TESTING TRADEOFF AND PECKING ORDER PREDICTIONS ABOUT DIVIDENDS AND DEBT. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Similar documents
TESTING TRADEOFF AND PECKING ORDER PREDICTIONS ABOUT DIVIDENDS AND DEBT. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French *

DIVIDENDS, DEBT, INVESTMENT, AND EARNINGS. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay? Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

Debt and Taxes: Evidence from a Bank based system

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO MANAGING FINANCIAL POLICY: EVIDENCE FROM THE FINANCING OF EXTRAORDINARY INVESTMENTS A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Financial pressure and balance sheet adjustment by UK firms

Determinants of Target Capital Structure: The Case of Dual Debt and Equity Issues

The Determinants of Capital Structure of Stock Exchange-listed Non-financial Firms in Pakistan

Dissecting Anomalies. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French. Abstract

A Comparison of Capital Structure. in Market-based and Bank-based Systems. Name: Zhao Liang. Field: Finance. Supervisor: S.R.G.

On the Capital Structure of Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs)

Chapter 18 Interest rates / Transaction Costs Corporate Income Taxes (Cash Flow Effects) Example - Summary for Firm U Summary for Firm L

The notion that income taxes play an important role in the

THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE S DETERMINANT IN FIRM LOCATED IN INDONESIA

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

Capital Structure in the Real Estate and Construction Industry

Firms Histories and Their Capital Structures *

THE SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO CAPITAL STRUCTURE TARGET BEFORE AND AFTER FINANCIAL CRISIS: EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIAN STATE OWNED ENTERPRISES

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan

A literature review of the trade off theory of capital structure

Capital Structure Determinants within the Automotive Industry

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 8 Number 2 Summer 1995 THE 1986 TAX REFORM ACT AND STRATEGIC LEVERAGE DECISIONS

A STUDY ON THE FACTORS INFLUENCING THE LEVERAGE OF INDIAN COMPANIES

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Determinants of Capital Structure: A Long Term Perspective

Determinants of Capital Structure of Commercial Banks in Ethiopia. Weldemikael Shibru. A Thesis Submitted to. The Department of Accounting and Finance

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

Does Insider Ownership Matter for Financial Decisions and Firm Performance: Evidence from Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan

Financial Conservatism: Evidence on Capital Structure from Low Leverage Firms. Bernadette A. Minton and Karen H. Wruck* Draft: July 9, 2001.

Dividend Changes and Future Profitability

The International Evidence on the Pecking Order Hypothesis

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Empirical Analysis of Oil and Gas Firms during

The Impact of Ownership Structure and Capital Structure on Financial Performance of Vietnamese Firms

SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS

Key Influences on Loan Pricing at Credit Unions and Banks

THE DETERMINANTS OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE IN THE TEXTILE SECTOR OF PAKISTAN

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Chapter 13 Capital Structure and Distribution Policy

Debt Capacity and Tests of Capital Structure Theories

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

Determinants of Credit Rating and Optimal Capital Structure among Pakistani Banks

The Equity Premium. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Access from the University of Nottingham repository:

Capital Structure, Unleveraged Equity Beta, Profitability and other Corporate Characteristics: Evidence from Australia

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions

MASTER THESIS. Muhammad Suffian Tariq * MSc. Finance - CFA Track ANR Tilburg University. Supervisor: Professor Marco Da Rin

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Capital structure decisions

An Initial Investigation of Firm Size and Debt Use by Small Restaurant Firms

Determinants of Capital Structure: A Case of Life Insurance Sector of Pakistan

Stock Repurchases and the EPS Enhancement Fallacy

In for a Bumpy Ride? Cash Flow Risk and Dividend Payouts

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR

CHEN, ZHANQUAN (2013) The determinants of Capital structure of firms in Japan. [Dissertation (University of Nottingham only)] (Unpublished)

TRADE-OFF THEORY VS. PECKING ORDER THEORY EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM THE BALTIC COUNTRIES 3

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

CORPORATE CASH HOLDING AND FIRM VALUE

Discounting Rules for Risky Assets. Stewart C. Myers and Richard Ruback

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas

Testing Static Tradeoff Against Pecking Order Models. Of Capital Structure: A Critical Comment. Robert S. Chirinko. and. Anuja R.

A Reinterpretation of the Relation between Market-to-book ratio and Corporate Borrowing

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

Financial Flexibility, Performance, and the Corporate Payout Choice*

Capital Structure Determinants: An Inter-industry analysis For Dutch Firms

Management Ownership and Dividend Policy: The Role of Managerial Overconfidence

UNOBSERVABLE EFFECTS AND SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO TARGET CAPITAL STRUCTURE

EAST ASIAN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: A TEST OF THE RELATION BETWEEN CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND FIRM PERFORMANCE

Empirical Methods for Corporate Finance. Regression Discontinuity Design

Study of the Static Trade-Off Theory determinants vis-à-vis Capital Structure phenomenon in context of Pakistan s Chemical Industry

Determinants of Capital Structure: A comparison between small and large firms

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1

The Debt-Equity Choice of Japanese Firms

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

Firm Manipulation and Take-up Rate of a 30 Percent. Temporary Corporate Income Tax Cut in Vietnam

The Debt-Equity Choice of Japanese Firms

THE DETERMINANTS OF EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND THE LINK BETWEEN EXECUTIVE STOCK OPTION HOLDING AND FIRM PERFORMANCE CHNG BEY FEN

Capital Structure. Capital Structure. Konan Chan. Corporate Finance, Leverage effect Capital structure stories. Capital structure patterns

FIRM SIZE AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE: EVIDENCE USING DYNAMIC PANEL DATA VÍCTOR M. GONZÁLEZ FRANCISCO GONZÁLEZ

Overconfident CEOs and Capital Structure

The cross section of expected stock returns

The Use of Market Information in Bank Supervision: Interest Rates on Large Time Deposits

Managerial Incentives and Corporate Cash Holdings

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSIONS, RECOMMENDATIONS, AND LIMITATIONS. Capital structure decision is believed to play an important role in maximizing the

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

The Applicability of Pecking Order Theory in Kenyan Listed Firms

What is the effect of the financial crisis on the determinants of the capital structure choice of SMEs?

