The Skorokhod Embedding Problem and Model Independent Bounds for Options Prices. David Hobson University of Warwick

Similar documents
Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Model Free Hedging. David Hobson. Bachelier World Congress Brussels, June University of Warwick

Robust Pricing and Hedging of Options on Variance

On robust pricing and hedging and the resulting notions of weak arbitrage

Robust Hedging of Options on a Leveraged Exchange Traded Fund

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

Model-independent bounds for Asian options

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

Non-semimartingales in finance

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

No-Arbitrage Bounds on Two One-Touch Options

Constructing Markov models for barrier options

The stochastic calculus

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

OPTION PRICE WHEN THE STOCK IS A SEMIMARTINGALE

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

Arbitrage Bounds for Volatility Derivatives as Free Boundary Problem. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

CONTINUOUS TIME PRICING AND TRADING: A REVIEW, WITH SOME EXTRA PIECES

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Risk Minimization Control for Beating the Market Strategies

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Hedging under Arbitrage

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

A Lower Bound for Calls on Quadratic Variation

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

CHAPTER 12. Hedging. hedging strategy = replicating strategy. Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

The Black-Scholes Model

Robust hedging of double touch barrier options

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

LIBOR models, multi-curve extensions, and the pricing of callable structured derivatives

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

The Black-Scholes Model

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

How to hedge Asian options in fractional Black-Scholes model

Risk Neutral Measures

Credit Risk in Lévy Libor Modeling: Rating Based Approach

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

A Brief Introduction to Stochastic Volatility Modeling

Are stylized facts irrelevant in option-pricing?

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Hedging

Stochastic Volatility (Working Draft I)

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Exam Quantitative Finance (35V5A1)

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Weak Reflection Principle and Static Hedging of Barrier Options

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Lecture 1: Lévy processes

Advanced topics in continuous time finance

The Uncertain Volatility Model

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

The Black-Scholes Model

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

BIRKBECK (University of London) MSc EXAMINATION FOR INTERNAL STUDENTS MSc FINANCIAL ENGINEERING DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, MATHEMATICS AND STATIS- TICS

On the pricing of emission allowances

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Pricing Variance Swaps on Time-Changed Lévy Processes

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Math 6810 (Probability) Fall Lecture notes

Beyond the Black-Scholes-Merton model

ADVANCED DERIVATIVES LECTURE NOTES. Claudio Tebaldi Università Bocconi

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

University of Oxford. Robust hedging of digital double touch barrier options. Ni Hao

Interest rate models in continuous time

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Stochastic Calculus - An Introduction

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

A note on the existence of unique equivalent martingale measures in a Markovian setting

Transcription:

The Skorokhod Embedding Problem and Model Independent Bounds for Options Prices David Hobson University of Warwick www.warwick.ac.uk/go/dhobson Summer School in Financial Mathematics, Ljubljana, September 211

Overview Lecture 1: A philosophy for model-independent pricing Lecture 2: The Skorokhod Embedding Problem Lecture 3: An application to Variance Swaps

Model-independent option pricing The classical approach The classical approach to derivative pricing The standard approach is to postulate a model (or a parametric family of models) (Ω,F,P,F,S). Price a contingent claim via expectation under the equivalent martingale measure Q: We have replication: E Q [e rt F T ] T e rt F T = E Q [e rt F T ]+ θ t d(s t e rt ) P/Qa.s.

Model-independent option pricing The classical approach Example For the family of exponential Brownian motion models ds t /S t = µdt +σdw t, for a call with payoff (S T K) +, the price is C BS where C BS = C BS (T,K;,S ;r,µ,σ) For convex payoffs (eg puts and calls) C BS (σ) is increasing in σ. Hence, in practice the model is calibrated using a liquid option. C BS (T,K) is an extrapolation device.

Model-independent option pricing Mis-specified models In a complete market the price and hedge are uniquely specified and replication is perfect provided the model is a perfect description of the real world. With an imperfect model (for notational simplicity, suppose r = ) Theorem Suppose the goal is to price a European claim on S with convex payoff F(S T ). Suppose the claim is priced and hedged under a diffusion model ds t = S t σ(s t )db t and that S is a martingale. Suppose the real world dynamics are such that ds t = S t σ t db t Suppose σ t σ(s t ). Then we have super-replication T E Q [F(S T )]+ θ(t,s t )ds t F(S T ) Q a.s.

