Markets with convex transaction costs

Similar documents
arxiv: v1 [q-fin.pr] 11 Oct 2008

Superhedging in illiquid markets

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Arbitrage and deflators in illiquid markets

Convex duality in optimal investment under illiquidity

Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under Proportional Transaction Costs in Finite Discrete Time

Viability, Arbitrage and Preferences

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices

Mathematical Finance in discrete time

Arbitrage Theory. The research of this paper was partially supported by the NATO Grant CRG

In Discrete Time a Local Martingale is a Martingale under an Equivalent Probability Measure

Arbitrage Theory without a Reference Probability: challenges of the model independent approach

arxiv: v3 [q-fin.pr] 22 Dec 2013

Consistency of option prices under bid-ask spreads

- Introduction to Mathematical Finance -

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Pathwise Finance: Arbitrage and Pricing-Hedging Duality

No-arbitrage Pricing Approach and Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

MATH 5510 Mathematical Models of Financial Derivatives. Topic 1 Risk neutral pricing principles under single-period securities models

3.2 No-arbitrage theory and risk neutral probability measure

European Contingent Claims

Asset valuation and optimal investment

Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets

Minimal Variance Hedging in Large Financial Markets: random fields approach

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Option Pricing with Delayed Information

Compulsory Assignment

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

The Birth of Financial Bubbles

Portfolio Optimisation under Transaction Costs

based on two joint papers with Sara Biagini Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa, Università degli Studi di Perugia

Lower and upper bounds of martingale measure densities in continuous time markets

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Non-semimartingales in finance

MESURES DE RISQUE DYNAMIQUES DYNAMIC RISK MEASURES

ECOLE POLYTECHNIQUE CENTRE DE MATHÉMATIQUES APPLIQUÉES UMR CNRS PALAISEAU CEDEX (FRANCE). Tél: Fax:

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

A Note on the No Arbitrage Condition for International Financial Markets

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

3 Arbitrage pricing theory in discrete time.

Conditional Certainty Equivalent

1 No-arbitrage pricing

Polynomial processes in stochastic portofolio theory

INTRODUCTION TO ARBITRAGE PRICING OF FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES

The super-replication theorem under proportional transaction costs revisited

6: MULTI-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

On the law of one price

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Hedging under Arbitrage

A Robust Option Pricing Problem

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

arxiv: v3 [q-fin.pm] 26 Sep 2018

Fundamental Theorems of Asset Pricing. 3.1 Arbitrage and risk neutral probability measures

Robust hedging with tradable options under price impact

How do Variance Swaps Shape the Smile?

A utility maximization proof of Strassen s theorem

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

CONSISTENCY AMONG TRADING DESKS

Indices of Acceptability as Performance Measures. Dilip B. Madan Robert H. Smith School of Business

PDE Approach to Credit Derivatives

ON THE FUNDAMENTAL THEOREM OF ASSET PRICING. Dedicated to the memory of G. Kallianpur

On Utility Based Pricing of Contingent Claims in Incomplete Markets

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Asymptotic Maturity Behavior of the Term Structure

Umut Çetin and L. C. G. Rogers Modelling liquidity effects in discrete time

On an optimization problem related to static superreplicating

LIST OF PUBLICATIONS

arxiv: v13 [q-fin.gn] 29 Jan 2016

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

Changes of the filtration and the default event risk premium

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Non replication of options

Strong bubbles and strict local martingales

LECTURE 4: BID AND ASK HEDGING

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Replication and Absence of Arbitrage in Non-Semimartingale Models

CHAPTER 2 Concepts of Financial Economics and Asset Price Dynamics

Interest rate models in continuous time

Optimal construction of a fund of funds

Games of Incomplete Information

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Robust Portfolio Choice and Indifference Valuation

Martingale Optimal Transport and Robust Finance

Optimization in Finance

Exact replication under portfolio constraints: a viability approach

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under Transaction Costs

Martingale Transport, Skorokhod Embedding and Peacocks

A No-Arbitrage Model Of Liquidity In Financial Markets Involving Stochastic Strings: Applications To High-Frequency Data

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

A new approach for valuing a portfolio of illiquid assets

Continuous-time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications

Hedging under arbitrage

Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models. Beatrice Acciaio

PAPER 211 ADVANCED FINANCIAL MODELS

Transcription:

1 Markets with convex transaction costs Irina Penner Humboldt University of Berlin Email: penner@math.hu-berlin.de Joint work with Teemu Pennanen Helsinki University of Technology Special Semester on Stochastics with Emphasis on Finance Concluding Workshop, Linz, December 2, 2008

Markets with convex transaction costs 2 The Market Model The market consists of d assets traded at t = 0,..., T. Filtered probability space (Ω, F, (F t ) T t=0, P ). The price of a portfolio is a non-linear function of the amount due to transaction costs, other illiquidity effects... Modeling portfolio processes becomes an issue. Kabanov (1999): Portfolios are vectors in R d, expressing the number of physical units of assets (or values of assets in terms of some numéraire). The set of all portfolios that can be transformed to a vector in R d + is a random subset of R d : solvency region. The form of the solvency region is determined by the current price and transaction costs.