Maximizing the value of the firm is the goal of managing capital structure.

The Relationship between Investment Decisions and Financing Decisions: Iran Evidence

Premium Timing with Valuation Ratios

DET E R M I N A N T S O F C A P I T A L S T R U C T U R E

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Transcription:

First draft: August 1999 This draft: November 1999 Not for quotation Comments welcome TESTING TRADEOFF AND PECKING ORDER PREDICTIONS ABOUT DIVIDENDS AND DEBT Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract We test the dividend and leverage predictions of the tradeoff and pecking order models. As both models predict, more profitable firms have higher long-term dividend payouts, and firms with more investments have lower payouts. Confirming the pecking order model but contradicting the tradeoff model, more profitable firms are less levered. Firms with more investment opportunities are also less levered, which is in line with the tradeoff model and a complex version of the pecking order model. Firms with more investments have lower long-term dividend payouts, but dividends do not vary to accommodate short-term variation in investment. Confirming the pecking order model, short-term variation in investment and earnings is mostly absorbed by variation in debt. * Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago (Fama) and Sloan School of Management, MIT (French).

The finance literature offers two competing models of financing decisions. In the tradeoff model, firms identify their optimal leverage by weighing the costs and benefits of an additional dollar of debt. The benefits of debt include, for example, the tax deductibility of interest and the reduction of free cash flow problems. The costs of debt include potential bankruptcy costs and agency conflicts between stockholders and bondholders. At the optimal leverage, the benefit of the last dollar of debt just offsets the cost. The tradeoff model makes a similar prediction about dividends. Firms maximize value by selecting the dividend payout that equates the costs and benefits of the last dollar of dividends. Myers (1984) develops an alternative pecking order model of financing decisions. The pecking order arises if the costs of issuing new securities overwhelm other costs and benefits of dividends and debt. The financing costs that produce pecking order behavior include the transaction costs associated with new issues and the costs that arise because of management s superior information about the firm s prospects and the value of its risky securities. Because of these costs, firms finance new investments first with retained earnings, then with safe debt, then with risky debt, and finally, under duress, with equity. As a result, variation in a firm s leverage is driven not by the tradeoff model s costs and benefits of debt, but rather by the firm s net cash flows (cash earnings minus investment outlays). We test the dividend and leverage predictions of the tradeoff and pecking order models. We focus on predictions about (i) how long-term leverage and dividend payouts vary across firms with profitability, investment opportunities, and the volatility of earnings and cash flows; (ii) whether leverage is mean-reverting; and (iii) whether firms use dividends and/or debt to absorb short-term variation in earnings and investment. We address these questions with cross-section regressions. The dividend regressions build on Lintner s (1956) model, which has been found to be a good description of the dividend process [Allen and Michaely (1995)]. Previous research uses time-series regressions to fit the model. This approach has problems. Requiring, say, 20 years of data in each firm s regression limits the sample of firms, and even with 20 years of data, time-series regressions are imprecise. We estimate the model with year-by-year cross-section regressions. This approach allows us to use a long time period (1965-97) and large samples 1

of firms (an average of 1549 per regression). More important, the cross-section regressions are convenient for testing whether the target payout of the Lintner model varies across firms in the manner predicted by the tradeoff and pecking order models. The cross-section regressions are also powerful for identifying any short-term variation in dividends away from their targets to accommodate investment. To our knowledge, we are the first to test the predictions of the tradeoff and pecking order models about the dividend payout ratio. One can argue, however, that our leverage results largely just confirm previous evidence. Our retort is that the existing evidence is a bit piecemeal, it is often based on small samples, and it is uniformly subject to a statistical problem that clouds inferences. For example, studies of the determinants of target leverage usually estimate a single cross-section regression, using a short time period [Bradley, Jarrel, and Kim (1984), Long and Malitz (1985), Rajan and Zingales (1995), Titman and Wessels (1988)]. The samples in these tests are sometimes large; for example, Rajan and Zingales (1995) have 2079 firms in their tests on U.S. data. But the papers that use a single cross-section regression to study target leverage do not actually examine whether leverage tends to revert to a target. The few papers that test for mean reversion use small samples [143 firms in Auerbach (1985), 108 in Jalilvand and Harris (1984)]. Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999) is the only paper that addresses the response of debt to short-term variation in investment and earnings. It is limited to a small sample of 157 firms that survive the entire 1971-89 period. We jointly examine target leverage, the mean reversion of leverage, and the short-term response of leverage to variation in earnings and investment in annual samples that cover the 1965-97 period and include an average of 2844 firms. In our view, however, the serious problem in the empirical leverage literature is under-stated standard errors that cloud all inferences. Previous work uses either cross-section regressions or panel (pooled time-series and cross-section) regressions. When cross-section regressions are used, the inference problem due to correlation of the residuals across firms is ignored. The papers that use panel regressions ignore both the cross-correlation problem and the bias in the standard errors of regression slopes that arises because the residuals are correlated across years. 2

