International Economics

Similar documents
International Trade: Economics and Policy. LECTURE 5: Absolute vs. Comparative Advantages

File: Ch03; Chapter 3: The Standard Theory of International Trade

INTERNATIONAL TRADE: THEORY AND POLICY

International Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE. 2.2 Mercantilists Views on Trade Case Study 2-1 Mercantilism Is Alive and Well in the Twenty-First Century

3. What proportion of international trade is based on absolute advantage?

3. What proportion of international trade is based on absolute advantage?

Remember the reasons for trade:

Lec 1: Introduction. Copyright 2000, South-Western College Publishing

Assignment 1. Multiple-Choice Questions. To answer each question correctly, you have to choose the best answer from the given four choices.

Introduction. Countries engage in international trade for two basic reasons:

2. David Ricardo's model explains trade based on: A) labor supply. B) technology. C) population. D) government control.

The Ricardian Model. Rafael López-Monti Department of Economics George Washington University Summer 2015 (Econ 6280.

CHAPTER 2 *(Core Chapter) THE LAW OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

Chapter 3 Why Everybody Trades: Comparative Advantage

International Linkages and Domestic Policy

Globalization. University of California San Diego (UCSD) Catherine Laffineur.

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

File: Ch02; Chapter 2: The Law of Comparative Advantage. Multiple Choice

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

ECS INTERNATIONAL TRADE

Ricardian Model part 1

UNIVERSITY OF CALICUT INTERNATIONAL ECONOMICS

Pre-Classical Theory of International Trade. Adam Smith s Theory of Absolute Cost Difference. David Ricardo s Theory of Comparative Cost Advantage.

Trade and Technology: The Ricardian Model

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

International Economic Issues. The Ricardian Model. Chahir Zaki

1/25/2011. Introduction to International Trade. Basic Theory of Trade

Assignment 2 (Chapter 2)

Endowment differences: The Heckscher-Ohlin model

The Standard Theory of International Trade

FREC 810 International Ag. Trade

Problem Set 1: Ricardo s Principle of Comparative Advantage

Department of Economics. INTERNATIONAL TRADE Only study guide for ECS302-E

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND TRADE POLICY Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 4 th Edition

Chapter 3: The Ricardian Trade Model. August 14, 2008

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

WHY is WHAT produced WHERE and traded to WHOM for WHAT?

International Economics Lecture 2: The Ricardian Model

Labor productivity and Comparative advantage The Ricardian model

International Trade in Goods and Assets. 1. The economic activity of a small, open economy can affect the world prices.

Chapter 7 Economic Growth and International Trade

Solution Problem Set #1

Micro International Trade Essentials 1 WCC Absolute Advantage, Comparative Advantage, and Trade

PubPol 201. Module 3: International Trade Policy. Class 2 Outline. Class 2 Outline. Class 2. The Gains and Losses from Trade

Lecture 12 International Trade. Noah Williams

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Название теста: Международная торговля(international trade) Предназначено для студентов специальности: Международные отношения, (3 курс 4 го), очное

The benefits of free trade: an introduction

Chapter 4. Comparative Advantage and Factor Endowments. Copyright 2011 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

Major Themes in International Economics + Review of Microeconomic Concepts

Lecture 6 Comparative Advantage. January 29, Lecture Outline

Lecture 2: Ricardian Comparative Advantage

Chapter 11: General Competitive Equilibrium

Specific factor endowments and trade I

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions:

Exam on International Economics, NAA119, 7.5 credits, Friday, 5 June 2015.

Factor endowments and trade I

Problem Set 2 Outline of Answers

Aggregate Supply and Demand

PubPol 201. Module 3: International Trade Policy. Class 2 The Gains and Losses from Trade

ECONOMICS - HIGHER LEVEL (400 Marks)

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 1776, Edited by R.H. Campbell and A.S. Skinner, Oxford, 1976,

MTA-ECON3901 Fall 2009 Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson or Model

Adaptive Agent-Based Simulations of Global Trade

International Economics. 3 Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade

Economics. Model Question Paper - 1 Time : 2.30 Hours MARKS : 90. Part - I. c) Deciding the Location of the Production Unit d) None

Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher- Ohlin Model

2015 EXAMINATIONS ECONOMICS - MSS J133 JOINT UNIVERSITIES PRELIMINARY EXAMINATIONS BOARD MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

Comparative Advantage Increasing Cost Model

Technology and trade I

Relationships among Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Interest Rates

Rents, Profits, and the Financial Environment of Business

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

3. Trade and Development

SYLLABUS Class: - B.B.A. VI Semester. Subject: - International Finance

C. One person must always be cheated when trade takes place by barter. D. It increases the initial cost of producing goods.

