the independence of the d-dimensional vector of Brownian motions, we get db i (t)db i (t) σ 2 i (t) d σij(t)dt 2 j (ii) Again using independence we get d j σ2 ij(t) d dt j σ2 ij (t)dt (q.e.d.). db i (t)db k (t) σ i (t)σ k (t) d σ ij σ kj (t)dt ρ ik (t)dt. Exercise 4.6 (Creating independent Brownian motions to represent correlated ones) In differential form and using matrix notation, we have db(t) A(t)dW (t) or dw (t) A (t)db(t). We use the multidimensional Lévy theorem (a straight forward extension of Theorem 4.6.5) to show that W (t) is a vector of independent Brownian motions. We need to check the following conditions: j Martingale property: Since we can represent W (t) in terms of an integral constant plus and Itô integral W (t) W () + A (u)db(u) W i (t) W i () + m j a ij (u)db j(u) it follows that each element W i (t) of this vector is a martingale (Theorem 4.3.(iv)). Continuity: By Theorem 4.3.(i), Itô integrals have continuous sample paths. Starting at zero: Similar to Exercise 4.3(iii), we can t show that W () is a vector of zeros. In the first point, we could choose the integration constant W () arbitrarily as only the change dw (t) is relevant in the definition of B(t). However, the exercise is only asking for the existence of a vector of Brownian motions W (t). Thus, by setting W () we can find such a vector. 4

Unit quadratic variation and zero cross variation: We need to show that each W i (t) has unit quadratic variation but zero cross variation with any other W j (t) for j i or equivalently that dw (t)dw T (t) I where I is the m m identity matrix. This can be easily done using matrix notation. We get dw (t)dw T (t) A (t)db(t) ( A (t)db(t) ) T A (t)db(t)db T (t)a T (t) A (t)c(t)a T (t) A (t)a(t)a T (t)a T I (q.e.d.). Exercise 4.7 (Instantaneous correlation) (i) We first note that B (t + ɛ) B 2 (t + ɛ) B (t ) B 2 (t ) + +ɛ t d (B (s)b 2 (s)). By Corollary 4.6.3, we have for the differential of the product of the two Brownian motions d (B (t)b 2 (t)) B 2 (t)db (t) + B (t)db 2 (t) + db (t)db 2 (t) B 2 (t)db (t) + B (t)db 2 (t) + ρdt. Thus, B (t + ɛ) B 2 (t + ɛ) B (t ) B 2 (t )+ and +ɛ B 2 (s)db (s)+ +ɛ t t B (s)db 2 (s)+ρɛ 5

E [B (t + ɛ) B 2 (t + ɛ) F (t ) B (t ) B 2 (t ) + ρɛ where we used that the two integrals are independent of the filtration F (t ) and that by Theorem 4.3.(iv) Itô integrals are martingales. Finally, E [(B (t + ɛ) B (t )) (B 2 (t + ɛ) B 2 (t )) F (t ) E [B (t + ɛ) B 2 (t + ɛ) F (t ) E [B (t + ɛ) B 2 (t ) F (t ) E [B (t ) B 2 (t + ɛ) F (t ) + E [B (t ) B 2 (t ) F (t ) B (t ) B 2 (t ) + ρɛ B 2 (t ) E [B (t + ɛ) B (t ) E [B 2 (t + ɛ) + B (t ) B 2 (t ) ρɛ. (q.e.d.) (ii) The means are M i (ɛ) E [X i (t + ɛ) X i (t ) F (t ) +ɛ t Θ i du Θ i ɛ (q.e.d.). Where we again used that the Riemann integral is deterministic and that the Itô integral is a martingale with zero expected value. The variances are V i (ɛ) E [ (X i (t + ɛ) X i (t )) 2 F (t ) Mi 2 (ɛ) [ ( +ɛ +ɛ ) 2 E Θ i du + σ i db i (u) Θ 2 i ɛ 2 t t ( +ɛ ) [ +ɛ [ ( +ɛ Θ i du E σ i db i (u) + E t t t +ɛ t σ 2 i du σ 2 i ɛ (q.e.d.). 6 ) 2 σ i db i (u)