In the spirit of Fama and MacBeth (1973), we use year-by-year cross-section regressions to study the determinants of leverage (and dividends). We use the average slopes from these annual regressions and the time-series standard errors of the average slopes to draw inferences. The advantage of this approach is that the volatility of the year-by-year slopes automatically adjusts for the cross-correlation of the residuals. And we can use the time-series properties of the annual slopes to allow for autocorrelation. The adjustments are large. Cross-correlation almost always inflates the standard errors of the average slopes by a factor of more than two and often more than five. In the regressions for the determinants of target leverage, autocorrelation produces an additional increase of about 250 percent in the standard errors of the average slopes. The autocorrelation problem is less serious in the dividend regressions and the regressions that test the mean reversion of leverage, but allowing for autocorrelation nevertheless increases the standard errors of the average slopes by about 40 percent. A synopsis of our evidence is difficult since the tests are tightly linked to our interpretation of the tradeoff and pecking order models. Thus, we leave an overview of the results to the conclusions. (The impatient reader can of course look ahead.) For the moment, suffice it to say that though motivated by different forces, the tradeoff and pecking order models share many predictions about dividends and debt. These shared predictions do well in our tests. On issues where the two models differ, we identify one big contradiction of the tradeoff model, one less serious contradiction of the pecking order, and one issue (the mean reversion of leverage) on which the data are reluctant to speak. The story proceeds as follows. Section I summarizes the tradeoff and pecking order models. Sections II and III use cross-section regressions to make inferences about how dividends and leverage line up with the predictions of the two models. Section IV concludes. There is also an appendix, which uses sorts to establish properties of key variables and provide qualitative perspective on the more formal results on the validity of major hypotheses produced by the regressions. 3

I. Predictions Our discussion of the tradeoff and pecking order models largely focuses on predictions about how leverage and the dividend payout ratio vary with profitability, investment opportunities, and the volatility of earnings and cash flows. A. The Pecking Order Model Myers (1984) uses Myers and Majluf (1984) to motivate the pecking order. In Myers and Majluf, managers use private information to issue risky securities when they are over-priced. Investors are aware of this asymmetric information problem, and they discount the firm s new and existing securities when new issues are announced. Because managers anticipate these price discounts, they are reluctant to issue risky debt and equity, and they may forego profitable investments if they must be financed with new risky securities. Managers prefer to finance projects with retained earnings, which involve no asymmetric information problem, and with low risk debt, for which the problem is negligible. Myers (1984) suggests that the costs of issuing risky debt or equity overwhelm the forces that determine optimal leverage in the tradeoff model. The result is the pecking order. To minimize asymmetric information costs and other financing costs, firms finance investments first with retained earnings, then with safe debt, then with risky debt, and finally, under duress, with equity. The pecking order implies predictions about dividends. Since it is expensive to raise outside funds, dividends are less attractive for firms with less profitable assets in place and large current and expected investments. Thus, controlling for investment opportunities, more profitable firms pay out more of their earnings as dividends. But given profitability, there is a negative relation between the payout ratio and investment opportunities. Myers (1984) also posits that, once set, dividends are (for unknown reasons) sticky, leaving variation in net cash flows to be absorbed largely by debt. Pecking order predictions about leverage are more complicated. In a pecking order world, debt typically grows when investment exceeds retained earnings and falls when investment is less than retained earnings. Thus, if profitability and investment outlays are persistent, the simple version of the 4

model predicts that, holding investment fixed, leverage is lower for more profitable firms, and given profitability, leverage is higher for firms with more investments. In a more complex view of the model, also offered by Myers (1984), firms are concerned with future as well as current financing costs. Balancing current and future costs, it is possible that firms with large expected investments maintain low-risk debt capacity to avoid financing future investments with new risky securities, or foregoing the investments. It is thus possible that, controlling for profitability, firms with larger expected investments have less current leverage. How can pecking order firms keep leverage down when investments are persistently large relative to earnings? Dividend payers can lower dividends or not raise them when earnings increase. Firms that do not pay dividends can refrain from starting when earnings are strong. Firms going public can issue more equity in anticipation of future investment. And when publicly traded firms choose to bear the high financing costs of new equity, they can issue more of it to accommodate future investment. It is possible that none of this works; that is, the balance of financing costs in the pecking order may force many firms with persistently large investments relative to earnings to have high leverage (the prediction of the simple version of the model). This is unlikely for dividend payers since they have a source of retained earnings (lower dividends or smaller increases) that can help maintain less leverage. Moreover, Fama and French (1999) find that (as the pecking order model predicts) dividend payers tend to be firms with high earnings relative to investment. Thus, for dividend payers, we are comfortable with the prediction that given the profitability of assets in place, firms with larger expected investments have less current leverage. For non-payers, this prediction is more tenuous. Myers (1984) argues that in a pecking order world, firms do not have leverage targets. Our analysis seems to suggest that considering future as well as current financing costs leads to such targets. If so, the targets are soft. Firms with more expected investments may tend to have less leverage, but period-by-period variation in net cash flows is still largely absorbed by debt. Moreover, any leverage targets are one-sided; firms have no particular incentive to increase leverage when positive net cash flows push it below values that allow expected investments to be financed with retained earnings and low-risk 5

debt. This is in contrast to the tradeoff model (discussed next) where the costs and benefits of debt push under-levered firms up and over-levered firms down toward their leverage targets. Finally, considering future as well as current financing costs leads to a pecking order prediction about how the volatility of net cash flows affects dividends and debt. To lower the chance of issuing new risky securities or foregoing profitable investments when net cash flows are low, firms with more volatile net cash flows are likely to have lower dividend payouts and less leverage. B. The Tradeoff Model In the tradeoff model, leverage and dividend targets are driven by an amalgam of forces. Potential bankruptcy costs, for example, push firms toward less target leverage, while the agency costs of free cash flow push them toward more. The tradeoff forces we consider make almost unanimous predictions about how target leverage and the dividend payout vary across firms with profitability and investment opportunities. The tradeoff model s predictions about dividends are similar to those of the pecking order model. But the models have some disagreements about leverage. Bankruptcy Costs Expected bankruptcy costs rise when profitability declines, and the threat of these costs pushes less profitable firms toward lower leverage targets. Similarly, expected bankruptcy costs are higher for firms with more volatile earnings, which should drive smaller less-diversified firms toward less target leverage. Bankruptcy costs also affect dividend payouts. Everything else the same, dividends cause firms to issue more debt. Since this increases the probability of bankruptcy, less profitable and more volatile firms are likely to choose lower target payout ratios. Taxes Taxes have two offsetting effects on optimal capital structures. The deductibility of corporate interest payments pushes firms toward more target leverage, while the higher personal tax rate on debt, relative to equity, pushes them toward less leverage. In Miller and Scholes (1978), the personal tax rate implicit in the pricing of a firm s interest payments does not vary with its leverage. If the marginal benefit of the corporate tax deduction is also constant at all levels of profit and loss, taxes do not produce an interior optimum for leverage. Whether taxes push a firm toward maximum leverage, no 6

