Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Similar documents
Unobserved Heterogeneity Revisited

Games of Incomplete Information ( 資訊不全賽局 ) Games of Incomplete Information

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

Today. Applications of NE and SPNE Auctions English Auction Second-Price Sealed-Bid Auction First-Price Sealed-Bid Auction

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

UCLA Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Exam Industrial Organization Field Exam (Spring 2010) Use SEPARATE booklets to answer each question

Auctions. Michal Jakob Agent Technology Center, Dept. of Computer Science and Engineering, FEE, Czech Technical University

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Bayesian games and their use in auctions. Vincent Conitzer

Auctions: Types and Equilibriums

Strategy -1- Strategy

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Auction. Li Zhao, SJTU. Spring, Li Zhao Auction 1 / 35

Optimal Auctions. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Auction is a commonly used way of allocating indivisible

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Microeconomics Comprehensive Exam

Auction Theory: Some Basics

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Bayesian Nash Equilibrium

Auctions That Implement Efficient Investments

Lecture 6 Applications of Static Games of Incomplete Information

Identification and Estimation of Dynamic Games when Players Beliefs are not in Equilibrium

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Resolving Failed Banks: Uncertainty, Multiple Bidding, & Auction Design

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Auctions. Agenda. Definition. Syllabus: Mansfield, chapter 15 Jehle, chapter 9

Simon Fraser University Spring 2014

The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Games with Private Information 資訊不透明賽局

Microeconomic Theory III Spring 2009

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Game Theory Problem Set 4 Solutions

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

All Equilibrium Revenues in Buy Price Auctions

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Algorithmic Game Theory

An Ascending Double Auction

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #18: Multi-Parameter Revenue-Maximization

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Random Search Techniques for Optimal Bidding in Auction Markets

Math 152: Applicable Mathematics and Computing

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

MS&E 246: Lecture 2 The basics. Ramesh Johari January 16, 2007

Notes for Section: Week 7

Mechanism Design and Auctions

GAME THEORY. Department of Economics, MIT, Follow Muhamet s slides. We need the following result for future reference.

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

Game Theory: Global Games. Christoph Schottmüller

1 Theory of Auctions. 1.1 Independent Private Value Auctions

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Notes for Section: Week 4

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Game Theory Lecture #16

Mechanism Design and Auctions

Up till now, we ve mostly been analyzing auctions under the following assumptions:

PhD Qualifier Examination

Sequential Rationality and Weak Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

Identification and Counterfactuals in Dynamic Models of Market Entry and Exit

Recalling that private values are a special case of the Milgrom-Weber setup, we ve now found that

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

Advanced Microeconomics

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Microeconomic Theory May 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program.

1 Auctions. 1.1 Notation (Symmetric IPV) Independent private values setting with symmetric riskneutral buyers, no budget constraints.

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

HW Consider the following game:

Evaluating Strategic Forecasters. Rahul Deb with Mallesh Pai (Rice) and Maher Said (NYU Stern) Becker Friedman Theory Conference III July 22, 2017

Budget Management In GSP (2018)

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Lecture 5: Iterative Combinatorial Auctions

Auctions 1: Common auctions & Revenue equivalence & Optimal mechanisms. 1 Notable features of auctions. use. A lot of varieties.

GMM for Discrete Choice Models: A Capital Accumulation Application

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

17 MAKING COMPLEX DECISIONS

A simulation study of two combinatorial auctions

Auctions. Microeconomics II. Auction Formats. Auction Formats. Many economic transactions are conducted through auctions treasury bills.

Chapter 3: Computing Endogenous Merger Models.

Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints

Independent Private Value Auctions

Strategy -1- Strategic equilibrium in auctions

Information Aggregation in Dynamic Markets with Strategic Traders. Michael Ostrovsky

Transcription:

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction Joan Llull Structural Micro. IDEA PhD Program I. Dynamic Discrete Games with Imperfect Information A. Motivating example: firm entry and exit The estimation of oligopolistic discrete games is very popular in industrial organization (IO). As a motivating example, we consider firms decision of entry/continuation/exit from a market. Markets are small and isolated, and we focus on the retail sector. Each active firm operates at most in one location or store. We observe a random sample of markets m = 1, 2,..., M. In each market, there are N potentially active and infinitely lived firms which decide simultaneously whether to operate or not. The distinction here between firms and markets is very important. We have N M firms (we assume that firms at most operate in one market) whose payoffs are affected by the decisions of other players in the same market. This is the main difference with what we have seen so far. In our example, the profit function is: Π it = θ RS ln S m(i)t θ RN ln 1 +, (1) {j:j m(i),j i} where d jt = 1 if firm j is active in marked m(j) and S m(i)t is the market size. This profit function can be interpreted as the outcome of a static symmetric game. In a competitive setup, there are so many players that individual firm s decisions do not affect decisions of other firms, as the measure of firms operating in the market is unaffected. However, in an oligopolistic market, the number of firms operating in the market is a best-response function with respect to competitor s choices. The fixed cost paid every year by a firm active on a market is: F it = ω F i + ε 1it, (2) where ε 1it represents an idiosyncratic shock to firm i s fixed cost. The entry cost, paid only when the firm was not active in the previous period, is given by: E it = (1 d it 1 )ω Ei. (3) Hence, the total current profits of an active firm with observable state variables x it (S m(i)t, d i, d it 1 ), where d i is the vector of choices for all firms in the d jt 1

same market as i except i itself, are: U it (1, x it, ω i, ε it ) = (4) θ RS ln S m(i)t θ RN ln 1 + ω F i (1 d it 1 )ω Ei + ε 1it. {j:j m(i),j i} The profit function of a non-active firm is given by the value of the best outside option, that we assume to be: U it (0, x it, ω i, ε it ) = ω Ni + ε 0it, (5) where ω Ni is normalized to zero for identification purposes. The unobserved state vector ε it is assumed to be private information of firm i, unknown by other players in the market. We assume that it is normally distributed, i.i.d. across firms and markets, and over time, with zero mean. x it and ω i are common knowledge. The researcher observes x it but not ε it and ω i. Note that this model embeds Rust s framework with unobserved heterogeneity whenever θ RN = 0. However, if θ RN 0, d it(x it, ω i, ε it ) is a best response function. The actual decisions are given by the solution of the Nash equilibrium. Full solution methods are often unfeasible in this context. Aguirregabiria and Mira (2007) propose a Hotz-Miller based estimation method for dynamic discrete games. A potential complication of this may be the existence of multiple equilibria, but it can also be handled in estimation. B. General setup One of the costly aspects of dynamic discrete games is the need for solving for the equilibrium in each period. If in single agent problems solving for the value functions implies a nested fixed points, in the games context there is a double nesting because on top of solving for the individual s problem, one also needs to solve for the equilibrium conditions. CCP estimations has turned particularly important in developing techniques that allowed us to advance in the possibilities of estimating such problems. To generalize the setup from the example above, let d it denote the own action of individual i, and let d it (d 1t,..., d i 1,t, d i+1,t,..., d It ) denote the actions of all other I 1 players. The flow utility of individual i choosing alternative j is thus: u ij (x t, d it ) + ε ijt, (6) where ε it (ε i1t,..., ε ijt ) is an i.i.d. random variable privately observed by individual i but not by the others. The vector x t, on the contrary, is observed by 2 d jt

