GENDER EQUITY IN THE TAX SYSTEM FOR FISCAL SUSTAINABILITY

Similar documents
THE CENTRAL ROLE OF A WELL-DESIGNED INCOME TAX IN THE MODERN ECONOMY

TAX REFORM, DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE AND RISING INEQUALITY

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Gender equity in the tax-transfer system for fiscal sustainability 1

Centre for Economic Policy Research

Gender, Time Use and Public Policy over the Life Cycle

DISCUSSION PAPERS. Reforming the Australian Tax Transfer System

Efficiency of the Tax System: a marginal excess burden analysis

Melbourne Economic Forum, 13 April Lower Personal Income Tax Rates. John Freebairn. University of Melbourne

Personal Income Tax Cuts and the new Child Care Subsidy: Do They Address High Effective Marginal Tax Rates on Women s Work?

Developments in the level and distribution of retirement savings

Index. Note: Page numbers in italics indicate information contained in tables, graphics or other illustrative material.

Superannuation account balances by age and gender

The principles of GIA and their application to an analysis of Australia s retirement incomes and savings policies

AIST. 22 October Sex Discrimination Commissioner Australian Human Rights Commission Level 3, 175 Pitt St SYDNEY NSW 200. Dear Ms Broderick,

Impact of removing stamp duties on insurance. Insurance Council of Australia

A gender impact assessment of Australia s retirement income policy

BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE INEQUALITY IN LATER LIFE. The superannuation effect. Helen Hodgson, Alan Tapper and Ha Nguyen

Income Inequality and Tax-Transfer Policy: Trends and Questions

DRAFT. A microsimulation analysis of public and private policies aimed at increasing the age of retirement 1. April Jeff Carr and André Léonard

FACT SHEET. Guaranteeing Women s Super How to Close the Gender Gap in Superannuation. Overview. Tristan Durie & Edward Cavanough

Economic Standard of Living

POVERTY IN AUSTRALIA: NEW ESTIMATES AND RECENT TRENDS RESEARCH METHODOLOGY FOR THE 2016 REPORT

Baby Boomers and Housing Markets. Presentation by Clare Wall, SGS Associate 7 th National Housing Conference October 2012

Equity and superannuation the real issues

REFORM OF INCOME TAX IN AUSTRALIA: A LONG-TERM AGENDA

Appendix 7: Deadweight economic loss caused by raising revenue for projects and programs

WOMEN S ECONOMIC SECURITY IN RETIREMENT

The labor market in Australia,

AIST-Mercer Super Tracker. Presenter: Dr David Knox, Mercer Chair: Karen Volpato, AIST

Superannuation System

Equity and superannuation

Economic Standard of Living

The Melbourne Institute Report on the 2004 Federal Budget Hielke Buddelmeyer, Peter Dawkins, and Guyonne Kalb

Improving the Efficiency of the Australian Tax System: a model-based analysis

Are retirement savings on track?

A picture of gender inequality in. Australia and the UK. Dr M.Claire Dale Research Fellow

The theory of taxation/3 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.15 Rosen) Desirable characteristics of tax systems (optimal taxation)

Industrial Relations Legislation Policy Background Paper

Fair Work Commission Fair Work Act Annual Wage Review Submission in Reply by the Australian Catholic Council for Employment Relations

Framing public policy from an intrahousehold gendered perspective. The cases of the UK, Australia and Germany since the mid-nineties.

Mythbusters. Myths that a 12 per cent SG is not needed. May Ross Clare, Director of Research ASFA Research and Resource Centre

Workforce participation of mature aged women

Introducing the Grattan Retirement Incomes Model (GRIM)

Economic standard of living

The New Zealand tax system and how it compares internationally

The role of public pensions and reform options

The Gender Earnings Gap: Evidence from the UK

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009

Modelling of the Federal Budget Personal Income Tax Measures

Submission to the Senate Education, Employment and Workplace Relations References Committee Inquiry into the Adequacy of the Allowance Payment System

An Education Bond Co-contribution Scheme:

Age Discrimination in Superannuation. Submission to. The Hon Susan Ryan AO Age Discrimination Commissioner

The need to look deeper on the gender gap

JEL Codes: C68, D43, H21. Keywords: CGE, computable general equilibrium, oligopoly, Cournot Nash, tax efficiency, Australia