leverage, or indeterminate leverage depends on whether the constant marginal corporate tax saving is greater than, less than, or equal to the constant marginal personal tax cost. DeAngelo and Masulis (1980) develop a model that allows the marginal benefit of the corporate tax deduction of interest to vary with leverage, and so produces an interior optimum for leverage. In their model, optimal leverage is determined by the size of a firm s non-debt tax shields, such as depreciation and R&D expenditures. The larger a firm s non-debt tax shields, (i) the larger its chance of having no taxable income, (ii) the lower its expected corporate tax rate, and (iii) the lower its expected payoff from interest tax shields. Thus, DeAngelo and Masulis (1980) predict that leverage is inversely related to the level of non-debt tax shields. Tests of the DeAngelo and Masulis (1980) model typically focus on non-debt tax shields, but the model implies a more general prediction about leverage and profitability. The driving force in their argument is asymmetric taxation of profits and losses. The government does not subsidize corporate losses as heavily as it taxes profits, so more profitable firms face a higher expected marginal tax rate. For low levels of earnings, progressive corporate tax rates reinforce the link between expected profitability and the expected tax rate. As a result, the expected payoff from interest tax shields is higher for more profitable firms and for firms with less volatile earnings. The deductibility of corporate interest thus pushes more profitable and less volatile firms toward higher leverage. Free Cash Flow In the agency models of Jensen and Meckling (1976), Easterbrook (1984), and Jensen (1986), the interests of managers are not aligned with those of securityholders, and managers tend to waste free cash flow (the excess of cash earnings over profitable investments) on perquisites and bad investments. Dividends and especially debt help control this agency problem by forcing managers to pay out more of the firm s excess cash. A firm s free cash flow is determined by the earnings from its assets in place and the size of its profitable investments. The model predicts that to control the agency costs created by free cash flow, firms with more profitable assets in place commit a larger fraction of their pre-interest earnings to debt payments and dividends. Thus, controlling for investment opportunities, the dividend payout and 7

leverage are positively related to profitability. Conversely, firms with more investments relative to earnings have less need for the discipline of dividends and debt. Thus, controlling for profitability, firms with more investment opportunities should have lower dividend payouts and less leverage. Adjustment (Financing) Costs In the tradeoff model, bankruptcy costs, interest tax shields, and free cash flow problems affect a firm s targets for leverage and dividend payout. In contrast, financing costs [for example, the transactions costs of issuing securities and the asymmetric information problem of Myers and Majluf (1984)] affect leverage and the dividend payout because they impose costs in moving toward dividend and leverage targets. Myers (1984) builds the pecking order model on the assumption that asymmetric information problems and other financing costs overwhelm the forces that determine optimal leverage in the tradeoff model. But if financing costs do not overpower all other factors, the tradeoff model survives, and firms weigh all costs and benefits when determining leverage targets. And adjustment (financing) costs affect the targets. To reduce the likelihood of having to issue risky securities or forego profitable investments, firms set their leverage and dividend payout targets below their no-adjustment-cost optimal values. The shift toward less leverage and lower dividend payouts is larger for firms with lower expected profits, larger expected investments, and more volatile net cash flows. In sum, asymmetric information problems and other financing costs reinforce the tradeoff model s predictions about target leverage and the dividend payout ratio. Controlling for other effects, more profitable firms, firms with fewer investments, and firms with less volatile earnings and net cash flows have higher leverage and payout targets. Financing costs also impede movement toward the targets, but in contrast to the pecking order model, in the tradeoff model these costs do not overwhelm the other factors that determine target ratios. C. Proxies for the Driving Variables Our measures of profitability, investment opportunities, and volatility are far from perfect. We use the ratio of annual pre-tax pre-interest earnings to end-of-year total assets, ET t /A t, and the ratio of preinterest after-tax earnings to assets, E t /A t, as noisy proxies for the expected profitability of assets in place. 8

ET t, earnings before taxes, preferred dividends, and interest payments, is the income that could be sheltered from corporate taxes by interest deductions. Thus, ET t /A t is a good measure of profitability when we look for tax effects in the tradeoff model. ET t /A t and E t /A t also provide information about profitability for testing the pecking order model and the effects of other forces in the tradeoff model. We use three additional proxies for expected profitability, (i) the ratio of annual dividends to endof-year book equity, D t /BE t, (ii) the ratio of total firm market value to book value, V t /A t, and (iii) book leverage, L t /A t (the ratio of debt to the book value of assets). D t /BE t is a proxy for profitability because firms with higher current and expected earnings are likely to have higher dividends. But D t /BE t is a noisy proxy because dividends also depend on payout policy. The market-to-book ratio, V t /A t, measures both the profitability of assets in place and investment opportunities. A firm s market value, V t, is the value of its assets in place plus the value of its future investments. Thus, V t /A t (a rough measure of Tobin s Q) tends to be higher for firms with more profitable assets in place and for firms with better investment opportunities. Finally, the appendix shows that like D t /BE t and V t /A t, L t /A t is a proxy for profitability. Specifically, more levered firms tend to be less profitable. The growth in assets, da t /A t = (A t A t-1 )/A t, is a direct measure of current investment. If investment is persistent, da t /A t is also a proxy for expected investment opportunities. Since research and development expenditures generate future investment, we use the ratio of R&D to assets, RD t /A t, as an additional proxy for expected investment. RD t /A t also serves as a proxy for non-debt tax shields, along with the ratio of depreciation expense to assets (Dp t /A t ). Finally, the appendix shows that like, V t /A t, D t /ME t (the ratio of dividends to the market value of common stock) is a proxy for investment opportunities; firms with higher market values relative to dividends have better investment opportunities. The tradeoff and pecking order models predict that firms with more volatile earnings and net cash flows have less leverage and lower dividend payouts. Since our empirical tests examine cross-sections of firms, using time series data to estimate volatility would limit our samples. Instead, we assume that larger more diversified firms are likely to have less volatile earnings and net cash flows, and we use firm size specifically, the natural logarithm of total book assets, ln(a t ) as a proxy for volatility. 9

