Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment *

Similar documents
Export performance requirements under international duopoly*

Public Schemes for Efficiency in Oligopolistic Markets

International Rent-shifting under Foreign Entry. through R&D and Licensing

Optimal Trade Policies for Exporting Countries under the Stackelberg Type of Competition between Firms

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Volume 29, Issue 1. Second-mover advantage under strategic subsidy policy in a third market model

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Export Taxes under Bertrand Duopoly. Abstract

International Economics B 6. Applications of international oligopoly models

Export Subsidies versus Export Quotas with Incompletely Informed Policy Makers

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Overview Basic analysis Strategic trade policy Further topics. Overview

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

research paper series

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Pension System and Time Preference in an Endowment Economy

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Funded Pension Scheme, Endogenous Time Preference and Capital Accumulation

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

Environmental Tax Competition in the Presence of Multinational Firms

Profit Share and Partner Choice in International Joint Ventures

Environmental Regulation Induced Foreign Direct Investment

Using Trade Policy to Influence Firm Location. This Version: 9 May 2006 PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE DO NOT CITE

Efficiency, Privatization, and Political Participation

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Emission Taxes, Relocation, and Quality Differences

International Trade Agreements, Environmental Policy, and Emergence of Multinational Firms

Environmental Regulations, International Trade and Strategic Behavior

Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies

SHORTER PAPERS. Tariffs versus Quotas under Market Price Uncertainty. Hung-Yi Chen and Hong Hwang. 1 Introduction

Coordination of tax policies toward inward foreign direct investment

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

Welfare in a Unionized Bertrand Duopoly. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay* and Sudeshna C. Bandyopadhyay

Notes on Auctions. Theorem 1 In a second price sealed bid auction bidding your valuation is always a weakly dominant strategy.

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

EconoQuantum ISSN: Universidad de Guadalajara México

International Trade Lecture 8: Strategic Trade Policy

A new model of mergers and innovation

Strategic environmental policy under free trade with transboundary pollution

Foreign direct investment and export under imperfectly competitive host-country input market

1 Dynamic programming

Online Shopping Intermediaries: The Strategic Design of Search Environments

3. Trade and Development

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

Noncooperative Oligopoly

1. Consider a small country (Thailand) with the following demand and supply curves for steel:

Strategic export policy, monopoly carrier, and product differentiation

Price undertakings, VERs, and foreign direct investment # October 2006

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

The Timing of Endogenous Wage Setting under Bertrand Competition in a Unionized Mixed Duopoly

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

Export restrictions on non renewable resources used as intermediate consumption in oligopolistic industries

Strategic R&D Policy in a Quality-Differentiated Industry. with More than Two Exporting Countries

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Domestic Lobbying and Foreign Direct Investment

Regional versus Multilateral Trade Liberalization, Environmental Taxation and Welfare

Strategic Trade Policy unotes14.pdf Chapter Environment: imperfectly competitive firms with increasing returns to scale.

Strategic Trade Policy under Isoelastic Demand and Asymmetric Production Costs

International Coordination of Environmental Policies: Is it Always Worth the Effort?

A NOTE ON MARKET COVERAGE IN VERTICAL DIFFERENTIATION MODELS WITH FIXED COSTS

Rafael Espinosa Ramirez, joint with M. Ozgur Strategic Environmental Policies and Mergers

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Environmental Tax Burden in a Vertical Relationship with Pollution-Abatement R&D

Tariffs, Vertical Oligopoly and Market Structure

Vertical integration and upstream horizontal mergers

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

A Model of Vertical Oligopolistic Competition. Markus Reisinger & Monika Schnitzer University of Munich University of Munich

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

Volume 29, Issue 2. Equilibrium Location and Economic Welfare in Delivered Pricing Oligopoly

Emission Permits Trading Across Imperfectly Competitive Product Markets

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Economics 230a, Fall 2018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition

Welfare and Profit Comparison between Quantity and Price Competition in Stackelberg Mixed Duopolies

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Switching Costs and the foreign Firm s Entry

Free entry and social efficiency in an open economy. Arghya Ghosh, Jonathan Lim, and Hodaka Morita

Profit tax and tariff under international oligopoly

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Economic Perspectives on the Advance Market Commitment for Pneumococcal Vaccines

Endogenous choice of decision variables

Environmental Taxation and Strategic Commitment in Duopoly Models

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

Economic Integration, Trade Diversion, and Welfare Change

Export Subsidies and Oligopoly with Switching Costs

Tariffs, Vertical Oligopoly, and Market Structure

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

Price undertakings, VERs, and foreign direct investment. The case of foreign rivalry # Jota Ishikawa * and Kaz Miyagiwa **

