Interfirm Production Linkages and Propagation of Shocks: Evidence from Korean Business Groups *

Similar documents
A Granular Interpretation to Inflation Variations

FIRM-LEVEL BUSINESS CYCLE CORRELATION IN THE EU: SOME EVIDENCE FROM THE CZECH REPUBLIC AND SLOVAKIA Ladislava Issever Grochová 1, Petr Rozmahel 2

Do Firm-Level Shocks Generate Aggregate Fluctuations?

Large Firms and International Business Cycle Comovement

The Micro Origins of International Business Cycle Comovement 1

Accounting for the Sources of Macroeconomic Tail Risks

Firms, Destinations, and Aggregate Fluctuations

Asian Economic and Financial Review MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION AND BANK LENDING IN SOUTH KOREA AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. Yu Hsing

Firms, Destinations, and Aggregate Fluctuations

Firms, Destinations, and Aggregate Fluctuations

Banking Market Structure and Macroeconomic Stability: Are Low Income Countries Special?

Networks: Propagation of Shocks over Economic Networks

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 12 and 13 Input-Output Linkages: Implications for Productivity and Volatility

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

Trade Agreements and Supply Chains

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Test of the bank lending channel: The case of Hungary

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Sectoral vs. Aggregate Shocks: A Structural Factor Analysis of Industrial Production

On the Direct and Indirect Real Effects of Credit Supply Shocks

The Predictability Characteristics and Profitability of Price Momentum Strategies: A New Approach

Journal of Insurance and Financial Management, Vol. 1, Issue 4 (2016)

Firm-Specific Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates

Role of Foreign Direct Investment in Knowledge Spillovers: Firm-Level Evidence from Korean Firms Patent and Patent Citations

Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Oil Price Effects on Exchange Rate and Price Level: The Case of South Korea

Differential Impact of Uncertainty on Exporting Decision in Risk-averse and Risk-taking Firms: Evidence from Korean Firms 1

Sectoral Volatility, Trade Partners, and Development

THE BEHAVIOUR OF CONSUMER S EXPENDITURE IN INDIA:

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Positive Correlation between Systematic and Idiosyncratic Volatilities in Korean Stock Return *

The Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations in a Credit Network Economy

On exports stability: the role of product and geographical diversification

International Trade Gravity Model

Multinational Firms and. the International Transmission of Crises: The Real Economy Channel

The impacts of cereal, soybean and rapeseed meal price shocks on pig and poultry feed prices

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Examining the Linkage Dynamics and Diversification Opportunities of Equity and Bond Markets in India

Transmission of Financial and Real Shocks in the Global Economy Using the GVAR

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

Bilateral Portfolio Dynamics During the Global Financial Crisis

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

MODELING VOLATILITY OF US CONSUMER CREDIT SERIES

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Chapter 1. Introduction

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Journal of Asian Economics xxx (2005) xxx xxx. Risk properties of AMU denominated Asian bonds. Junko Shimizu, Eiji Ogawa *

Enhancing the Practical Usefulness of a Markowitz Optimal Portfolio by Controlling a Market Factor in Correlation between Stocks

Comovement of Asian Stock Markets and the U.S. Influence *

ROLE OF FUNDAMENTAL VARIABLES IN EXPLAINING STOCK PRICES: INDIAN FMCG SECTOR EVIDENCE

Topic 3, continued. RBCs

A portfolio approach to the optimal funding of pensions

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FINANCIAL FRICTIONS IN PRODUCTION NETWORKS. Saki Bigio Jennifer La'O. Working Paper

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

A multilevel analysis on the determinants of regional health care expenditure. A note.

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

The Margins of US Trade

Testing for Convergence from the Micro-Level

THE EURO AND EQUITY MARKETS IN EURO-ZONE COUNTRIES

Trading Volume, Volatility and ADR Returns

Worker Betas: Five Facts about Systematic Earnings Risk

Exchange Rate Regimes and International Business Cycle Transmission Revisited: The Korean Experience

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Liquidity skewness premium

Provided by the author(s) and NUI Galway in accordance with publisher policies. Please cite the published version when available.

Sustainability of Current Account Deficits in Turkey: Markov Switching Approach

Financial Econometrics Series SWP 2011/13. Did the US Macroeconomic Conditions Affect Asian Stock Markets? S. Narayan and P.K.