Our tests exclude financial firms and utilities. Compustat s historical coverage of financial firms is thin, and financial intermediaries seem in any case inappropriate subjects for testing the predictions of leverage models. We exclude utilities to avoid the criticism that their financing decisions are a byproduct of regulation. We can report, however, that including utilities has little effect on the results. D. Market or Book Leverage Do the leverage predictions of the tradeoff and pecking order models describe market leverage, L t /V t (the ratio of debt to the market value or assets), or book leverage, L t /A t? We argue that most of the predictions of two models apply to book leverage, but they sometimes carry over to market leverage. In the tradeoff model, agency costs, taxes, and bankruptcy costs push firms to increase debt as earnings increase. Thus, scaling earnings and debt by assets, the model predicts a positive marginal relation between profitability, ET t /A t, and book leverage, L t /A t. Since market value also increases with profitability, this positive relation which does not necessarily carry over to market leverage, L t /A t. Controlling for earnings on assets in place, firms with more investment opportunities have less free cash flow and lower optimal levels of debt. Thus, scaling debt and investment with assets, the predicted relation between book leverage and investment is negative. Since market value grows at least in proportion to profitable investment outlays, there is also a negative marginal relation between investment opportunities and market leverage. In the pecking order model, firms with lots of profits and few investments have little debt. Or, standardizing by book assets, firms with high profitability, given their investments, have less book leverage. Since market value increases with profitability, the negative relation between profitability and book leverage, L t /A t, also holds for market leverage, L t /V t. In the simple version of the pecking order, the level of a firm s debt is determined by accumulated differences between retained earnings and investment. Thus, scaling by assets, and assuming investment and earnings are persistent, the marginal relation between investment and book leverage is positive. There is no prediction about market leverage. In the more complex pecking order model, firms balance current and expected financing costs in making leverage decisions. Firms with larger expected investments are pushed toward keeping more low- 10

risk debt capacity to finance anticipated investments. The result is likely to be a negative marginal relation between leverage and expected investment. Whether this prediction applies to book or market leverage depends on whether low risk debt capacity is a function of the book or the market value of assets, an issue on which there is ambiguity. When larger expected investments lead to less book leverage, however, they also produce less market leverage if the investments are expected to be profitable and so add to current market value. But when low risk debt capacity depends on market value, the resulting negative marginal relation between market leverage and expected investment opportunities does not necessarily carry over to book leverage. In short, the positive relation between profitability and leverage predicted by the tradeoff model applies to book leverage. The negative relation between profitability and leverage predicted by the pecking order model holds for both book and market leverage. The tradeoff model predicts that firms with more investments have less book and market leverage. In the simple pecking order model, firms with more investments have more book leverage but not necessarily more market leverage. In the complex pecking order model, larger expected investments are associated with less book and market leverage when low risk debt capacity depends on book assets. This prediction holds for market leverage when low risk debt capacity depends on the market value of assets. Finally, for ease of reference in the discussion of empirical results that follows, appendix Chart 1 summarizes the predictions of the tradeoff and pecking order models. III. Dividend Regressions The tests of tradeoff and pecking order predictions about dividends build on Lintner s (1956) model, which seems to provide a good description of dividend behavior [Allen and Michaely (1995)]. The model says that a firm has a long-term target payout ratio, TP, that relates its target dividend for year t+1, TD t+1, to common stock earnings, Y t+1, (1) TD t+1 = TP*Y t+1. Because of adjustment costs, the firm moves only part way to the target in year t+1, (2) D t+1 -D t = SOA(TD t+1 - D t ) + e t+1 11

(3) D t+1 -D t = a 1 Y t+1 + a 2 D t + e t+1. Thus, the speed of adjustment, SOA = -a 2, is less than 1.0. A. The Target Payout Approach Our approach to modeling the target payout in (1) is like that used later to model target leverage. Each year we estimate a cross-section regression of dividends (scaled by assets) on earnings (also scaled by assets), allowing the earnings slope to vary across firms as a function of proxies for investment opportunities, profitability, and volatility, the driving forces in the tradeoff and pecking order models, (4) D t+1 /A t = a 0 + (a 1 + a 1V V t /A t + a 1B D t /BE t + a 1L L t /A t + a 1A da t /A t + a 1M D t /ME t + a 1D RDD t + a 1R RD t /A t + a 1S ln(a t ))Y t+1 /A t + e t+1. To simplify the notation, we omit the firm subscript that should appear on the variables and residuals in (4) and the year subscript that should appear on the regression coefficients. We put earnings on the right of regression (4), rather than in the denominator on the left, to avoid the influential observation problem that would arise when earnings are near zero. Most of the explanatory variables in (4) are scaled by assets or book equity. This can create influential observations when A t and BE t are close to zero. To address this issue, each year we drop firms with A t less than $2.5 million or BE t less than $0.5 million. This causes the average number of firms per regression to drop from 1571 to 1549. The choice of interaction variables in (4) is motivated by the evidence in the appendix that V t /A t, da t /A t, D t /ME t, and RD t /A t are proxies for investment opportunities, and V t /A t, L t /A t, and D t /BE t are proxies for the profitability of assets in place. The log of firm size, ln(a t ), is our proxy for volatility. RDD t is a dummy that is 1.0 for firms with no reported R&D. On average more than 40 percent of Compustat firms report no R&D, and it seems appropriate to allow for a non-linearity in the relation between R&D and dividends produced by this large lump of firms. Previous research on the Lintner (1956) model [Fama and Babiak (1968), Choe (1990)] finds that dividends adjust slowly toward target payouts; the speed of adjustment in (2) is far from 1.0. Slow adjustment implies that, for the purpose of modeling the long-term target payout, there is noise in the 12