Markets with convex transaction costs 3 The Market Model A market model is a sequence (C t ) T t=0 of F t -measurable set-valued mappings Ω R d such that each C t (ω) is a closed subset of R d with R d C t (ω). For each t and ω C t (ω) denotes the set of all portfolios that are freely available in the market. A market model is called convex, if each C t (ω) is convex. A convex market model is called conical, if each C t (ω) is a cone.

Markets with convex transaction costs 4 Example 1: Frictionless market If (S t ) T t=0 is an adapted price process with values in R d +, then C t (ω) = {x R d S t (ω) x 0}, t = 0,..., T defines a conical market model.

Markets with convex transaction costs 5 Example 2: Proportional transaction costs [Kabanov (1999)]: If (S t ) T t=0 is an adapted price process and (Λ t ) T t=0 an adapted matrix of transaction costs coefficients, the solvency regions are defined as ˆK t := {x R d a R d d + : x i S i t + d (a ji (1 + λ ij t )a ij ) 0, 1 i d}. j=1 One can also define solvency regions directly in terms of bid-ask matrices (Π t ) T t=0 as in [Schachermayer (2004)]: ˆK t = {x R d a R d d + : x i + d j=1 (aji π ij t a ij ) 0, 1 i d}. For each ω and t the set ˆK t (ω) is a polyhedral cone and C t (ω) := ˆK t (ω), t = 0,..., T defines a conical market model.

Markets with convex transaction costs 6 Example 3: Convex price processes [Astic and Touzi (2007)], [Pennanen (2006)] A convex price process is a sequence (S t ) T t=0 of R {+ }-valued functions on R d Ω such that for each t the function S t is B(R d ) F t -measurable and for each ω the function S t (, ω) is lower semicontinuous, convex and vanishes at 0. S t (x, ω) denotes the total price of buying a portfolio x at time t and scenario ω. If (S t ) T t=0 is a convex price process, then C t (ω) = {x R d S t (x, ω) 0}, t = 0,..., T defines a convex market model.

Markets with convex transaction costs 7 Example 3: Convex price processes

Markets with convex transaction costs 8 Example 3: Convex price processes [Çetin and Rogers (2007)]: A market with one riskfree and one risky asset. The convex price process is given by S t ((y, x), ω) = y + s t (ω)ϕ(x) for a strictly positive adapted price process of a risky asset (s t ) T t=0 and a strictly convex and increasing function ϕ : R (, ]. (Example: ϕ(x) = eαx 1 α.) [Çetin, Jarrow and Protter (2004)]: A supply curve s t (x, ω) gives a price per unit of x units of a risky asset. Then the total price is given by S t ((y, x), ω) = y + s t (x, ω)x. No assumptions about convexity, smoothness required.

Markets with convex transaction costs 9 Example 4: Convex transaction costs Replace a bid-ask matrix (Π t ) T t=0 by a matrix of convex price processes (S ij t ) T t=0 (1 i, j d) on R +. S ij (x, ω) denotes the number of units of asset i for which one can buy x units of asset j. In a market with proportional transaction π ij (ω)x if x 0, costs we have S ij (x, ω) = 1 π ji (ω) x if x 0. If (S ij t ) (1 i, j d) are sequences of convex price processes on R +, then C t (ω) = {x R d a R d d + : x i d (a ji S ij t (a ij, ω)), 1 i d} j=1 defines a convex market model.

Markets with convex transaction costs 10 Notation A denotes the set of all adapted R d -valued processes. A process x A is a self-financing portfolio processes if x t x t 1 C t P -a.s. for all t = 0,..., T We always define x 1 := 0. The set of all final values of self-financial portfolio processes (or, equivalently, of all claims that can be replicated at no cost) is denoted by A T (C)

Markets with convex transaction costs 11 Motivation: Hedging We want to give a dual characterization of the set of all initial endowments that allow an investor to hedge a given claim Hedging theorem. A key to the hedging theorem is no-arbitrage condition and FTAP: In a classical frictionless model it provides existence of pricing martingales (martingale measures) provides closedness of the set A T (C) of all claims that can be replicated at no cost.

Markets with convex transaction costs 12 Motivation: Hedging In a market with proportional transaction costs several natural generalizations of the notions of arbitrage and martingale measures are possible [Kabanov and Stricker (2001)], [Schachermayer (2004)], [Grigoriev (2005)], [Rásonyi (2008)]... In a market with convex structure martingale measures are not sufficient for the dual characterization [Föllmer and Kramkov (1997)]... We are interested in a no-arbitrage notion that implies closedness of the set A T (C).

