A Binomial Model of Asset and Option Pricing with Heterogen

Similar documents
A Binomial Model of Asset and Option Pricing with Heterogeneous Beliefs

BOUNDEDLY RATIONAL EQUILIBRIUM AND RISK PREMIUM

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

AGGREGATION OF HETEROGENEOUS BELIEFS AND ASSET PRICING: A MEAN-VARIANCE ANALYSIS

Recent Developments in Asset Pricing with Heterogeneous Beliefs and Adaptive Behaviour of Financial Markets

Option Pricing Models for European Options

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Aggregation of Heterogeneous Beliefs and Asset Pricing Theory: A Mean-Variance Analysis

The Black-Scholes Model

Bank Capital Requirements: A Quantitative Analysis

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

M.I.T Fall Practice Problems

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

The Black-Scholes Model

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

θ(t ) = T f(0, T ) + σ2 T

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Arbitrageurs, bubbles and credit conditions

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Path Dependent British Options

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

1. 2 marks each True/False: briefly explain (no formal proofs/derivations are required for full mark).

Counterparty Credit Risk Simulation

FINANCE 2011 TITLE: RISK AND SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT GROUP WORKING PAPER SERIES

1 Interest Based Instruments

The British Russian Option

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Hedging under Arbitrage

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Credit Risk Modelling: A Primer. By: A V Vedpuriswar

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

Path-dependent inefficient strategies and how to make them efficient.

Binomial Trees. Liuren Wu. Options Markets. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu (Baruch ) Binomial Trees Options Markets 1 / 22

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

Monte Carlo Simulations

Fixed-Income Options

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

Variable Annuities with Lifelong Guaranteed Withdrawal Benefits

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

A Production-Based Model for the Term Structure

Managing Systematic Mortality Risk in Life Annuities: An Application of Longevity Derivatives

Equity Market and Credit Cycle

25857 Interest Rate Modelling

Portability, salary and asset price risk: a continuous-time expected utility comparison of DB and DC pension plans

Vayanos and Vila, A Preferred-Habitat Model of the Term Stru. the Term Structure of Interest Rates

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Finance: A Quantitative Introduction Chapter 8 Option Pricing in Continuous Time

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

ASSET PRICING AND WEALTH DYNAMICS AN ADAPTIVE MODEL WITH HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS

On modelling of electricity spot price

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell Midterm 2014

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Quasi-Convex Stochastic Dynamic Programming

25. Interest rates models. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, References for this Lecture:

CHAPTER 2: STANDARD PRICING RESULTS UNDER DETERMINISTIC AND STOCHASTIC INTEREST RATES

Economics 483. Midterm Exam. 1. Consider the following monthly data for Microsoft stock over the period December 1995 through December 1996:

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

Disasters Implied by Equity Index Options

The Multistep Binomial Model

Jaime Frade Dr. Niu Interest rate modeling

Financial Derivatives Section 5

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Conditional Density Method in the Computation of the Delta with Application to Power Market

Dynamic Hedging and PDE Valuation

Credit Risk : Firm Value Model

Homework Assignments

Foreign Exchange Derivative Pricing with Stochastic Correlation

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Risk Neutral Valuation

Term Structure Lattice Models

(atm) Option (time) value by discounted risk-neutral expected value

Basic Concepts and Examples in Finance

PhD Qualifier Examination

Rohini Kumar. Statistics and Applied Probability, UCSB (Joint work with J. Feng and J.-P. Fouque)

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

TEST OF BOUNDED LOG-NORMAL PROCESS FOR OPTIONS PRICING

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Carnegie Mellon University Graduate School of Industrial Administration

Option-based tests of interest rate diffusion functions

Transcription:

A Binomial Model of Asset and Option Pricing with Heterogeneous Beliefs School of Finance and Economics, UTS 15th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance 15-17 July 2009 Sydney

Basic idea and motivation Recent literatures on behavior finance (Thaler (2002), Shefrin (2005)), Heterogeneous agent models (Hommes (2006), LeBaron (2006) and Chiarella, Dieci and He (2008) and asset pricing under heterogeneous beliefs (Abel (1989, 2002), Jouni and Napp (2006,2007), David (2008)) have shown that investors behavioral biases and heterogeneous beliefs have significant impact on equilibrium asset prices. On the other hand, evolutionary finance (Kogan etal (2008) and Blume and Easly (2006)) literature found that under the assumption of log-utility in a complete market, heterogeneity in investors beliefs cannot persist, irrational investors will be driven out of the market after a long horizon.