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

Karl Marx and Market Failure

Chapter 11 International Trade and Economic Development

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

ECONOMICS. The figures in the margin indicate full marks for the questions

Ricardian Model. Recaps. The Concept of. Comparative Advantage. Production Possibilities Frontier

Specific Factors Model (2/1/2012) Econ

AP Macroeconomics Trent Thornton Voice mail:

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Faculty of Arts and Science. August Examination 2006 ECO 209Y

New Zealand Economics Competition

SUPPLY AND DEMAND CHAPTER 2

International Trade Theories

CHAPTER 17 International Trade

Chapter 5. The Standard Trade Model. Slides prepared by Thomas Bishop

Economics 181: International Trade Midterm Solutions

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

CHAPTER 9 DISTRIBUTION: EXCHANGE AND TRANSFER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 2 nd Edition

Chapter 11: The Effects of General Fluctuations in Wages on the Prices of Production

SYMBIOSIS CENTRE FOR DISTANCE LEARNING (SCDL) Subject: Managerial Economics

Postgraduate Diploma in Marketing June 2012 Examination Specimen Paper Economic and Legal Impact Paper I (Econ)

Transcription:

International Economics 2The Law of Comparative Advantage Trade Based on Comparative Advantage: David Ricardo A. The Law of Comparative Advantage (LCA) According to LCA, even if one nation has an absolute disadvantage with respect to the other nation in the production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade. This nation should specialize in the production and export of the commodity in which its absolute disadvantage is smaller (this is the commodity of its comparative advantage) and import the commodity in which its absolute disadvantage in greater (this is the commodity of its comparative disadvantage). 1

Law of Comparative Advantage Even if one nation is less efficient than (has absolute disadvantage with respect to) the other nation in production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade. The first nation should: 1) Specialize in the production and export of the commodity in which its absolute disadvantage is smaller (this is the commodity of its comparative advantage) and 2) Import the commodity in which its absolute disadvantage is greater (this is the commodity of its comparative disadvantage ). International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 3 Example U.S. U.K. Wheat (bushels/labor hour) 6 1 Cloth (yards/labor hour) 4 2 Q) Determine: 1. Basis for trade 2. Patterns of trade 3. Gains from trade 4. The range for mutually advantageous trade (if the two countries are trading according to the following ratios (6W=6C), can we consider it the only available rate of exchange? International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 4 2

U.K. has absolute disadvantage in both goods. Since U.K. unit of labor is half as productive in cloth but six times less productive in wheat compared to U.S., the U.K. has a comparative advantage in cloth. U.S. has comparative advantage in wheat. International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 5 The range for mutually advantageous trade is: Rate of exchange 6W=6C isn't the only rate of exchange between the two countries. As the range of mutually advantageous trade between them is: 4C < 6W < 12C Why? Since the US could exchange 6W for 4C domestically (in the sense that both require 1 hour to produce), the US would gain if it could exchange 6W for more than 4C from the UK. On the other hand, in the UK 6W = 12C (in the sense that both require 6 hours to produce). Anything less than 12C that the UK must give up to obtain 6W from the US represents a gain from trade for the US. International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 6 3

The closer the rate of exchange is to 4C = 6W (the domestic, or internal, rate in the US, the smaller is the share of the gain going to the US and the larger is the share of the gain going to the UK. On the other hand, the closer the rate of exchange is to 6W = 12C (the domestic, or internal, rate in the UK), the greater is the gain of the US relative to that of the UK. For example, If the US exchanged 6W for 8C with the UK, both nations would gain 4C, for a total gain of 8C. If the US could exchange 6W for 10C, it would gain 6C and the UK only 2C International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 7 The range for mutually advantageous trade is: 4C < 6W < 12 C The spread between 12C and 4C (i.e., 8C) represents the total gains from trade available to be shared by the two nations by trading 6W. For example, if 6W are exchanged for 6C, US gains 2C and UK gains 6C, making a total of 8C from the exchange. Thus, we can conclude that: The closer the rate of exchange to the domestic, or internal, rate the smaller is the share of the gain going to the country. 4

The Case of No Comparative Advantage U.S. U.K. Wheat (bushels/labor hour) 6 3 Cloth (yards/labor hour) 4 2 This occurs when the absolute disadvantage that one nation has with respect to another nation is the same in both commodities. For example, if one hour produced 3W instead of 1W in the UK the UK would be exactly half as productive as the US in both wheat and cloth. The UK (and the US) would then have a comparative advantage in neither commodity, and no mutually beneficial trade could take place. International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 9 This requires slightly modifying the statement of the law of comparative advantage to read as follows: Even if one nation has an absolute disadvantage with respect to the other nation in the production of both commodities, there is still a basis for mutually beneficial trade, unless the absolute disadvantage (that one nation has with respect to the other nation) is in the same proportion for the two commodities. International Economics Hanan Nazier 2017/2018 10 5

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Costs Ricardo based his law of comparative advantage on a number of simplifying assumptions: 1)Only two nations and two commodities, 2)Free trade, 3)Perfect mobility of labor within each nation but immobility between the two nations, 4)Constant costs of production, 5)No transportation costs, 6)No technical change, and 7)The labor theory of value. The labor theory of value The best-known advocates of the labor theory were Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx. The labor theory of value (LTV) was an early attempt by economists to explain why goods were exchanged for certain relative prices on the market. It suggested that the value of a commodity could be measured objectively by the average number of labor hours necessary to produce it. Accordingly, two commodities will trade for the same price if they embody the same amount of labor-time. For instance, if it takes 10 hours to produce good (x), and 20 hours to produce good (y), then the exchange ratio would be two units of (y) for one unit of (x). 12 6