Markets with convex transaction costs 13 No-arbitrage notions for conical models [Kabanov and Stricker (2001)], [Kabanov, Rásonyi and Stricker (2001), (2003)], [Schachermayer (2004)] A market model C has the no arbitrage property if A T (C) L 0 (R d +) = {0}, where A T (C) = {x T x is self-financing}. A market model C dominates a conical market model C if C t C t and C t \ C 0 t ri C t for all t = 0,..., T, where C 0 t = C t C t. A conical market model C has the robust no-arbitrage property if C is dominated by another conical model C which has the no-arbitrage property.

Markets with convex transaction costs 14 No-arbitrage notions for convex models Given a convex market model C, we define a conical market model C by C t (ω) = {x R d C t (ω) + αx C t (ω) α > 0}, t = 0,..., T. C t (ω) is the recession cone of C t (ω): C t (ω) = α>0 αc t (ω) If C is conical then C = C. The set Ct the origin. (ω) describes the behavior of C t (ω) infinitely far from We say that a convex market model C has the robust no scalable arbitrage property if the model C has the robust no-arbitrage property.

Markets with convex transaction costs 15 No-arbitrage notions for convex models Given a convex market model C, one can also consider the conical market model C given by C t(ω) := cl α>0 αc t (ω), t = 0,..., T. C t (ω) is the tangent cone of C t (ω). If C is conical then C = C. The set C t(ω) describes the behavior of C t (ω) close to the origin. We say that a convex market model C has the robust no marginal arbitrage property if the model C has the robust no-arbitrage property.

Markets with convex transaction costs 16 Main result Theorem 1 If the convex market model C has the robust no scalable arbitrage property then the set A T (C) of all claims that can be replicated with zero initial investment is closed in probability.

Markets with convex transaction costs 17 Applications: Hedging A contingent claim processes with physical delivery c = (c t ) T t=0 A is a security that gives its owner a random portfolio c t possibly at each time t = 0,..., T. The set of all claim processes that can be replicated with zero initial investment is A(C) = {c A x A : x t x t 1 +c t C t, t = 0,..., T, x T = 0}. We call a process p A a super-hedging premium process for a claim process c if c p A(C). If c = (0,..., 0, c T ) and p = (p 0, 0,..., 0), then c p A(C) iff there exists a self-financing portfolio process such that c T p 0 + x T.

Markets with convex transaction costs 18 Applications: Hedging Theorem 2 [Hedging Theorem] Assume that a market model C is convex and that it has the robust no scalable arbitrage property. Let c, p A be such that c p L 1 (P ). Then the following are equivalent: (i) p is a super-hedging premium process for c. [ T ] [ T ] (ii) E (c t p t ) z t E σ Ct (z t ) t=0 t=0 for every R d +-valued bounded martingale (z t ) T t=0. Here σ Ct (ω) denotes the support function of C t (ω): σ Ct (ω)(z) := sup x z, z R d. x C t (ω)

Markets with convex transaction costs 19 Applications: Hedging If C is conical, we have σ Ct (ω)(y) = 0 if y Ct (ω), + otherwise. An adapted R d \ { 0}-valued process z = (z t ) T t=0 is called a consistent price system for a conical model C, if z is a martingale such that z t C t almost surely for all t. z = (z t ) T t=0 is called a strictly consistent price system for a conical model C if z is a martingale with strictly positive components and such that z t ri C t almost surely for all t. [Kabanov, Rásonyi and Stricker (2001), (2003)], [Schachermayer (2004)]

Markets with convex transaction costs 20 Applications: Hedging Corollary 3 Assume that C is a conical market model and that it has the robust no arbitrage property. Assume further that F 0 is trivial and let c T L 1 (P ) and p 0 R. Then the following are equivalent. (i) p = (p 0, 0,..., 0) is a super-hedging premium for c = (0,..., 0, c T ). (ii) E [c T z T ] p 0 z 0 for every bounded consistent price system (z t ) T t=0. (iii) E [c T z T ] p 0 z 0 for every bounded strictly consistent price system (z t ) T t=0. [Kabanov, Rásonyi and Stricker (2003)], [Schachermayer (2004)]

Markets with convex transaction costs 21 Applications: FTAP Theorem 4 [FTAP] A convex market model C has the robust no scalable arbitrage property if and only if there exists a strictly positive martingale z such that z t ri dom σ Ct for all t. (Equivalently: there exists a strictly consistent price system z for C ). A convex market model C has the robust no marginal arbitrage property if and only if there exists a strictly positive martingale z such that z t (dom σ Ct ) for all t. (Equivalently: there exists a strictly consistent price system z for C ). Similar results in [Kabanov, Rásonyi and Stricker (2003)] and [Schachermayer (2004)] for polyhedral conical models and in [Rásonyi (2007)] and [Rokhlin (2007)] for more general conical models.

Markets with convex transaction costs 22 Thank you for your attention!