Model-independent option pricing Pricing criteria in incomplete markets Pricing criteria in incomplete markets Price under a martingale measure Price under a risk measure Super-replication pricing Utility-indifference pricing Marginal utility-indifference pricing All these criteria are model based.

Model-independent option pricing A reverse approach: recovering models from prices Breeden and Litzenberger Lemma Suppose, for fixed T, call prices are known for every strike K (, ). Then, assuming we have C(T,K) = E Q [e rt (S T K) + ] Q(S T > K) = e rt K C(T,K) Q(S T dk) = e rt 2 2 K C(T,K)

Model-independent option pricing A reverse approach: recovering models from prices Corollary Any co-maturing European claim can be priced and hedged perfectly. F(S T ) = F(x)+(S T x)f (x) + x F (k)(s T k) + dk + x F (k)(k S T ) + dk E[e rt F(S T )] = e rt F(x)+(E[e rt S T ] e rt x)f (x) + x F (k)c(t,k) + dk + x F (k)p(t,k)dk

Model-independent option pricing A reverse approach: recovering models from prices Dupire Lemma Suppose call prices are known for every strike K (, ) and every T (,T]. Assuming C(T,K) is sufficiently differentaible, there exists a unique diffusion of the form ds t = S t σ(t,s t )db t +rs t dt such that C(T,K) = E[e rt (S T K) + ] In particular σ(t, s) solves = 1 2 σ(t,k)2 K 2 2 2 K C(T,K) rk K C(T,K) T C(T,K)

Model-independent option pricing A reverse approach: recovering models from prices More generally, given a set of option prices is there a model consistent with those option prices? is there a model with continuous paths? is there a model with paths of finite quadratic variation? if there is, is it unique? if there is not, is there an arbitrage? is there a model-independent (strong) arbitrage? is there a model-dependent (weak) arbitrage?? A consistent model is a quintuple (Ω,F,Q,F,S) such that E Q [e rt F T ] = f for each traded claim with associated traded price f. Prices of underlyings and vanillas { Models/ Classes of models } Prices and hedges for exotics

Model-independent option pricing The pricing problem The pricing problem Suppose we are given a family {F α ;α A} of traded payoffs. Let V be the linear space with basis {F α ;α A}. Suppose we are also given a map (pricing functional) L : V R such that L(λ 1 F 1 +λ 2 F 2 ) = λ 1 L(F 1 )+λ 2 L(F 2 ) F 1 F 2 L(F 1 ) L(F 2 ) Suppose we now add a family of payoffs {F α ; α Ã}. When can L be extended to a linear function L : Ṽ R where Ṽ is the linear space with basis {F α ;α A} {F α ; α Ã}? The family {F α } is the set of traded securities, with traded prices {f α }. The family {F α } is the set of exotics.

Model-independent option pricing The pricing problem We split the class of traded securities into underlyings and vanillas and A into A U A V Underlyings may be traded with a simple strategy. If S is an underlying (e r(t τ) S T S τ ) {F α ;α A U } Such a security is costless. Moreover we allow positions (ie multiples) δ τ = δ(s t ; t τ) which depend on the price history up to τ Vanillas (typically calls and puts) may only be traded at time zero.

Model-independent option pricing The pricing problem Definition A semi-static superhedging strategy Π for ˆF is a portfolio of traded instruments such that Π = m U i=1 δ α i F αi + m V j=1 π α j F αj ˆF. Lemma Suppose L(F α ) = f α α A. Suppose Π = m U i=1 δ α i F αi + m V j=1 π α j F αj ˆF. Then, for any extension L, L(ˆF) m V j=1 π α j f αj.

Model-independent option pricing The pricing problem Henceforth we assume a single underlying, and that the set of vanilla options is the set of calls and puts with maturity T and with the full continuum of strikes K. No other vanilla securities trade. The aim is to give (the range of) no-arbitrage prices for a co-maturing exotic.