Transcription:

名古屋学院大学論集社会科学篇第 45 巻第 4 号 (2009 年 3 月 ) Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment * Tomohiro KURODA 1 Introduction Worldwide environmental destruction has been attracting considerable attention. Obviously, emissions from production activities are the major causes of the environmental problems. When firms generate emissions, the conventional wisdom says that the government should intervene to restrict the production. Environmental standards are typical policy measures for this purpose. The standards restrict the level of production and hence the negative externalities generated by emissions are internalized. In this age of globalization, however, production and consumption may not be done at home. For example, by undertaking foreign direct investment (FDI), firms may not produce in their own countries. The differences in the pollution regulation among countries might cause the pollution activities to be relocated in the countries with relatively lower pollution regulations. When the domestic government adopts tough environmental regulations, domestic firms may shift their plants abroad. 1 Attracting FDI generates employment. If emission regulations are loose enough abroad, for example, environmental damages could become worse as a result of the plant relocation. That is, there usually exist multiple markets. Thus, the framework of an open economy is indispensable to examine emission regulations. These arguments above show that the relationship between the environmental policy and the foreign direct investments becomes more important issue. Nevertheless, there are limited literature on the interaction between them. Barrett [1994] deals with strategic environmental standards in the third-country model, however, his model does not contain the foreign direct investments. The purpose of this paper is to shed light on the effects of FDI on emission regulations in the open economy. We consider the strategic aspects of environmental standards with or without FDI, and analyze the role of cooperation. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Next section contains the cases where emissions are * Author acknowledges the Grant-in-Aid for Research from the Research Institute of Nagoya Gakuin University in 2006. Faculty of Economics, Nagoya Gakuin University, Nagoya, Aichi 456 8612, Japan; Phone: +81 52 678 4080, Fax: +81 52 682 6812; E-mail: tkuroda@ngu.ac.jp 1 See Markusen, Morey, and Olewiler [1993, 1995], Kayalica and Lahiri [2000] for example. 103

名古屋学院大学論集 generated by production. Our analysis focuses on the effectiveness of environmental standards. The last section concludes the paper. 2 The basic model In this model there are two exporting countries (labeled by 1,2) and one consuming(third country) country. There is one firm in each exporting country which operates for the oligopolistic market of a homogeneous good in the consuming country. The inverse demand function of the oligopolistic good is given by: p=α-βd, (1) where D is the total consumption in the third country. D=x 1 +x 2, (2) where x i is the output of oligopolistic good produced by country(firm) i=1, 2. Production of the good causes local pollution. Firms have the pollution abating technologies. The governments regulate the local pollution by setting a quantity restriction by emission standards. Average (and marginal) costs of producing firm are, given the environmental standards set by the governments, k i =c i +μ(θ i -z i ). (3) c i is a constant per unit cost determined by the production technology and factor market conditions. μ is a constant unit cost of abatement, θ i is the gross pollution per unit, and z i (0, θ i ) is the maximum quantity of pollution per unit that the firms are allowed to emit into the atmosphere. Note that the smaller z means the stricter environmental restriction. The profits are given by: π i =(p-k i )x i. (4) We assume that there are unemployment in countries 1 and 2. Following Brander and Spencer [1987], factor input costs are taken to be the income of the factors which would remain unemployed in the absence of the production of the oligopolistic good. Hence the welfare levels of the country 1 and 2 are given by following W i. W i =c i x i +π i -φ i x i z i, (5) where φ i is the marginal dis-utility of environmental damage. We consider the two different scenarios, (see descriptions below), with or without FDI. Scenario 1: No FDI appears. Each firm operates in its own country. Profit belongs to the country 104

Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment where it operates. 1. Assuming that the firms behave in a Cournot-Nash fashion, we characterize the optimal z i which will maximize each country s welfare. 2. Moreover, we consider the uniform policy reform from non-cooperative equilibrium. We can show that the reform turns to be welfare-improving. 3. We characterize the cooperative equilibrium levels of z c i. Scenario 2: Firm located in the country 1 is owned by the foreign multinationals of the rest of the world. Profit of the firm 1 no longer belongs to country 1. 1. Assuming that the firms behave in a Cournot-Nash fashion, we characterize the optimal z i which will maximize each country s welfare. 2. Moreover, We characterize the cooperative equilibrium levels of z c i. 3. We reconsider the role of the FDI and the levels of restriction. 3 Without Foreign Direct Investment 3.1 Non-cooperative equilibrium The Cournot-Nash non-cooperative equilibrium output is obtained by first order conditions of profit maximization. x i = α+k j-2k i 3β. (6) Totally differentiating x i and π i, we obtain: dx 1 = 2μ 3β dz 1- μ 3β dz 2, (7) dx 2 =- μ 3β dz 1+ 2μ 3β dz 2, (8) dπ i = 4μ x i dz i + -2μ x i dz j. 3 3 (9) Totally differentiating W i, we have following formulas: 3βdW 1 =A 1 dz 1 +A 2 dz 2, (10) 3βdW 2 =A 3 dz 1 +A 4 dz 2, (11) where A 1 =[2μ(c 1 +2βx 1 ) -φ 1 (2μz 1 +3βx 1 )], A 2 =μ[φ 1 z 1 -c 1-2βx 1 ], A 3 =μ[φ 2 z 2 -c 2-2βx 2 ], 105

名古屋学院大学論集 A 4 = [2μ(c 2 +2βx 2 )-φ 2 (2μz 2 +3βx 2 )]. We discuss first the direct effects of each government s environmental policy on the welfare. When country 1 reduces z 1,i.e. dz 1 <0, the total environmental damage in the country 1 is reduced. Thus, the benefit of reducing environmental damage is given by second term in A 1, [-φ 1 (2μz 1 +3βx 1 )]dz 1 >0. Tougher standard is good for environment, however, the domestic production shrinks and unemployment expands. These deficits are given by the first term in A 1, [2μ(c 1 +2βx 1 )]dz 1 <0. Second, we examine the external effects of each government s environmental policy on the other country s welfare. When country 1 reduces z 1, the rival firm operating in country 2 expands the prodution and generates more emissions. The external effects are decomposed into following three effects: 1. Environmental damage in country 2 increases. (Negative for country 2) 2. Employment in country 2 increases. (Positive for country 2) 3. Profit of firm in country 2 increases. (Positive for country 2) These three effects are given by the coefficients of dz 1 in A 3. Non-cooperative equilibrium can be obtained by setting (dw i /dz i )=0, with A 2 =A 3 =0. z N i = 2μc i-βx i (3φ i -4μ), (12) 2μφ i where N denotes the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium. 3.2 Uniform policy reform from Nash equilibrium The uniform reduction in environmental standards is defined as dz 1 =dz 2 =-δ. (13) Evaluating the welfare at Nash non-cooperative levels, 2dW i z i=z i=φ N i x i δ>0 (14) Thus, we obtain following proposition. Proposition 1. Starting from the Nash equilibrium levels, uniform reduction in pollution allowance is welfare-improving for both countries. Tougher regulation means the decrease in the firm s profit, however, the improvement of the environmental damage can outweigh the negative effects. Therefore, as long as policy reform takes place uniformly, we can achieve the welfare enhancement for both countries. 3.3 Cooperative equilibrium From former subsection, we obtain the results that countries get better off by reducing their 106

Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment environmental standards uniformly. For simplicity, we assume identical technologies and marginal disutility of pollution, c i =c, θ i =θ, φ i =φ, we pay attention to the cooperative solution. From the assumption, non-cooperative (and cooperative) solutions become symmetric, i.e., z N 1=z N 2. In order to find the cooperative equilibrium, we define the total welfare W by adding W 1 and W 2. Totally differentiating W, 3βdW=(A 1 +A 3 )dz 1 +(A 2 +A 4 ) dz 2. (15) Setting the coefficients of dz i equal to zero and solving simultaneously for z i, we find the cooperative equilibrium as follows. z c i= μc- 2βx i( φ-μ)-φβx j μφ. (16) Comparing the solutions between non-cooperative and cooperative ones, we can state following proposition. Proposition 2. The governments impose more restrictive environmental standards under the cooperative equilibrium than that under non-cooperative equilibrium. Proof. z N i-z c i= βφx i+2φβx j 2μφ >0 (17) This is because the international externalities are negative. Under the cooperative solution governments take into account of A 2 0 and A 3 0. 4 With Foreign Direct Investment Consider the case where the foreign firm in country 1 is owned by the foreign multinationals in the rest of the world. One thing should be noted that the profit earned by the firm in country 1 no longer belongs to country 1. Thus, the welfare of the country 1 consists of employment and dis-utility from pollution. W 1 =c 1 x 1 -φ 1 x 1 z 1. (18) 4.1 Non-cooperative equilibrium Totally differentiating W i, we obtain the formulas of welfare changes. 107