FIW Working Paper N 58 November International Spillovers of Output Growth and Output Growth Volatility: Evidence from the G7.

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

MONEY, PRICES AND THE EXCHANGE RATE: EVIDENCE FROM FOUR OECD COUNTRIES

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

Volume 30, Issue 4. Credit risk, trade credit and finance: evidence from Taiwanese manufacturing firms

Financial Regulation, Banking Integration, and Business Cycle Synchronization

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Debt Overhang, Rollover Risk, and Investment in Europe

Discussion Paper No. DP 07/05

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Corporate Investment and Portfolio Returns in Japan: A Markov Switching Approach

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

Transcription:

Interfirm Production Linkages and Propagation of Shocks: Evidence from Korean Business Groups * Sunghoon Chung May 2017 Very preliminary draft. Please do not cite or circulate. Abstract This note provides a new empirical evidence supporting the postulate that firm-to-firm production linkages are an important mechanism for the propagation of idiosyncratic micro shocks. By exploiting the variation of the share of internal transactions across business groups in Korea, we find that the more internalized business groups tend to exhibit higher covariances of firm-specific shocks among their member firms, implying that the transmission of the shocks are more pervasive in firms with heavier internal production linkages. JEL Classification: L14 Keywords: Firm-to-firm Linkages, Propagation of Shocks, Internalization in Business Group. *I thank seminar participants at KDI for helpful comments. All errors are mine. Korea Development Institute (KDI), 263 Namsejong-ro, Sejong 30149, Korea, Tel: 82-44-550-4278, Fax: 82-44- 550-4226, Email: sunghoon.chung@kdi.re.kr 1

1 Introduction Interfirm production linkages have been emphasized as a key channel through which idiosyncratic micro shocks are transmitted to other firms and thereby induces sizeable aggregate fluctuations. In a seminal work, Gabaix (2011) shows, based on Hulten s (1978) argument, that a few granular disturbances can propagate substantially in an economy with input-output (IO) linkages across firms. di Giovanni, Levchenko, and Mejean (2014, hereafter dglm) supplement the Gabaix s result with an accounting exercise that explicitly measures the magnitude of the linakges effect on the aggregate volatility. 1 Specifically, they find that the majority of the mirco shock-driven aggregate fluctuation is accounted for by the propagation of the shocks through the production linkages, although their direct impacts are still nontrivial. This paper provides a new empirical pattern that manifests the role of interfirm linkages for the transmission of idiosyncratic shocks. To this end, we employ internal transaction data among member firms in business groups over the period of 2007 through 2015 to measure the group-level (weighted) average of the internal sales share as a proxy for the interfirm production linkages. The heterogeneous levels of internalization are then plotted against the weighted (co)variances of all individual shocks in the corresponding business groups. We find a strong relationship that business groups with higher production linkages tend to display greater total variances of idiosyncratic shocks among their member firms, implying that the shocks are more easily transmitted to other members if they depend more on one another. Our finding is consistent with and complementary to the aforementioned result in dglm. Due to the lack of firm-level transaction data, they assume that firm s sourcing and sales structures are the same within a sector and exploit the sector-level IO coefficients to measure the degree to which firms in different sectors are interconnected with each other. We do not require such an assumption. Our finding also relates to more recent studies to identify the effect of localized micro shocks to aggregate economies, all of which consistently find the significant role of rigid supply chains across firms for amplifying the shocks (e.g., Barrot and Sauvagnat, 2016; Boehm, Flaaen, and Pandalai-Nayar, 2016; Carvalho et al., 2017). Finally, we shed some light on the nature of business group as well. In particular, while the prior literature often documents that an important incentive to form a business group is to hedge risks coming from external shocks (Almeida, Kim, and Kim, 2015; Cestone et al., 2016), our empirical result suggests that the heavy reliance on sourcing from or sales to the group members can magnify risks that stem from internal shocks. In the next section, we briefly explain the decomposition method to isolate the firm individual shocks. Section 3 reports and discusses the main finding after introducing the data we employ. Section 4 concludes. 1 In the same spirit, some studies estimate the impact of sector-level shocks on the aggregate economy (e.g., Foerster, Sarte, and Watson, 2011; Carvalho and Gabaix, 2013; Acemoglu, Akcigit, and Kerr, 2016). See also Long and Plosser (1983) and Acemoglu et al. (2012), among others, for the theoretical understanding on input-output linkages effect. 2