Submission to Senate Standing Committees on Economics Inquiry into Economic Security for Women in Retirement

Women and top incomes in Australia 1

Economic Standard of Living

Economic Standard of Living

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

Chapter 1: Introduction (read on your own) Chapter 1 Appendix: Regression Analysis (read on your own)

Labour Market Challenges: Turkey

SECURING RETIREMENT INCOMES. TAX & SUPERANNUATION: THE SHORTCOMINGS OF the SUPERANNUATION TAXATION EXPENDITURES

Supporting carers to work

18. Changes in Inequality in Australia and the Redistributional Impacts of Taxes and Government Benefits

ECONOMIC SURVEY OF NEW ZEALAND 2007: TWO BROAD APPROACHES FOR TAX REFORM

POLICY INSIGHT. Inequality The hidden headwind for economic growth. How inequality slows growth

INCOME TAXES. Outline: Chapter 13 INCOME TAXES. 5. Market Analysis of Taxation on Interest and Investment Income

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

INQUIRY INTO MINERAL RESOURCE RENT TAX BILL 2011 AND RELATED BILLS

The Effects of Income Support Settings on Incentives to Work. Nicolas Hérault, Guyonne Kalb and Justin van de Ven

Piecewise Linear Taxation and Top Incomes

Minimum Wage: Maximum Impact. Alan Manning London School of Economics

Inside the black box of the family

Women and the Economy 2010: 25 Years of Progress But Challenges Remain

Public Good Provision Rules and Income Distribution: Some General Equilibrium Calculations

The Elasticity of Taxable Income in New Zealand

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION IN SCOTLAND 2015

Paper for New Agenda for Prosperity, the University of Melbourne, 28 March 2008 Reforming State Taxes John Freebairn The University of Melbourne

The Impact of Taxation and Public Expenditure on Income Distribution in Indonesia

Poverty and Income Inequality in Scotland: 2013/14 A National Statistics publication for Scotland

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

The Effects of Changes in Family Composition and Employment Patterns on the Distribution of Income in Australia: 1982 to

CHAPTER 4. EXPANDING EMPLOYMENT THE LABOR MARKET REFORM AGENDA

Labour Market Responses to the Abolition of Compulsory Superannuation

Effects of the Australian New Tax System on Government Expenditure; With and without Accounting for Behavioural Changes

REGULATORY IMPACT STATEMENT FOR MINIMUM WAGE REVIEW 2012

The Elasticity of Taxable Income in New Zealand

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Extending the Aaron Condition for Alternative Pay-As-You-Go Pension Systems Miriam Steurer

Decomposing the marginal excess burden of the GST

Long-Term Fiscal External Panel

The Effects of Ageing on the Financing of Social Health Provision. Chris Heady 26 th March 2013

The evolving retirement landscape

Australian Tax Reform

Economic influences on the Australian mortgage market

Exploring the Personal Income Tax System

Indicators for the 2nd cycle of review and appraisal of RIS/MIPAA (A suggestion from MA:IMI) European Centre Vienna

2005 Survey of Owners of Non-Qualified Annuity Contracts

High income earners the big winners from scrapping 37% tax bracket

Transcription:

GENDER EQUITY IN THE TAX SYSTEM FOR FISCAL SUSTAINABILITY Workshop: Gender Equity in Australia s Tax and Transfer System 4-5 November 2015 Patricia Apps University of Sydney Law School and IZA

Introduction Two of the most fundamental changes in the Australian economy since the middle of the 20 th century are: the decline in the TFR, from around 3.5 in 1960 s to 1.8 today a dramatic rise in the female labour force participation rate. OECD (2014) stats for 2012: female rate = 70.5%; male rate = 82.2%. A gap of less than 12 percentage points. However, the female participation rate is misleading. The 12 percentage point gap conceals a far wider gender gap in labour supply, in the order of 40 to 50 per cent during the prime working age years due to the high proportion of women in part-time work.

Introduction Policy challenge: A large fall in a country s TFR creates the potential for a significant social dividend due to the high parental time costs of a child, mostly of the mother. The challenge is to put in place a policy setting that leads to productivity gains from the reallocation of female time from the home to the market. With the optimal policy setting we would expect to see an expansion of the tax base that provided additional revenue for investments in child care, education, health care and infrastructure. This paper discusses tax policies that work against this outcome.