Using a rather simple binomial model, this paper examines the impact of heterogeneity on asset and option prices. Investors have heterogeneous beliefs regarding the probability and future returns in each state of the economy. We construct a consensus belief from the subjective beliefs to characterize market equilibrium. We show that if the consensus belief prevails as the objective belief, then investors wealth share process are all martingale. Also heterogeneity can persist and have interesting effect on investors wealth share processes, asset prices, equilibrium risk-free and option prices.

(H1) Assume U(x) = ln(x). (H2) Assume that stock price follow a multi-period Cox-Ross-Rubinstein model. This means, given information at time t, the cum-price of the risky asset at time t + 1 has the following probability distribution, { S(t) u(t, t + 1), p(t, t + 1); S(t + 1) = S(t) d(t, t + 1), 1 p(t, t + 1). with d(t, t + 1) < R f (t) < u(t, t + 1) where R f (t) = 1 + r f (t) is the return of the riskless asset over the period [t, t + 1]. (H3) Assume that I investors have their own subjective beliefs of the probability and rate of return at each state. Let p i (t) = E i t(p(t, t + 1), u i (t) = E i t(u(t, t + 1)) and d i (t) = E i t(d(t, t + 1)) denote investor i s belief of p(t, t + 1), u(t, t + 1) and d(t, t + 1), respectively. B i (t) := (p i (t), u i (t), d i (t)) denotes investor i s set of subjective belief of S(t + 1) at time t.

Portfolio Strategies Lemma Let ū i = u(t) R f (t) and d i = d(t) R f (t) be the excess rate of return in the up and down states, respectively over the period [t, t + 1] under investor i s perspective. The optimal proportion of wealth of investor i invested in the risky asset over the period [t, t + 1] is given by ū i p i + ˆω i = R d i (1 p i ) f ū i d i

Consensus belief and Market equilibrium Definition A belief B m (t) = (p m (t), u m (t), d m (t)), defined by the probability and return of the risky asset associated with the up and down state respectively, is called a consensus belief at time t if the market equilibrium price for the risky asset and risk free rate under the heterogeneous beliefs are also those under the homogeneous belief B m (t).

Proposition (i) Let w i (t) = W i (t) W m (t) denote investor i share of the market at time t. The consensus belief at time t, B m (t), is given by p m = i w i p i, u m = ū m + R f, d m = d m + R f where ( I ū m = i=1 ( I d m = i=1 w i w i ) 1 1 p i ū 1 i, 1 p m p i p m ) 1 d 1 i

(ii) The equilibrium risk free rate is given by 1 = 1 p m + p [ m = E m t R f d m u m where R(t + 1) = S(t + 1)/S(t). 1 R(t + 1) (iii) The individual and market consensus belief of the state prices or the risk neutral probabilities of the up and down state at time t are given by q i,u (t) = d i ū i d i, q i,d (t) = ūi ū i d i, i = 1, 2,, I, m. ],

(iv) In equilibrium, the stock price at time t is given by S(t) = EQ i t (S(t + 1)) R f = Ei t(z S(t + 1)) R f, i = 1, 2,, I, m where Z = { qu (t) p, p; 1 p q d (t) 1 p, is the Randon-Nikodym derivative that change the probability measure from i to Q i, and often referred to as the pricing kernel in the asset pricing literatures.

Example 1 Consider a benchmark belief B o (t) = (p o (t), u o (t), d o (t)), and assume that investors subjective beliefs diverge from the benchmark belief. We do this by imposing a Mean Preserved Spread (MPS) on investors beliefs. Let investor i s belief be given by B i (t) = (u o (t) + ɛ iu, d o (t) + ɛ id ) iid iid where ɛ iu Unif ( θu, θ u ), similarly ɛ id Unif ( θd, θ d ). Therefore investors divergence of opinion regarding the stock returns in both up and down states are i.i.d. We let number of investors I = 10 and run 5000 simulations for each pair of (θ u, θ d ). Furthermore, we assume investors agree on the probability, hence p i = p o for all i.

Impact of heterogeneity on consensus belief θ u [0.01, 0.2], θ d = 0 θ u = 0, θ d [0.01, 0.1] θ u [0.01, 0.2], θ d = 0.1

Equilibrium risk-free rate, E(r f ) (black), σ(r f ) (red) θ u [0.01, 0.2], θ d = 0 θ u = 0, θ d [0.01, 0.1] θ u [0.01, 0.2], θ d = 0.1

Implicatons Assume investors wealth are evenly distributed, then the market as a consensus investor believes that divergence of opinion regarding future asset return in the upstate (downstate) is negatively (positively) related to expected future stock return and the equilibrium risk-free rate. Higher divergence of opinions leads to higher volatility for both the expected future asset return and the equilibrium risk-free rate.