all individuals, and, therefore, includes the state variables of all individuals. The dependence of u ij ( ) on i is a reflection of the possibility of different state variables affecting payoffs differently (e.g. own state variables vs other individuals ); the absence of t in it reflects that we are in a stationary environment. Choices are taken simultaneously in each period. We concentrate on rational stationary Markov perfect equilibria, which imply that, given that ε it is i.i.d. across individuals, individual i expects other agents to make choices d it with probabilities: Pr(d it x t ) = Pr(d jt x t ). (7) j i These CCPs represent the best-response probability functions. In this type of models, an equilibrium exists, but uniqueness is rather unlikely to hold. However, these CCPs uniquely identify the beliefs of agents. Taking expectations of u ij (x t, d it ) over d it, we obtain: ũ ij (x t ) = Pr(d it x t )u ij (x t, d it ). (8) d it D I 1 These concentrated payoffs resemble the standard payoffs of the single-agent models seen so far. Now we additionally need to construct the continuation values. The difficulty on that front is that the state variables, which follow a process given by F x (x t+1 x t, d it, d it ), depend on the unobserved choices by the other individuals. Following a similar idea, we can obtain the concentrated transition functions as: F i (x t+1 x t, d it ) = Pr(d it x t )F x (x t+1 x t, d it, d it ). (9) d it D I 1 Given all this, the conditional value functions can be expressed as: v ij (x t ) = ũ ij (x t ) + β V (x t+1 )d F i (x t+1 x t, d it ), (10) and then V (x t+1 ) can be replaced the standard CCP representation, i.e.: v ij (x t ) = ũ ij (x t ) + β [v ik (x t ) + ψ k (p i (x t ))] d F i (x t+1 x t, d it ). (11) Once the model is transformed this way, estimation follows standard CCP procedures, which range from likelihood or GMM versions of Hotz and Miller (1993) to the iterative Nested Pseudo-Likelihood algorithm in Aguirregabiria and Mira (2002). The latter is the approach adopted in the seminal paper by Aguirregabiria and Mira (2007). 3

Note that the use of CCP estimation methods made the estimation of these models feasible. Full solution maximum likelihood approaches would not be tractable, because it would require solving for the equilibrium of the game (on top of solving for the dynamic problem). Furthermore, the estimation is based on conditions that are satisfied by every Markov perfect equilibrium, which skips the complication generated by the existence of multiple equilibria. II. Auctions A. Introduction Auctions are often used as mechanisms for allocation of resources to bidders in an as efficient as possible way. There are many interesting real-world applications that generate interesting data and a great deal of opportunities for empirical investigation, raising interesting issues. As a result, there is an important and growing literature in empirical micro that aims at structurally estimating the parameters of the bidders valuations. This is of fundamental importance for auction design, because they allow the simulation of efficiency results under different types of auction mechanism. It allows to determine the optimal design, and the parameters of this design (e.g. the reserve prices). Since the aim of this section is only to provide a brief introduction to the structural estimation of auctions, we focus on two particular types of auctions: first and second price sealed bid auctions for one good, N players, and independent valuations v i for i = 1,..., N. In the first price sealed bid auctions, each player simultaneously submits a bid, and the object is assigned to the highest bidder, who pays the price she bid. In the second price sealed bid auctions, the highest bidder wins, but pays the bid of the second highest bidder. The literature has studied other types of auctions. For example, English auctions are similar to first price sealed bid auctions except that bidders sequentially call ascending prices, and other players observe bids. In Dutch auctions, the price is reduced until a player accepts the offer, so only the winning bid is ever observed. In Japanese auctions, players exit as the auctioneer raises the price, and the winner pays the price at which the only other remaining bidder exits. While Dutch auctions are strategically equivalent to first price sealed bid auctions, Japanese auctions are not necessarily strategically equivalent to second price sealed bid auctions, because players update their information sets as the auction evolves. As noted above, we focus on single object first and second price sealed bid auctions. There are N risk-neutral bidders (indexed by i = 1,..., N) and they have valuations v i, independently drawn from a common distribution F ( ). The 4

data consists of the outcomes observed across independent auctions k = 1,..., K that follow the same paradigm. In this introductory review, we focus on the case where individual i observes her own valuation v i, but not other players valuations. The literature also analyzes the case in which the individual, instead, has a signal x i v i, but does not observe v i, and also the case in which different players have a (partially) common valuation. Players submit a single bid b i IR + and do not observe other players bids. The econometrician only observes bids, either all of them, or only the winning bid or price. The structural estimation of auction models usually rely on the equilibrium bid functions and on distributional assumptions regarding F ( ), which often is specified parametrically. The literature focuses on Perfect Bayesian Equilibria in weakly undominated pure strategies. A bidding strategy is a function that maps valuations into bids. The bidding strategy is the equilibrium solution of a expected utility maximization problem. B. Equilibrium responses in second and first price sealed bid auctions In second price sealed bid auctions, it is a weakly dominant strategy for every individual to bid her expected valuation, i.e. b i = v i. Intuitively, bidding more implies winning some auctions that yield negative expected value but leaves unchanged the expected value of any other auction that would be won, whereas bidding less implies losing some auctions that yield positive expected value but leaves unchanged the expected value of any other auction that she would win. In a first price sealed bid auction, best responses are slightly more complicated, because, unlike in the second price counterpart, changing the bid not only affects the probability of winning, but also the price to pay. Let p(b) denote the probability of winning the auction with bid b, defined as: p i (b) Pr(max{b j } j i b). (12) Then, b i solves: b i = arg max(v i b)p i (b). (13) b The resulting b i is the best response to other player s expected actions. The first order condition yields: (v i b i )p (b i ) p(b i ) = 0. (14) 5