Model-independent option pricing The canonical example One-touch digitals Let S be a forward price. We assume it is possible to trade forwards on S. Given the prices of calls with maturity T, what is the price of a one-touch digital option paying ˆF = I {sup t T S t B}? Note C(K) is a decreasing convex function with C() = S. Suppose S < B else the problem is trivial. Let H B = inf{t : S t B}. Then ˆF = I {HB T} and we have, for each K < B, Then ˆF (S T K) + 1 B K +(S 1 H B S T ) B K I {H B T} C(K) L(ˆF) inf K<BB K

Model-independent option pricing The canonical example Is there a model for which the bound is attained? If so then the bound is a best bound. Write K = K (B) = arginf{c(k)/(b K)}. Write µ for the law of S T. Suppose µ has a density with respect to Lebesgue measure. Let b = E µ [S T S T > K ] = y>k yµ(dy)/ y>k µ(dy). Let a = E µ [S T S T < K ] = y<k yµ(dy)/ y<k µ(dy).

Model-independent option pricing The canonical example Consider a process (S t ; t T) such that S = yµ(dy) S is constant on (,T/2) S T/2 = { b with probability (S a)/(b a) a with probability (b S )/(b a) S is constant on (T/2,T) conditional on S T/2 = b, S T has law µ restricted to (K, ); conditional on S T/2 = a, S T has law µ restricted to (,K ). Lemma S is a martingale with S T µ. (S T K ) = (H b T) = (S T > K ) b = B P(H B T) = E[ˆF] = C(K )/(B K )

Model-independent option pricing The canonical example Do other models exist? Are there continuous models? Consider S over [,T/2). Let W = S = yµ(dy). Let Ha,b W = inf{u : W u / (a,b)}. Then { b with probability (S a)/(b a) W H W = a,b a with probability (b S )/(b a) Let Λ be an increasing continuous function such that Λ() = and lim t T/2 Λ(t) =. Now set S t = W min{h W a,b,λ(t)}. Then (S t) t T/2 is a martingale with the correct distribution at time T/2. Is there a similar construction over [T/2,T]? The same time-change argument will work, so we can convert this to a question about Brownian motion.

Model-independent option pricing The canonical example Suppose (S t ) t T is a martingale such that S T µ. Then there exists a Brownian motion W and a time-change A such that S t = W At. If S is continuous then the Dambis-Dubins-Schwarz Theorem gives that S t = W S,S t Then W AT µ. Conversely, suppose W τ µ. Then S t = W t/(t t) τ is such that S T = W τ µ. Hence we can identify price processes (S t ) t T for which S T µ with stopped Brownian motions with W τ µ. The problem of finding stopping times for Brownian motion for which W τ µ is called the Skorokhod embedding problem.

Skorokhod embeddings Skorokhod embeddings

Model-independent bounds for variance swaps Model-independent bounds for variance swaps Overview Continuous monitoring, continuous price process Semimartingale case Non-probabilistic case Continuous monitoring, no continuity assumption on price process Discrete monitoring

Continuous monitoring, continuous price process Variance swaps: Neuberger/Dupire Suppose we have a model (Ω,F,F,P) supporting an asset price F = (F t ) t T. Think of F as a forward price. Suppose F is a continuous semimartingale. Denote the quadratic variation by [F] t. Suppose we know the prices of vanilla options with maturity T. We wish to price a variance swap, a path-dependent security paying T d[f](t)/f2 t [logf] T. Then, by Itô s formula for semimartingales T d[f] F 2 t = 2lnF T +2lnF + T 2 F t df t There is a model-independent price for a variance swap, and a perfect hedge consisting of a static portfolio of calls and a dynamic

Continuous monitoring, continuous price process Variance swaps: Neuberger/Dupire Suppose we have (Ω,F,F,P) supporting F = F t. Suppose F is a continuous semimartingale. Suppose that the asset price process is continuous (f(t)) t T. Suppose price paths have a quadratic variation [f](t). Suppose we know the prices of vanilla options with maturity T. We wish to price a variance swap, a path-dependent security paying T d[f](t)/f(t)2 [logf] T. Then, by Föllmer s pathwise Itô s formula for semimartingales T d[f] f(t) 2 = 2lnf(T)+2lnf()+ T 2 f(t) df(t) There is a model-independent price for a variance swap, and a perfect hedge consisting of a static portfolio of calls and a dynamic strategy in the underlying.