Here, we used that the increment in the Itô processes is independent of the filtration F (t ) in the second step. We can take the deterministic time integral out of the expectation in the third step and again reply on the martingale property of the Itô integral in the fourth step to eliminate this term. We further use the Itô isometry (Theorem 4.3.(v)) to transform the squared Itô integral into a Riemann integral in the fourth step. The covariance is Θ du + Θ 2 du + C(ɛ) E [(X (t + ɛ) X (t )) (X 2 (t + ɛ) X 2 (t )) F (t ) M (ɛ)m 2 (ɛ) [( +ɛ +ɛ ) ( +ɛ +ɛ ) E σ db (u) σ 2 db 2 (u) Θ Θ 2 ɛ 2 t ( t +ɛ t ) [ t +ɛ t t ( t +ɛ ) [ +ɛ Θ du E σ 2 db 2 (u) + Θ 2 du E σ db (u) t [( +ɛ t ) ( +ɛ t ) t +E σ db (u) σ 2 db 2 (u) t [( t +ɛ t ) ( t +ɛ ) E σ db (u) σ 2 db 2 (u) t t In order to solve the remaining expectation, we first define for t t I i (t) By the Itô product rule, we have t σ i db i (u) di i (t) σ i db i (t) d (I (t)i 2 (t)) (t) I 2 (t)di (t) + I (t)di 2 (t) + di (t)di 2 (t) or I (t)i 2 (t) I (t ) I 2 (t ) + Thus, t d (I (u)i 2 (u)) I 2 (u)di (u) + I (u)di 2 (u) + ρσ σ 2 du. t t t 7

+ɛ C(ɛ) E [I (t + ɛ) I 2 (t + ɛ) ρσ σ 2 du ρσ σ 2 ɛ. (q.e.d.). t Consequently, we have for the correlation between the increments of the Itô processes C(ɛ) V (ɛ)v 2 (ɛ) ρσ σ 2 ɛ σ 2 σ 2 2ɛ 2 ρ. (iii) We have M i (ɛ) E [X i (t + ɛ) X (t ) F (t ) [ +ɛ +ɛ E Θ i (u)du + σ i (u)db i (u) F (t ) t t [ t +ɛ E Θ i (u)du F (t ). t We first note that by Definition.2., the real constant M can be considered a (trivial) random variable as well. Here {M B} Ω, i.e. we do not learn anything about the particular outcome ω Ω by observing M. We now apply the dominated convergence theorem (Theorem.4.9) to the sequence of random variables I(ɛ) ɛ +ɛ t Θ i (u)du that is bounded in absolute value by M. We have lim ɛ ɛ M i(ɛ) lim E [I(ɛ) F (t ) ɛ [ E lim I(ɛ) ɛ F (t ) [ E lim ɛ ɛ [I () + I () ɛ + o (ɛ) F (t ) E [Θ i (t ) F (t ) Θ i (t ) (q.e.d.). Here, we used a Taylor series expansion of the integral around ɛ where I() and I () Θ i (t ). 8