2 Decomposition of Shocks Our decomposition method to identify the firm-level idiosyncratic shocks follows dglm. The annual sales growth rate of firm f by destination country n at time t, γ f nt, are first decomposed into common shock and idiosyncratic shock. The common shock δ jnt is the average growth rate of all active firms at each destination by sector (j). The idiosyncratic shock ɛ f nt for firm f is simply defined as the residual, i.e., the destination-specific sales growth rate net of the common shock. We assume that both shocks are random variables and allow them to have serial or spatial correlations. The variance of the weighted sum of all idiosyncratic firm shocks, or firm-specific volatility in short, is then obtained as σ 2 Fτ = Var( f ω f nτ 1 ɛ f nt ) n = ω 2 f nτ 1 Var(ɛ f nt) + f,n g = f,m =n ω gmτ 1 ω f nτ 1 Cov(ɛ gmt, ɛ f nt ). (1) f,n The weight ω f nτ 1 in Eq. (1) is the sales of f in country n at time τ 1 where τ is a given fixed year during the sample period so that the weight remains as a constant. We will discuss more about this in the sext section. The main contribution of dglm is to evaluate the relative size of the firm-specific volatilitiy σfτ 2, which turns out to be about 70 to 80% for the case of France, compared to the aggregate volatility. 2 In addition, since σfτ 2 is composed of the weighted variances of individual shocks and covariances between them as in Eq. (1), they can gauge how each term contributes to the overall firm-specific volatility. Again, at least in France, the second covariances term constitutes a dominant portion of σ 2 Fτ. The question in this paper is defining what drives such dominance of the covariances term in the overall firm-specific volatility. Particularly, we hypothesize that the production linkages between firms is a key mechanism for the magnification of the initial idiosyncratic shocks. Note that the existence of production linkages by itself do not necessarily create the shock propagation, so long as firms can easily switch their business partners in response to shocks from their customers or suppliers: rigid customer-supplier relationship matters for the propagation of shocks. In addition, the positive correlation between firms idiosyncratic shocks can arise through other channels such as labor market conditions or local housing prices (Barrot and Sauvagnat, 2016). Thus, a direct firm-level evidence for the hypothesis is desirable. Our strategy for testing the hypothesis is to exploit the heterogeneous intensity of internalization across business groups. Business groups typically form a production network through vertical integration but at different degrees. Hence, we take the degree of internalization, i.e., the group-level (weighted) average of the internal sales share as the measure for the intensity 2 Friberg and Sanctuary (2016) implement the same analsis for Sweden to find that the firm-specific volatility explains about half of the Swedish aggregate volatility. 3

of production linkages as in Feenstra and Hamilton (2006). We then examine how its variation is related to the correlation of idiosyncratic shocks between member firms within business groups. That said, the firm-specific volatilitiy σfτ 2 can be decomposed into the group level variances as follows: σ 2 Fτ = I Var( i=1 f G iτ n ω f nτ 1 ɛ f nt ) + COV τ = I GroupVar iτ + COV τ (2) i=1 where G iτ indicates the set of member firms in ith business group at year τ and I is the total number of business groups in our sample. GroupVar iτ in Eq. (2) is the variance of the weighted sum of all idiosyncratic firm shocks in ith business group, or the (ith) group-specific volatility in short. Just as in Eq. (1), this term includes all variances of individual shocks and covariances between them. COV τ includes to all the rest of variances and covariances of firm shocks that constitutes σ 2 Fτ. 3 Data and Empirical Finding We now turn to the implementation with data. Our sample data is drawn from the Survey of Business structure and Activities (SBA) in Korea. Starting from 2006, the annual survey has collected information about corporate activities including sales, investment decisions, and strategic alliances as well as basic firm structures. It includes the total amount of exports, but not distinguished by destination country. Hence, there are two destination countries in our sample: domestic and foreign. Importantly, however, it has information on internal transactions with domestic member firms and foreign affiliates, so we can calculate the internal transaction shares by destination country. The sample covers all private firms that employ at least 50 full-time workers and have equity values at least 300 million Korean won. Thus, it is truncated below and we observe only about 12,000 firms in each year, which accounts for 2~3% of all corporates in Korea. These top firms, however, accounts for 60~64% of the total output and nearly 100% of the total exports in the economy, indicating the granularity in the firm distribution. Furthermore, the shocks from small-sized firms would have a negligible impact on the aggregate economy as argued in Gabaix (2011), so the truncation issue is not likely a concern. We also draw the list of firms associated as members of the 58 largest business groups from the Korea Fair Trade Commission, which is combined with the SBA to identify the member firms in each business group. Again, despite the truncation, most firms in business groups satisfy the two criteria and are included in the sample. Our sample period ranges from 2007 to 2015, and τ can be one out of nine years from 2006 to 2014. Rather than choosing one specific year, however, we apply all possible τ s to get as many weights as the number of sample years 4