Continuous monitoring, continuous price process In Brownian terms Suppose we now work on a stochastic basis (Ω,F,P,F) on which the price realisation is a stochastic process X t (ω). WLOG we may assume X t is a martingale. If we write X t = B At for some continuous time-change, (and B = X = 1 [WLOG]) then and T (dx t ) 2 X 2 t = AT T ds B 2 s (db At ) 2 B 2 A t = AT AT = 2lnB AT + (db s ) 2 B 2 s = 2 B s db s AT Writing τ for A T, and if X T B τ µ, then [ τ ] ds E = 2E[lnB τ ] = E[ 2lnZ Z µ]. B 2 s ds B 2 s

Continuously monitored processes with jumps Continuously monitored processes with jumps What if we no longer assume continuity of our price process? The problem Assume given the continuum of call prices with maturity T; moreover assume calls are available as hedging instruments. Place upper/lower bounds on the price of the variance swap contract. Write µ for the marginal law at time T implied by vanilla prices.

Continuously monitored processes with jumps Time changed BM and the variance swap We have X t = B At but the time-change A may have jumps. X T B AT µ. Define J t = inf s t X s and R t = sup s t X s. Define I t = inf s t B s and S t = sup s t B s. Then I At J t X t R t S At and T Taking the lower bound T (dx t ) 2 T (X t ) 2 (dx t ) 2 T (R t ) 2 (dx t ) 2 T (R t ) 2 (dx t ) 2 T (X t ) 2 (dx t ) 2 (J t ) 2 (db At ) 2 T (M) (S At ) 2 = da AT t (S At ) 2 du (S u ) 2

Skorokhod embedding problems A Skorokhod embedding problem for Brownian motion Let B be Brownian motion (with B = 1). Suppose µ is a distribution with mean 1. The problem Over Skorokhod embeddings τ (of µ in B) find the embedding which minimises τ du S 2 u (in expectation).

Skorokhod embedding problems Optimality for the SEP Let B be a Brownian motion. Let κ be a decreasing function κ : [, ) [,1], and let G 1 be a random variable Define τ G κ = min(inf{u > : B u G},inf{u > : B u κ(s u )}) Theorem (Perkins, 1985) There exists κ,g such that τκ G is an embedding of µ. (Hobson-Klimmek, 21) τκ G minimises E[ τ S 2 t dt] over solutions of the SEP for µ.

Skorokhod embedding problems S t B t 1 τ t κ(s t )

Skorokhod embedding problems A lower bound on the price of a variance swap Thus we have a model independent bound for the price of the variance swap in the presence of jumps. Question Can this bound be attained? For the bound to be attained we must have (at jumps times) X t = R t = S At = S At (if µ has a density, else we must care about atoms) (R T x) (X T x) (X T < γ(x)) for a monotonic decreasing function γ [Recall we have reduced the problem to a functional of B τ and S τ alone]

Skorokhod embedding problems Suppose B = 1. Define H x = inf{u > : B u x}. Theorem Define M t = B(H 1+t/(T t) τ G κ ) Then M t is a martingale for which M T has law µ and for which the price of the variance swap attains the model-independent lower bound.

Skorokhod embedding problems G Figure: A price realisation

Discrete monitoring Discrete monitoring Definition H : R + R + R is a Variance Swap Kernel if for all x,y R + H(x,y), H(x,x) =, lim y x x 2 H(x,y) (y x) 2 = 1, Examples: H D (x,y) = (y x) 2 /x 2, H L (x,y) = (lny lnx) 2, H B = 2 ( log(y/x) ( y x)) x. Roughly speaking H(x,x(1+ǫ)) = ǫ 2 +o(ǫ 2 ).

Discrete monitoring Definition A partition P on [,T] is a set of times = t < t 1 <... < t N = T. Definition The payoff of a variance swap with kernel H for a price realisation f and partition P is V H (f,p) = N 1 k= H(f(t k ),f(t k+1 )). We concentrate on H = H D where H D (x,y) = (y x) 2 /x 2.