Totally differentiating this expression with respect to b and v, we obtain: db i dv i = p (b i ) (v i b i )p (b i ) 2p (b i ) > 0. (15) The last inequality is obtained from observing that the denominator is the second order condition (and, hence, it is negative), and that the winning probability is increasing in the bid. Therefore, if players are in pure strategy equilibrium with an interior solution, then b i is increasing in v i. This ensures invertibility, and, hence, identification. C. Identification Let F (v) denote the distribution of valuations. In a second price sealed bid auction, the distribution of valuations is trivially identified if all bids are observed because, as noted before, all players bid their valuation. The case in which only the winning price is observed (in each of K auctions in which the same equilibrium is played) is a bit more convoluted. If only the winning price is observed, which equals to the second highest bid, then the probability distribution of the second highest valuation, denoted by F N 1,N (v) is identified trivially from the distribution of paid prices. Let f N 1,N (v) denote the corresponding density. Given symmetry and independence, this density equals: f N 1,N (v) = N(N 1)F (v) N 2 (1 F (v))f(v). (16) Intuitively, the N(N 1) comes from the combinatorial possibilities in which v is the second highest valuation, F (v) N 2 is the probability that N 2 valuations are lower than v, and 1 F (v) is the probability that one of them is higher. Given a boundary condition F N 1,N (v) = F (v) = 0, and noting that f(v) > 0 above the boundary condition, the identification of F (v) comes from solving the differential equation above. In first price sealed bid auctions, identification comes from the first order condition above. If all bids are observed, then p(b) is trivially identified. Hence, v i is identified from (14): v i = b i + p(b i) p (b i ) = b G(b i ) i + (N 1)g(b i ), (17) where G( ) and g( ) are respectively the cdf and pdf of observed bids, and the latter equality is obtained from noting that p(b) = G(b) N 1. Therefore, the probability distribution of (v 1,..., v N ) is identified off the bidding distribution G(b). 6

If only the winning bid is recorded, the distribution of winning bids, H(b) is identified from the outcomes observed in the different auctions. Since the winning bid is defined as the highest one, H(b) is just the probability that all the bids in all the auctions are less than or equal to b, such that: H(b) = Pr(b k i b i = 1,..., N) = G(b) N. (18) Therefore: G(b) = H(b) 1 N, (19) and: g(b) = 1 N H(b) 1 N 1 h(b), (20) where h(b) is the density of winning bids. Replacing these two in (17), this shows that the bidding distribution is identified off the winning bid distribution. D. Estimation Estimation strategies range from minimum distance to maximum likelihood. In minimum distance estimation, once the distribution of bids is derived, up to parameter values, these parameters are estimated comparing sample moments of the observed bids against theoretical moments of the G( ) distribution for each parameter value. Sometimes, this moments are trivial functions of the parameters, and standard minimum distance methods are easy to implement. Other times, it is too costly to derive the theoretical moments from the distribution, and we proceed with simulated method of moments, using Monte Carlo approaches. In particular, for a given set of parameters, valuations are drawn for all players. This valuations correspond to bids, given the equilibrium bidding strategies of each player. Keeping the seed fixed, iterate over parameters to minimize the distance between simulated and data moments. Maximum likelihood approaches are also feasible, but have the complication that the upper bound of the support often depends on parameter values, which lead to estimates that, while consistent, are not asymptotically normal. 7