名古屋学院大学論集 where 3βdW 1 =B 1 dz 1 +B 2 dz 2, (19) 3βdW 2 =B 3 dz 1 +B 4 dz 2, (20) B 1 =[2μc 1 -φ 1 (2μz 1 +3βx 1 )], B 2 =μ[φ 1 z 1 -c 1 ], B 3 =μ[φ 2 z 2 -c 2-2βx 2 ], B 4 =[2μ(c 2 +2βx 2 ) -φ 2 (2μz 2 +3βx 2 )]. Non-cooperative equilibrium can be obtained by setting (dw 1 /dz 1 )=0, (dw 2 /dz 2 )=0 and B 2 =B 3 =0. z N 1= 2μc 1-3βφ 1 x 1 2μφ 1, (21) z N 2= 2μc 2 -β x 2 (3φ 2-4μ ). (22) 2μφ 2 Comparing non-cooperative environmental standards, we have following proposition. Proposition 3. Suppose that the FDI only takes place in country 1. When the countries behave noncooperatively, the country 1, where the firm is owned by foreign multinationals, applies more severe environmental restriction than country 2. Proof. z N 1-z N 2=- 8(φω+μc ) < 0, (23) φ(45φ-28μ ) where ω=(α-μθ-c) =3βx 1 z 1=z 2=0> 0. Recalling that the profit earned by the firm in the country 1 does not belong to country 1, the government of country 1 takes account of welfare change through the employment and environmental damage, whereas the government of country 2 takes care profit of the firm as well as the employment and environment. Comparing z N 1 without FDI to the one in the presence of FDI, we can state that the non-cooperative environmental standard with FDI approaches to the cooperative solution. 4.2 Cooperative equilibrium Totally differentiating W, 3βdW=(A 1 +A 3 ) dz 1 +(A 2 +A 4 ) dz 2. (24) Setting the coefficients of dz i equal to zero, and solving simultaneously for z i, we find the cooperative equilibrium, z1= c μc-φ(2βx 1+βx 2 ), (25) μφ 108

Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment z c 2= μc-φβx 1-2βx 2 ( φ-μ) μφ. (26) Comparing the standards between country with FDI and country without FDI, we can obtain following proposition. Proposition 4. Suppose that the FDI only takes place in country 1. Under the cooperative equilibrium, the country 1 applies more restrictive environmental standard than the other country. Proof. z c 1-z c 2=- φω-μc 2φ(3φ-2μ ) < 0 When firm in the country 1 operates through FDI, the environmental standards in cooperative solution differ whereas we have symmetric solution without FDI in the former section. The difference of environmental standards stems from the presence of the FDI. After the foreign multinationals built a production plant in country 1, the substantial fixed cost for investment are already sunk. So the country 1 hosting the FDI can set the environmental standards tougher than country 2. 5 Concluding We have examined the strategic aspects of environmental standards in third-market model. From the common wisdom in the literature of strategic trade policies, countries can subsidize the firm to extract the rival s profit. This is true to the strategic environmental policies. When countries set their environmental standards non-cooperatively, each country sets relatively laxer level of standard rather than the cooperative optimal. In this paper we introduce the foreign direct investment in the country 1. We obtain the result that the presence of the FDI causes country to set more tougher regulation. One thing should be noted that the foreign direct investment in out model is already sunk, hence, the foreign multinational can not relocate the plant to other country. This is a crucial assumption, however, our purpose is to investigate the effect of presence of the FDI on the environmental policies. The internalization of the FDI is interesting question, however, that is beyond the scope of this paper. The further extension with internalization of FDI and political processes in more general settings are analysed in Ishikawa and Kuroda [2004]. References BARRETT, S. (1994): Strategic environment policy and international trade, Journal of Public Economics, 54, 325 338. BRANDER, J. A., and B. J. SPENCER (1987): Foreign direct investment with unemployment and endgeneous taxes and tariffs, Journal of International Economics, 22, 257 79. 109

名古屋学院大学論集 ISHIKAWA, J., and T. KURODA (2004): Firms vs. Environmentalists: Endogenous trade and environmental policies under foreign direct investment, mimeograph. KAYALICA, O. M., and S. LAHIRI (2000): Strategic environmental policies in the presence of Foreign Direct Investment, mimeograph. MARKUSEN, J. R., E. R. MOREY, and N. OLEWILER (1993): Environmental policy when market structure and plant locations are endogenous, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 24, 69 86. (1995): Competition in regional environmental policies when plant locations are endogenous, Journal of Public Economics, 56, 55 77. 110