dividend variable on the left of regression (4). As long as this noise is unrelated to the explanatory variables on the right, however, it does not bias the slopes, and the regression yields unbiased estimates of the long-term target payout ratio as a function of investment opportunities, profitability, and volatility. In the spirit of Fama and MacBeth (1973), we use averages of the annual slopes from (4) and time-series standard errors of the averages to draw inferences. The advantage of this approach is that the year-by-year variation in the slopes, which determines the standard errors of the average slopes, includes estimation error due to the correlation of the residuals across firms. Autocorrelation of the annual slopes is also an issue. The autocorrelations are often large, 0.2 to 0.5. We could adjust the standard errors of the average slopes for the estimated autocorrelation of the slopes. But with just 33 observations on the slopes for 1965-97, autocorrelation estimates are imprecise, with standard errors around 0.18. We use a less formal approach. To be conservative, we assume the standard errors of the average slopes, calculated assuming serial independence of the annual slopes, should be inflated by 40%. Thus we require t-statistics greater than about 2.8, rather than the usual 2.0, to infer reliability. (This correction is exact if first-order autocorrelation of the annual slopes is the only problem, and the autocorrelation is 0.5.) Results In the tradeoff model, firms with more investments relative to earnings have lower free cash flows and thus less need for discipline from dividends. In the pecking order model, firms with abundant investments relative to earnings pay fewer dividends, preserving low-risk debt capacity for current and expected investment. Thus, both models predict that, controlling for the profitability of assets in place, firms with more investment opportunities have lower dividend payouts. The negative average da t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slope (t = -3.91) and the negative average RD t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slope (t = -3.06) produced by the estimates of (4) in Table 1 support this prediction. The positive D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t slope (t = 3.86) also supports the prediction since firms with higher values of D t /ME t have fewer investment opportunities. In the tradeoff model, firms with more profitable assets in place have more need for the discipline of dividends to control the agency problem created by their free cash flows. In the pecking order model, more profitable assets allow firms to pay higher dividends while maintaining low risk debt capacity to finance investment. Thus, the reasons are again different, but both models predict that given investment 13

opportunities, more profitable firms have higher dividend payouts. The positive D t /BE t *Y t+1 /A t slope (t = 10.99) and the negative L t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slope (t = -10.90) produced by the estimates of (4) in Table 1 are in line with this prediction. (Firms with higher D t /BE t tend to be more profitable and profitability is negatively related to book leverage.) The positive V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slope (t = 2.55) also supports the prediction that more profitable firms choose higher target payouts if the slope is due to the information about profitability in V t /A t rather than to information about investment opportunities. In the tradeoff model, more volatile earnings imply lower expected tax rates and higher expected bankruptcy costs, which push firms toward less leverage and lower dividend payouts. In the complex pecking order model, more volatile net cash flows push firms toward lower dividend payouts and less leverage by raising the chance that low-risk debt capacity will not be available for future investments. The positive ln(a t ) slope (t=7.90) in the estimates of (4) is consistent with the prediction that more volatile (i.e., smaller) firms have lower dividend payouts. The appendix shows that D t /ME t and D t /BE t are positively related to the payout ratio, D t /Y t. One might then worry that the explanatory power of D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t and D t /BE t *Y t+1 /A t in (4) has little to do with the fact that D t /ME t and D t /BE t are also proxies for investment opportunities and profitability. But if true, this argument implies that the explanatory power of other profitability and investment proxies is under-stated. Table 1 shows that dropping both D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t and D t /BE t *Y t+1 /A t from (4) does enhance the V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t, RD t /A t *Y t+1 /A t, and da t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slopes. Thus, dropping the dividend variables leaves intact our inferences about how the target payout varies with profitability and investment opportunities. Moreover, there is no mechanical reason D t /ME t and D t /BE t are related to the payout ratio. One can thus argue that D t /ME t and D t /BE t proxy for the payout ratio because they line up with investment opportunities and profitability in the way predicted by the tradeoff and pecking order models. Other evidence in Table 1 also suggests that the explanatory power of D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t and D t /BE t *Y t+1 /A t in (4) traces at least in part to information about investment opportunities (D t /ME t ) and profitability (D t /BE t ). When D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t alone is dropped from (4), the major effect is to kill the slope on V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t. The appendix shows that V t /A t is positively related to both investment opportunities 14