Hedging Hedging Suppose we can find ψ,δ : R + R such that Then H(x,y) ψ(y) ψ(x)+(y x)δ(x) (*) H(f(t k ),f(t k+1 )) ψ(f(t k+1 )) ψ(f(t k ))+δ(f(t k ))(f(t k+1 ) f(t k )) N 1 V H (f,p) ψ(f(t)) ψ(f())+ δ(f(t k ))(f(t k+1 ) f(t k )) k= If ψ is differentiable, then by considering y x in (*) we see that we may take δ(x) = ψ (x). So we want to find ψ for which H(x,y) ψ(y) ψ(x) (y x)ψ (x) By scaling we assume initial price is unitary. Then we may take ψ(1) = ψ (1) =.

Hedging ψ κ(x) 1 Figure: Upper and lower bounds for the uniform case - together with the price under a continuity assumption x

Hedging For the best ψ we expect equality at y = x and at y = κ(x) where κ = κ µ was determined earlier. Let κ : (1, ) (,1) be decreasing. Suppose ψ = ψ K solves H(x,y) ψ(y) ψ(x) (y x)ψ (x) with equality at y = κ(x). Then, for x > 1, H(x,κ(x)) = ψ(κ(x)) ψ(x) (κ(x) x)ψ (x) (1) H y (x,κ(x)) = ψ (κ(x)) ψ (x) Then differentiating (1) we get H x (x,κ(x)) = ψ (x)(x κ(x)) i.e. ψ (x) = H x (x,κ(x))/(x κ(x)).

Hedging Let k = κ 1. Define ψ = ψ κ by { x ψ(x) = 1 (x u)hx(u,κ(u)) u κ(u) du x > 1 H(k(x),x) +ψ(k(x))+(k(x) x)ψ (k(x)) x < 1

Hedging Definition H is an increasing (decreasing) variance swap kernel if H 1. x(u,y) u y is monotone increasing (decreasing) in y, 2. H(a,b)+H y (a,b)(c b) ( )H(a,c) H(b,c) for all a > b. Thus H D is an increasing and H L a decreasing variance swap kernel. The kernel H B is both an increasing and a decreasing kernel. Define L(x,y) = H(x,y) ψ(y)+ψ(x)+ψ (x)(y x). Lemma If H is an increasing (decreasing) variance swap kernel then L(x,y), for all x,y >.

Hedging Corollary V HD (f,p) ψ κ (f(t))+σ N 1 i= ψ κ(f(t i ))(f(t i+1 f(t i )) This result holds for any decreasing κ We can optimise over κ. When we do so we find the cheapest subreplicating hedge is obtained by κ = κ µ. Converse results exist for upper bounds and for H L. For H N the upper bound equals the lower bound. This part of the story involves no probability. To show attainment of the bounds, and therefore that the bounds are best possible we need to introduce a stochastic model.

Numerical results Figure: Upper and lower bounds for the uniform case - relative to the price under the continuity assumption

Summary and Open issues Figure: Upper and lower bounds for the lognormal case - relative to the price under the continuity assumption. Horizontal axis denotes volatility.

Summary and Open issues Summary We have found bounds on the price of volatility swaps which apply accross all models consistent with an observed set of co-maturing puts and calls. The bounds can be enforced with a simple hedging strategy. Depending on the form of the kernal, prices may be lower/higher than the continuous case if the jumps are downward. (For H D, jumps down mean that the standard Dupire/Neuberger argument overstates the fair price.)

Summary and Open issues Extensions: the forward start problem Suppose we know call prices at T 1 > T > and we want to consider the forward starting variance swap with payoff V H (f,p) = N 1 1 k=n H(f(t k ),f(t k+1 )) where P = {t N,...t N1 } and T = t N < t N +1 < < t N1 = T 1.

Summary and Open issues Extensions: the problem with intermediate data Suppose that in addition to call prices at T we also know call prices at intermediate times = T < T 1 < < T K = T, where T k P. Let P k = {t n P;T k 1 t n T k }. Then V H (f,p) = K V H (f,p k ) k=1 and we can get a best bound for the problem with intermediate data from adding together the best bounds for the forward starting problem.

Summary and Open issues 1 11.94 2 11.68 4 11.47 8 11.38?? continuous case 1