(iv) Similar to the hint, we define for t > t Y i (t) and get t σ i (u)db i (u) D ij (ɛ) E [(X i (t + ɛ) X i (t )) (X j (t + ɛ) X j (t )) F (t ) M i (ɛ)m j (ɛ) [( +ɛ ) ( +ɛ ) E Y i (t + ɛ) + Θ i (u)du Y j (t + ɛ) + Θ j (u)du F (t ) M i (ɛ)m j (ɛ) E [Y i (t + ɛ) Y j (t + ɛ) F (t ) + t ( +ɛ ( +ɛ ) + Θ i (u)du E [Y j (t + ɛ) F (t ) t E [Y i (t + ɛ) Y j (t + ɛ) F (t ) t t ) Θ j (u)du E [Y i (t + ɛ) F (t ) Here, we followed the same main steps as in the derivation in (ii). We now apply the Itô product rule again to compute the remaining expectation and get [ +ɛ +ɛ D ij (ɛ) E Y j (u)dy i (u) + Y i (u)dy j (u) + t t [ t +ɛ E ρ ij (u)σ i (u)σ j (u)du F (t ). t +ɛ t dy i (u)dy j (u) F (t ) We now apply the same limit argument as in (iii) and start by defining the sequence of random variables I ij (ɛ) ɛ +ɛ that is bounded in absolute value by M 3. We get t ρ ij (u)σ i (u)σ j (u)du 9

lim ɛ ɛ D ij(ɛ) lim E [I ij (ɛ) F (t ) ɛ [ E lim I(ɛ) ɛ F (t ) [ E lim ɛ ɛ [I() + I ()ɛ + o(ɛ) F (t ) E [ρ ij (t ) σ i (t ) σ j (t ) F (t ) ρ ij (t ) σ i (t ) σ j (t ) (q.e.d.). (v) We showed this already implicitly in the derivation of the means and covariances. We have D ij (ɛ) E [I ij (ɛ) F (t ) E [I() + I ()ɛ + o(ɛ) F (t ) E [ρ ij (t ) σ i (t ) σ j (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ) F (t ) ρ ij (t ) σ i (t ) σ j (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ) V i (ɛ) σk 2 (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ) C(ɛ) ρ (t ) σ (t ) σ 2 (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ) for i j k for i j (q.e.d.). (vi) Finally, lim ɛ C(ɛ) V (ɛ)v 2 (ɛ) lim ɛ ρ (t ) σ (t ) σ 2 (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ) (σ 2 (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ)) (σ 2 2 (t ) ɛ + o(ɛ)) ρ (t ) σ (t ) σ 2 (t ) lim + o(ɛ) ɛ σ 2 (t ) σ2 2 (t ) ρ (t ) (q.e.d.). Exercise 4.8 (i) Let f(t, x) exp { θx ( r + 2 θ2) t }. We have Itô s lemma yields (r t + 2 ) θ2 f(t, x), x 2 θf(t, x), 2 f x 2 θ2 f(t, x).

dζ(t) df(t, W (t)) (r + 2 ) θ2 ζ(t)dt θζ(t)dw (t) + 2 θ2 ζ(t)dt rζ(t)dt θζ(t)dw (t) (q.e.d.). (ii) By Itô s product rule (Corollary 4.6.3) we get d (ζ(t)x(t)) ζ(t)dx(t) + X(t)dζ(t) + dx(t)dζ(t) rζ(t)x(t)dt + ζ(t) (t)(α r)s(t)dt + ζ(t) (t)σs(t)dw (t) θζ(t)x(t)dw (t) rζ(t)x(t)dt θζ(t) (t)σs(t)dt ζ(t) ( (t)σs(t) θx(t)) dw (t). (7) In the last step, we have used the fact that θσ α r. Equation (7) shows that ζ(t)x(t) is a martingale, since all dt-terms vanish in the differential. Equivalently, we could express ζ(t)x(t) by a single Itô integral. Since all Itô integrals are martingales, so is ζ(t)x(t) ζ(t)x(t) ζ()x() + (iii) First, note that ζ(s) ( (s)σs(s) θx(s)) dw (s). ζ() exp { θw ()}. Now let (t) be an adapted portfolio process such that, X(T ) V (T ), i.e. the final value of the trading strategy is equal to the final value of the F(T ) measurable random variable V (T ). As has been shown in (ii), ζ(t)x(t) is a martingale, i.e. We obtain E [ζ(t)x(t) F(s) ζ(s)x(s), s t. X() ζ()x() E [ζ(t )X(T ) E [ζ(t )V (T ). 2