and the profitability of assets in place. When D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t and V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t are both in (4), the slope on V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t can concentrate more on the information in V t /A t about profitability. And as predicted by the tradeoff and pecking order models, the V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slope is positive. When D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t is dropped, V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t must also pick up some of the information in D t /ME t about investment opportunities. The slope near zero on V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t is then consistent with the tradeoff and pecking order predictions that more profitable assets in place lead to higher dividend payouts, but better investments produce lower payouts. Similarly, when D t /BE t *Y t+1 /A t alone is dropped from (4), the main effects are large increases in the V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t slope (from 0.009 to 0.053) and the D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t slope (from 1.20 to 3.98). This suggests that when D t /BE t *Y t+1 /A t is dropped from (4), its information about profitability is picked up by V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t, and part of the information in V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t about investment opportunities moves to D t /ME t *Y t+1 /A t. Finally, one might be concerned that if leverage and the dividend payout are jointly determined, including leverage as an explanatory variable in (4) leads to an endogeneity problem. Any such problem is attenuated by the fact that, like all the interaction variables in (4), leverage is lagged relative to the dividend to be explained. Moreover, Table 1 shows that when L t /A t *Y t+1 /A t alone is dropped from (4), the main result is a more than doubling of the slope on V t /A t *Y t+1 /A t. This suggests that the slope on L t /A t *Y t+1 /A t traces at least in part to the information in book leverage about the profitability of assets in place. In any case, a negative marginal relation between leverage and the payout ratio is in the spirit of both the tradeoff model (higher leverage obviates the need for the disciplinary benefits of dividends) and the pecking order model (firms with more debt pay less dividends to avoid issuing risky securities). B. Dividends and Investment The estimates of (4) support tradeoff and pecking order predictions about how investment, profitability, and volatility affect target dividend payouts. We now examine whether firms vary dividends away from their targets to accommodate short-term variation in investment. In these tests, we turn to Lintner s (1956) partial adjustment equation (3), which includes normal variation in dividends due to movement toward the target payout. We use two versions of (3). The simple version does not allow for 15

variation across firms in the target payout and speed of adjustment of (2) and (3). Specifically, adding a constant to (3) and scaling by total assets, each year we estimate the cross-section regression, (5) (D t+1 -D t )/A t = a 0 + a 1 Y t+1 /A t + a 2 D t /A t + a 3 da t+1 /A t + e t+1. The cross-section approach is unusual in tests of the Lintner model. Its advantage is that the slope on concurrent investment, da t+1 /A t = (A t+1 -A t )/A t produces a powerful test of whether dividends respond to short-term variation in investment. Average slopes from the year-by-year estimates of (5) are in Table 2. Lintner s earnings variable shows up clearly; the positive average slope on Y t+1 /A t is 12.53 standard errors from zero. The estimated speed of adjustment (the negative of the slope on D t /A t ) is 5.69 standard errors from zero. But it is small, 0.23. Slow adjustment of dividends is, however, also found in time-series tests of the Lintner model for recent periods [Choe (1990), Dewenter and Warther (1998)]. We estimate the target payout implied by the estimates of (5) as the ratio of the averages of the annual values of a 1 and -a 2. [This is like the estimate of TP from a pooled time-series cross-section estimate of (5).] The estimate, 0.39, is close to the average aggregate payout for the 1965-97 sample period, 0.44. Regression (5) is mispecified. The target payout and speed of adjustment of the Lintner model surely vary across firms. The tradeoff and pecking order models predict that the payout ratio depends on investment opportunities, the profitability of assets in place, and volatility. To allow variation across firms in TP and SOA, we expand regression (4) to include interaction terms that allow the slopes on Y t+1 /A t and D t /A t to vary as functions of proxies for investment opportunities, profitability, and volatility, (6) (D t+1 -D t )/A t = a 0 + (a 1 + a 1V V t /A t + a 1B D t /BE t + a 1L L t /A t + a 1A da t /A t + a 1M D t /ME t + a 1D RDD t + a 1R RD t /A t + a 1S ln(a t ))Y t+1 /A t + (a 2 + a 2V V t /A t + a 2B D t /BE t + a 2L L t /A t + a 2A da t /A t + a 2M D t /ME t + a 2D RDD t + a 2R RD t /A t + + a 2S ln(a t ))D t /A t + b 1 da t+1 /A t + e t+1. 16

The proxy variables in (6) are the same as those used to model the target payout in (4). Since the target payout in the Lintner model depends on the slopes for Y t+1 /A t and D t /A t, both slopes are allowed to vary with the proxies for profitability and investment opportunities. Moreover, it seems reasonable that variables that help determine TP may also have a role in SOA. Our main interest in (6) is not what the slopes on the interaction variables say about the target payout and the speed of adjustment of the Lintner model. Indeed, without going into details, using the interaction variables in (6) to draw inferences about the target payout is hopeless because TP depends in a complicated way on the slopes on the Y t+1 /A t and the D t /A t interaction variables. In Table 2, we bypass messy and uninteresting details, and report overall Y t+1 /A t and D t /A t slopes that aggregate the interaction slopes in (6). (See Table 2 for details.) We can then focus on our main interest, the information from the da t+1 /A t slope about the short-term response of dividends to investment. The cross-section estimates of the Lintner model from (6) in Table 2 are reassuring on several counts. Like (5), (6) produces a low average SOA (0.16), but as noted earlier, low SOA s are also the norm in time-series tests of the Lintner model. The overall target payout ratio from (6) is 0.39, which again is close to the average aggregate payout for the sample period, 0.44. Most impressive, the average regression R 2 from (6) is 0.49, versus 0.26 for (5). Thus, allowing for variation across firms in the SOA and TP of the Lintner (1956) model substantially enhances the explanatory power of the regressions. What do regressions (5) and (6) say about short-term variation in dividends in response to investment? The average da t+1 /A t slope from (6) in Table 2 is negative, which suggests some accommodation. But the slope is zero up to four decimal places (t = -0.23). The da t+1 /A t slope in (5), which does not allow variation across firms in SOA and TP, is a bit further from zero. But it is statistically unreliable (t = -1.28) and economically trivial; on average, the change in dividends absorbs about 0.2 percent of the change in assets. And the problem is not statistical power. The fact that a slope as small as -0.002 is -1.28 standard errors from zero says that the regressions have power to identify meaningful variation in dividends in response to investment if it is there. 17