(T = 9) and take the average values of GroupVar iτ. Once we decompose the annual sales growth rates by destination into shocks and calculate firm-specific and group-specific volatilities, Figure 1 shows the main finding of this paper. It plots (log of) the mean internal sales share against (log of) the standard deviation of the average group-specific variance over the nine years. The figure displays a clear pattern that the more internalized business groups tend to exhibit higher group-specific variances, implying that the transmission of the shocks are more pervasive in firms with heavier internal production linkages. When the (standard deviation of) group-specific variance is regressed on the internal sales share, we obtain 0.419 as the coefficient estimate which is statistically significant at 1% level. More discussions to come. 4 Conclusion To be written. References Acemoglu, D., U. Akcigit, and W. Kerr. 2016. Networks and the Macroeconomy: An Empirical Exploration. In M. Eichenbaum and J. Parker, eds. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2015. University of Chicago Press, vol. 30, pp. 273 335. Acemoglu, D., V.M. Carvalho, A. Ozdaglar, and A. Tahbaz-Salehi. 2012. The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 80:1977 2016. Almeida, H., C.S. Kim, and H.B. Kim. 2015. Internal Capital Markets in Business Groups: Evidence from the Asian Financial Crisis. The Journal of Finance 70:2539 2586. Barrot, J.N., and J. Sauvagnat. 2016. Input Specificity and the Propagation of Idiosyncratic Shocks in Production Networks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131:1543 1592. Boehm, C.E., A. Flaaen, and N. Pandalai-Nayar. 2016. Input Linkages and the Transmission of Shocks: Firm-Level Evidence from the 2011 T ohoku Earthquake. Working paper. Carvalho, V., and X. Gabaix. 2013. The Great Diversification and Its Undoing. American Economic Review 103:1697 1727. Carvalho, V.M., M. Nirei, Y.U. Saito, and A. Tahbaz-Salehi. 2017. Supply Chain Disruptions: Evidence from the Great East Japan Earthquake. Working Paper Series No. 2017-01, Becker Friedman Institute. Cestone, G., C. Fumagalli, F. Kramarz, and G. Pica. 2016. Insurance Between Firms: The Role of Internal Labor Markets. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 11336, London. 5

di Giovanni, J., A.A. Levchenko, and I. Mejean. 2014. Firms, Destinations, and Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 82:1303 1340. Feenstra, R.C., and G.G. Hamilton. 2006. Emergent Economies, Divergent Paths: Economic Organization and International Trade in South Korea and Taiwan. Cambridge University Press. Foerster, A.T., P.D.G. Sarte, and M.W. Watson. 2011. Sectoral versus Aggregate Shocks: A Structural Factor Analysis of Industrial Production. Journal of Political Economy 119:1 38. Friberg, R., and M. Sanctuary. 2016. The contribution of firm-level shocks to aggregate fluctuations: The case of Sweden. Economics Letters 147:8 11. Gabaix, X. 2011. The Granular Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 79:733 772. Hulten, C.R. 1978. Growth Accounting with Intermediate Inputs. The Review of Economic Studies 45:511 518. Long, J.B., Jr., and C.I. Plosser. 1983. Real Business Cycles. Journal of Political Economy 91:39 69. 6

Figure 1: Internal Sales Share and Group-Specific Volatility Source: Author s calculation. 7