Exercise 4.9 (i) By Lévy s theorem it is sufficient to show that B(t) is a continuous martingale starting at zero with unit quadratic variation in order to establish that it is a Brownian motion. We first note that B(t) is an Itô integral with B(). By Theorem 4.3., Itô integrals are continuous martingales. The quadratic variation of B(t) is (db(t)) 2 (sign (W (t)) dw (t)) 2 sign 2 (W (t)) (dw (t)) 2 dt and it follows that it is a Brownian motion. (ii) We have d (B(t)W (t)) B(t)dW (t) + W (t)db(t) + db(t)dw (t) B(t)dW (t) + W (t)sign (W (t)) dw (t) + sign (W (t)) dt and since B()W () we get B(t)W (t) B(s)dW (s) + W (s)sign (W (s)) dw (s) + sign (W (s)) ds Since Itô integrals are martingales it follows that [ E [B(t)W (t) E sign (W (s)) ds E [sign (W (s)) ds. In the last step, we have used that with probability one half, sign (W (t)) ± for t >. (iii) Let f(t, x) x 2. We have t, x 2x, 2 f x 2 2. Using the Itô formula to compute the differential of dw 2 (t) yields dw 2 (t) 2W (t)dw (t) + dt (q.e.d.) 22

(iv) We have d ( B(t)W 2 (t) ) B(t)dW 2 (t) + W 2 (t)db(t) + db(t)dw 2 (t) 2B(t)W (t)dw (t) + B(t)dt + W 2 (t)sign (W (t)) dw (t) +2W (t)sign (W (t)) dt. Integrating both sides yields B(t)W 2 (t) + 2B(s)W (s)dw (s) + 2W (s)sign (W (s)) ds. B(s)ds + W 2 (s)sign (W (s)) dw (s) We take expectation on both sides and again use the martingale property of the Itô integral to get E [ B(t)W 2 (t) [ E B(s)ds + 2W (s)sign (W (s)) ds In order to evaluate the first Riemann integral, we set f(t, x) tx such that f t (t, x) x and f x (t, x) t. We apply the Itô formula to obtain the differential of tw (t) as (8) Integrating and rearranging yields d (tb(t)) B(t)dt + tdb(t). T B(t)dt T B(T ) T tdb(t) T (T t)db(t). The last term is an Itô integral of a deterministic integrand and thus normally distributed with zero mean and variance T (T t) 2 dt 3 (T t)3 T 3 T 3. It follows that the first term in Equation (8) is zero and we get E [ B(t)W 2 (t) [ [ E 2W (s)sign (W (s)) ds E 2 W (s) ds 23

It is obvious, that the expected value is strictly positive for t > since the integrand is non-negative and almost surely strictly positive. If B(t) and W (t) are independent, then by Theorem 2.2.5 any two function f (B(t)) and g (W (t)) are independent. Now let g (B(t)) B(t) and f (W (t)) W 2 (t) then by Theorem 2.2.7 independence implies that E [B(t)W 2 (t) E [B(t) E [W 2 (t). But since E [B(t) we would require E [B(t)W 2 (t). We have shown above that E [B(t)W 2 (t) > and thus B(t) and W (t) are not independent. Exercise 4.2 (Local time) (i) f (x) f (x) if x > K undefined if x K x < K if x K undefined if x K (ii) f(w (T )) f(w ()) + T I {W (t)>k} dw (t) (9) Using that by Theorem 3.3.2(i), W (T ) N (, T ), we can compute the expected value of the right hand side as 24

E [f(w (T )) E [ (W (T ) K) + ( ) + T x K N (x)dx T ( ) T x K K T T 2π T T K T N (x)dx xn (x)dx KN ( T K ) K T 2π e K 2 2π e ( xe x 2 2 dx KN K ) T x 2 2 K T KN ( T K ) ( 2T KN K ) T Since the Itô integral is a martingale starting at zero, it has zero expected value and we get for the right hand side [ T E [f(w ()) + E I {W (t)>k} dw (t) E [ (W () K) + ( K) +. This shows that Equation (9) does not hold. (iii) The answer to this question is pretty much given in the hints already. f (x) f (x) if x K 2n n(x K) + if K x K + 2 2n 2n if x K + 2n if x < K 2n n if K < x < K + 2n 2n if x > K + 2n 25