Comparative Advantage and Opportunity Costs 13 A. Comparative Advantage and Labor Theory of Value: Though assumptions 1-6 can easily be relaxed, assumption No. 7 (labor theory of value) is not valid. According to Labour theory of value, the value or price of a commodity depends exclusively on the amount of labor going into its production. This implies that: 1) Either labor the only factor of production or it is used in same fixed proportion in production of all commodities. 2) Labor is homogeneous (i.e. of only one type). Since neither of the assumptions is true, we can t base the explanation of comparative advantage on labor theory of value. 7

B. The Opportunity Cost Theory (OCT) The law of comparative advantage is sometimes referred to as the law of comparative cost. According to the Opportunity Cost Theory, the cost of a commodity is the amount of a second commodity that must be given up to release just enough resources to produce one additional unit of the first commodity. That is, it the value of the next-highest-valued alternative use of that resource. Thus, the nation with the lower opportunity cost in the production of a commodity has a comparative advantage in that commodity. The theory of comparative advantage states that countries should specialize in producing goods where they have a lower opportunity cost. Example If US has to give up 2/3 unit of cloth to release enough resources to produce one additional unit of wheat, then the opportunity cost of wheat is 2/3 unit of cloth (1W = 2/3 C). If 1W = 2C in UK, then the opportunity cost of wheat is lower in US, and thus US has a comparative advantage over UK in wheat. In a two-nation, two-commodity world, UK would have a comparative advantage in cloth. According to law of comparative advantage, US should specialize in producing wheat and export some of it in exchange for British cloth. 8

C. The Production Possibility Frontier (PPF) under Constant Costs PPF: a curve showing alternative combinations of the two commodities that a nation can produce by fully utilizing its resources with the best technology available to it. US UK Wheat Cloth Wheat Cloth 180 0 60 0 150 20 50 20 120 40 40 40 90 60 30 60 60 80 20 80 30 100 10 100 0 120 0 120 Figure: The PPFs of the United States and the United Kingdom. 9

Notes on the previous figure The opportunity cost is measured by the slope of the PPF, also known as the marginal rate of transformation MRT. The US has to give up 30W to produce an additional 20C (30W=20C), Thus, the opportunity cost of W in US is 1W = 2/3C. The UK has to give up 10W to produce an additional 20C (10W = 20C), Notes on the previous figure The opportunity cost is measured by the slope of the PPF, also known as the marginal rate of transformation MRT. The US has to give up 30W to produce an additional 20C (30W=20C), thus, the opportunity cost of W is 1W = 2/3C. The UK has to give up 10W to produce an additional 20C (10W = 20C), the opportunity cost of W is 1W = 2C. While opp. costs are constant in each nation, they differ among nations, providing the basis for trade. Constant opportunity costs arise when: Resources are perfect substitutes or used in fixed proportions in the production of both commodities. All units of the same factor are homogeneous. 10

D. Opportunity Costs and Relative Commodity Prices The (absolute) slope of US PPF is 120/180 = 2/3 which measures opportunity cost of wheat in US. The (absolute) slope of UK PPF is 120/60 = 2 which measures opportunity cost of wheat in UK. Assuming prices equal costs and the nation produces both commodities, the opp. cost of wheat is equal to price of wheat relative to price of cloth (P w /P c ). In the US, P w /P c =2/3, and inversely P c /P w = 3/2= 1.5 In the UK, P w /P c =2, and inversely P c /P w = ½= 0.5 The lower P w /P c in the US reflects its comp-adv. in wheat. The lower P c /P w in the UK reflects its comp-adv. in cloth. Conclusion: the difference in relative commodity prices between the two nations is a reflection of their com-adv. and provides the basis for mutually beneficial trade. The Case of No Comparative Advantage: There is a case where there is no comparative advantage; when absolute disadvantage that one nation has with respect to another nation is the same in both commodities. U.S. Wheat (bushels/man-hour) 6 3 Cloth (yards/man-hour) 4 2 U.K. 11

The Basis for and the gains from Trade under Constant Costs A. Illustration of the Gains from Trade With no trade, US may produce (and consume) a combination of (90W-60C) on its PPF (point A). The UK may produce a combination of (40W-40C) on its PPF (point A / ). With trade, US would specialize in producing wheat and produce at point B (180W-0C) (complete specialization). UK would specialize in producing cloth and produce at point B / (0W-120C). If they trade 70W for 70C, US consumes 110W-70C (point E), the UK consumes 70W-50C (point E / ). FIGURE 2-2 The Gains from Trade. 12

The US gains 20W and 10C from trade (E compared to A), UK gains 30W and 10C (E / compared to A / ). Without trade, total production of wheat is 130 (90+40), but with trade it is 180 (all in the US). Without trade, total production of cloth is 100 (60+40), but with trade it is 120 (all in the UK). Gains from trade come from the increase in production due to specialization (50W and 20C); shared by both nations through trade, and thus lead to increased consumption. Without trade no nation would specialize in production because both need to consume some of the other commodity. The End 26 13