In the pecking order model, financing with retained earnings avoids the asymmetric information problem that arises when firms issue risky debt or equity. The model thus seems to predict that firms adjust dividends to absorb short-term variation in investment. But this prediction is not firm. The estimates of (4) say that, as predicted by the model, firms with more investments choose lower target payouts. If this negative relation between investment and long-term payouts leaves dividend payers with enough retained earnings and low risk debt capacity to absorb variation in investment, the insensitivity of dividends to investment does not violate the pecking order. The appendix shows that for different groups of dividend payers net issues of stock are small and of random sign. For the 1965-97 period, dividend payers as a group are on average net repurchasers of stock. In short, consistent with the pecking order model, firms do not typically pay dividends and issue stock. Note, though, that in a pecking order world, the non-response of dividends to short-term variation in investment does imply that the adjustment costs (asymmetric information problems and other financing costs) of varying dividends are larger than for debt. The evidence [e.g., Smith (1986)] on the rather strong response of stock prices to changes in dividends and the weak response to changes in debt seems roughly consistent with this proposition. It is widely acknowledged that dividends are insensitive to short-term variation in investment [Myers (1984), Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999)]. But the only evidence we are aware of is Fama (1974). We extend Fama s (1974) results, obtained from time-series tests of the Lintner model on a limited sample of large firms, to a later time period and annual samples that include all dividend-paying firms. IV. Leverage Regressions Our final tests are cross-section regressions to explain the behavior of leverage. We address three questions. (i) Does the level of leverage vary across firms in the manner predicted by the tradeoff model or the pecking order model? (ii) Do firms have leverage targets and does leverage return to its target? (iii) To what extent is debt used to absorb short-term variation in earnings and investment? The framework for the tests is a standard partial adjustment model in which the change in book leverage partially absorbs the difference between target leverage, E(L t+1 /A t+1 ), and lagged leverage, L t /A t, 18

(7) L t+1 /A t+1 -L t /A t = a 0 + a 1 [E(L t+1 /A t+1 ) - L t /A t ] + a 2 Z + e t+1. Z is a vector of current and past investment and earnings, included to test whether these variables produce temporary movement in leverage away from its target. We estimate (7) with a two-step cross-section regression approach. Each year t+1, we first regress book leverage L t+1 /A t+1 on the variables assumed to determine target leverage, (8) L t+1 /A t+1 = b 0 + b 1 V t /A t + b 2 ET t /A t + b 3 D t /BE t + b 4 D t /ME t + b 5 Dp t /A t + b 6 RDD t + b 7 RD t /A t + b 8 ln(a t ) + e t+1. We then use the fitted values from (8) for year t+1 as the proxy for E(L t+1 /A t+1 ) in the second-stage estimate of (7) for t+1. In the market leverage model, we substitute L t+1 /V t+1 for L t+1 /A t+1 in (7) and (8). The partial adjustment framework of (7) and (8) nests the tradeoff and pecking order models. In the trade-off model, firms have leverage targets and they move toward the targets every period. The fitted values from (8) are estimates of the targets, and the speed-of-adjustment a 1 in (7) measures how adjustment costs slow the movement of leverage toward its target. In contrast, in the pecking order model, the costs of issuing new risky securities swamp all other forces. As a result, firms do not have leverage targets, and regression (8) simply describes how leverage varies across firms as a function of profitability, investment opportunities, and firm size. The simple pecking order model predicts that in the estimates of (7) the speed-of-adjustment, a 1, is indistinguishable from zero, whereas the tradeoff model says it is reliably positive. Finally, because dividends are sticky and the costs of adjusting debt are less than the costs of adjusting equity, the pecking order model predicts a strong short-term response of leverage to short-term variation in earnings and investment (the Z variables in (7)). The explanatory variables for the level of leverage in the tradeoff and pecking order models are the profitability of assets in place, investment opportunities, non-debt tax shields, and the volatility of earnings and net cash flows. Our proxies for profitability in (8) are ET t /A t, V t /A t, and D t /BE t. The proxies for investment opportunities are V t /A t, D t /ME t, and RD t /A t. RD t is also a proxy for non-debt tax shields, along with depreciation, Dp t /A t. We use the log of assets, ln(a t ) to proxy for volatility. 19

One can argue that D t /BE t and D t /ME t should be dropped from (8) because they are proxies for the dividend payout ratio as well as for profitability and investment opportunities. Since the payout ratio and long-term leverage are likely to be jointly determined, including D t /BE t and D t /ME t in the leverage regressions creates a potential endogeneity problem. Thus, we also show estimates of (8) for dividend payers that exclude the dividend variables. This regression for payers then has the same explanatory variables as the regression for non-payers. Finally, all explanatory variables in (8) are predetermined. This mitigates any endogeneity problems in the relations between leverage and its determinants. A. Comments on Methodology Variants of the target leverage regression (8) are common in the literature. Estimation of (8) with a single cross-section regression is typical [e.g., Bradley, Jarrell, and Kim (1984), Long and Malitz (1985), Rajan and Zingales (1995)]. Panel (pooled time series cross-section) regressions are the weapon of choice in partial adjustment models like (7) [Auerbach (1984), Jalilvand and Harris (1984), Shyam- Sunder and Myers (1999)]. In the earlier work that uses a single cross-section regression, the inference problem created by correlation of the regression residuals across firms is ignored. The papers that use panel regressions ignore both the cross-correlation problem and the potential inference problem caused by autocorrelation of the regression residuals. We estimate (7) and (8) with year-by-year cross-section regressions, and we use Fama-MacBeth (1973) time-series standard errors, which incorporate estimation error caused by correlation of the residuals across firms, to draw inferences about the average slopes. Residual cross-correlation is important. The average slopes from our regressions are like the slopes from a pooled time-series crosssection regression that uses annual dummies to allow the average values of the variables to change through time. Skipping the details, the Fama-MacBeth standard errors of our average slopes are almost always more than twice and often more than five times OLS standard errors from pooled time-series cross-section regressions that ignore residual cross-correlation. Autocorrelation of the slopes from the annual cross-section regressions is also a problem. In the regression (8) to explain the level of leverage, the first-order autocorrelations of the annual slopes are 20