(iv) Similar to (iii), there is not too much to add to the hints. We first note that the intervals of the piecewise function definition have limits [ lim n [ lim, K n 2n lim n K 2n, K + 2n [ K + ) 2n, [, K) K (K, ). Thus, lim f n(x) n lim n f n(x) if x K x K (x K) + if x K if x < K if x K. () 2 if x > K (v) Let M(T ) max t T W (T ) be the maximum of a fixed Brownian motion path ω during the time interval [, T. By assumption, M(T ) < K and by definition T L K (T ) lim n n I {W (t) (K 2n,K+ 2n)} dt. Now, from M(T ) < K it follows that there exists an n such that K 2n > M(T ) for all n n. Consequently, for all n n, the indicator function inside the integral evaluates to zero for all t [, T and we get L K (T ). (vi) Taking expectation on both sides and using that by Theorem 4.3.(iv) the Itô integral is a martingale with zero expected value yields E [L K (T ) E [ (W (T ) K) + >, 26

where the inequality follows from our result in (ii). Although it is not immediately obvious from the final result, it is enough to note that by the normal distribution of W (T ) values of W (T ) > K have a strictly positive probability for all finite levels of K and thus the expectation is strictly positive as well. Now, P {L K (T ) } E [L K (T ) and just showed that the implication does not hold. cannot have that P {L K (T ) }. Thus, by contradiction we Exercise 4.2 (Stop-loss start-gain paradox) (i) The stop-loss start-gain strategy involves holding a long position in one share whenever the stock price strictly exceeds the strike price and holding no position otherwise. The crucial point is, that buys and sells are not made at the same price and thus the hedger incurs a cost every time he enters and unwinds the stock position. To make it clear, assume that we by one stock whenever the price level K + ɛ is crossed from below (and we had no position before) and sell one stock whenever the price level K is crossed from above (and we were long one stock before). Building up and subsequently unwinding the stock position thus yields to a loss of ɛ. Since the mathematical model of a geometric Brownian motion is a process with continuous sample paths, ɛ can theoretically made arbitrarily small. However, smaller values of ɛ lead to more frequent transactions. Real world stock prices however don t take values in R but are usually quoted in full USD-cents. Furthermore, they don t move continuously but jump. Thus, each time the stock price crosses the strike price the hedger encounters a friction of at least one USD-cent. Furthermore, the strategy ignores transaction cost that can become very significant for high number of buys and sells in the stock. (ii) Taking expectation and using that by Theorem 4.3.(i) the Itô integral is a martingale with zero expected value yields E [X(T ). However, 27

E [ (S(T ) K) + >. ( { S() exp 2 σ2 T + σ } + T x K) N (x)dx ( { S() exp 2 σ2 T + σ } T x K ln ( S() K ) 2 σ2 σ T ) N (x)dx From the second equation and the properties of the normal distribution it is obvious that the integrand is non-negative everywhere and that it takes strictly positive values for some values of x. Thus, the expected value is strictly positive as well. In conclusion P ( X(T ) (S(T ) K) +) <, i.e. there are some paths where the stop-loss start-gain strategy does replicate the option payoff (i.e. all paths where the maximum stock price over the interval [, T is strictly less than K). However, since the expected value of the payoff of the strategy does not agree with the expected value of the option payoff, we do not have X(T ) (S(T ) K) + almost surely. This also follows from the result on the local time in Exercise 4.2. Since a Brownian motion spends a non-zero time at any level with positive probability, so does it at the strike K. But once the strike is crossed, the hedger incurs a cost and the exact replication fails. 28