50 25 40 30 20 10 30 20 10 20 15 10 5 1.05 1.06 1.07 1.08 1.09 1.1 1.04 1.06 1.08 1.1 1 1.025 1.05 1.075 1.1 1.125 (θ u, θ d ) = (0.01, 0.1) (θ u, θ d ) = (0.1, 0.1) (θ u, θ d ) = (0.2, 0.1) Figure: Impact of divergence of opinion on the distribution of expected future stock return under the market consensus belief

Dynamic Impact of Heterogeneous beliefs Proposition Under the market consensus belief B m (p m (t), u m (t), d m (t)), the wealth share of every investor i who survives up to time t, that is w i (t) > 0, [ ] E m wi (t + 1) t = 1 w i (t)

Proposition Under investor i s subjective belief B i (p i (t), u i (t), d i (t)), investor i survives at time t + 1 and [ ] E i wi (t + 1) t 1. w i (t) Equality will hold if and only if B i (t) = B m (t).

A two-parameter model We assume that each investor i believes that the asset price dynamics will conform to the Black-Sholes model in continuous-time, however they have different beliefs about the drift (µ i ) and volatility parameter (σ i ). Motivation is to allow us to price options and bonds and compare with benchmark results. We assume that the beliefs B i (µ i, σ i ) are formed in the follow way, u i = exp(σ i t), di = 1/u i, and p i = exp(µ i t) d i u i d i where t is the time increment between any two successive periods. It is well known that this discrete-time model approaches the following continuous-time model when t 0, ds(t)/s(t) = µ i dt + σ i dw (t)

Example 2 Consider 2 investors who have the same belief about the instantaneous expected return for the risky asset, i.e µ 1 = µ 2 = µ o. However, they have different levels of confidence, let σ 1 = σ o (1 δ) and σ 2 = σ o (1 + δ), where δ > 0. Obviously, investor 1 is more confident about his/her estimate of instantaneous expected return than investor 2. We let T = 1, t = 1/250, µ o = 0.07, σ o = 0.1654, δ = 0.5, w 1 (0) = w 2 (0) = 0.5 and investigate the distribution and first 4 moments of wealth share of investor 1 w 1 (T ), log asset prices ln(s(t )) and risk-free rate r f (T ).

800 1000 800 600 800 600 400 400 600 400 200 200 200 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6-0.4-0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.052 0.054 0.056 0.058 0.06 w 1 (T ) ln(s(t )) r f (T ) Mean Std Dev Skewness Kurtosis w 1 (T ) 0.4914 0.0506-0.3790 3.1612 (δ = 0) 0.5 0 0 0 ln(s(t )) 0.0437 0.1244-0.1558 2.9639 (δ = 0) 0.0563 0.1654 0 3 r f (T ) 0.0575 0.0011-0.9621 4.6820 (δ = 0) 0.0575 0 0 0

Option prices under Heterogeneous beliefs Consider any self-financing portfolio which invests ω(t) in the risky asset and (1 ω(t)) in the risk-free asset at time t, then the expected value (under the consensus belief of the portfolio at time t + 1, H(t + 1) when benchmarked again the risky asset is E m t ( H(t + 1) S(t + 1) = ω(t) + (1 ω(t))e m t ) ( ) H(t)ω(t)R(t + 1) + H(t)(1 = E m ω(t))rf (t + 1) t S(t + 1) ( ) H(t)Rf (t + 1) = H(t) S(t)R(t + 1) S(t) that is the value of any contingent claim with a payoff function V (.,.) is given by V (S(t), t) = S(t) E m t (V (S(T ), T )/S(T )).

Zero-coupon bond prices and Call option prices Option Prices 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 Bond 1.00 Prices 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4 Call option prices Strike 0.99 0.98 0.97 0.96 50 100 150 200 250 Days to Maturity Figure: Zero-coupon bond prices Impact of heterogeneity on bond and option prices. Dark line represent the bond and call option prices under the consensus belief when investors have different level of confidence as in Example 2. Light line represent the bond and call option under the homogeneous benchmark belief which is also the average belief.

Market expects a lower (higher) future return and equilibrium risk-free rate when investor s opinions diverge more regarding future stock return for the upstate than for the downstate. Dynamically, under the market consensus beliefs, every investor s wealth share process is a martingale. Therefore, in the long-run each investor s wealth share is expected to remain the same, hence heterogeneity in the market will be persistent.

In a modified version of the model, we characterize investors by their beliefs of the instantaneous expected return and volatility of the risky asset. When investors have common beliefs regarding the expected return, the distribution of future wealth is negatively skewed for the more confident investor. The distribution for future risk-free rate is also heavily skewed to the left. Heterogeneity causes the zero-coupon bond and call option prices to deviate from the homogeneous benchmark values.