Introduction Analysis focuses on the negative incentive effects of gender/second earner discrimination in three areas of tax policy: the Family income tax system GST tax advantaged superannuation We begin with an analysis of time use and expenditure data to show: the large and persistent life cycle gender gap in labour supply the negative impact on household private income, saving and the tax base.

Life cycle time use Data: ABS 2005-06 Time Use Survey and full sample of couples drawn from the 2009-10 Household Expenditure Survey (5252 records). Life cycle is defined not on the age of head of household as in the economics literature, but on presence and age of children. Five phases: Pre-children At least one child of preschool age is present Children are of school age or older but still dependent Parents are of working age but with no dependent children at home Retirement.

Life cycle time use: ABS data 5 phases: 1 pre children almost identical female and male market hours 2 at least one child 0to preschool age dramatic fall in female market hours 3 children of school age or older and still dependent 4 post child phase (under 60) 5 retirement (60+) Market hours pa 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 Domestic and child care hours pa 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 1 2 3 4 5 Life cycle phase 1 2 3 4 5 Life cycle phase Male labour supply Female labour supply Male dom+ccare hrs Male domestic hrs Female dom+ccare hrs Female domestic hrs Gender gap persists from phase 2 to phase 4 with no children at home. Literature attributes persistence to loss of human capital.

Gender gap in labour supply The gender gap in labour supply in phase 2 reflects the additional work choice created by the arrival of the first child. One parent, typically the mother on a lower wage, can work at home providing child care and domestic services as an alternative to working in the market and buying in care and related services. Choice will depend on the net-of-tax gender pay gap and access to child care at an affordable price and acceptable quality. Life cycle profiles of income, saving and taxes indicate the potential losses from tax policies that widen the net-of-tax gender pay gap.

Life cycle income, saving and taxes Household private income, saving and taxes track female earnings which, in turn, track female labour supply. Phase Household income* Female earnings* Saving* H income tax- (FTB+C**) 1 116141 47502 19760 19410 2 83824 6240 5824 11411 3 110244 30212 9776 19387 4 94744 26208 14040 17113 5 6980 0 1404 4179 * Median **C = CCB + CCTR Profiles conceal high degree of heterogeneity within phases 2 to 4.

Heterogeneity female labour supply Phases 2 to 4 are split into two types according to median second hours. Type H1 : households with second hours below the median Type H2 : households with second hours at or above the median Type Phase Male hours Female hours Female income H inc. tax- (FTB+C**) # Kids 2 2058 11 2170 7555 2.08 H1 3 2105 438 16375 17335 1.90 4 1743 454 14894 14180-2 2116 1410 42764 17674 1.85 H2 3 2080 1949 52833 24776 1.72 4 1983 1830 51120 23672 **C = CCB + CCTR Female earnings and taxes track female hours within each phase.

Family income tax system Transformation of Australia s income tax system since 1980s. 1980s: rate scale of the Personal Income Tax (PIT) was highly progressive and family payments were universal. The system ranked well in terms of gender equity and female labour supply incentives. During the Howard years : the progressivity of the rate scale declined dramatically despite rising inequality. Gave massive tax cuts to top incomes (Apps, 2015). individual as the unit of taxation for families was replaced by a system of quasi-joint taxation by withdrawing family payments on jointincome. Many partnered mothers as second earners face marginal tax rates that are well above the top rate on personal income. We now have a large net-of-tax gender pay gap (Apps, 2010).

Joint taxation Progressive joint taxation is recognised to discriminate against the second earner, by imposing a higher MTR on her income. - supported by the fallacy that household income is a reliable indicator of the living standards of couples. Household income omits the contribution of a partner specialising in child care and work at home, effectively setting its value to zero. Women at home are made invisible. Joint income can seriously misrepresent living standards due to the high degree of heterogeneity in second earner labour supply and the relatively flat profile of the primary wage distribution until the top percentiles. Data show that when the second earner of a low wage family in quintile 1 of household income goes out to work, the family can be reranked to quintile 4 and misrepresented as just as well-off as a single-earner family on twice the wage working half the hours.

Quasi joint family taxation Howard s system of quasi-joint taxation supported by targeting fallacy argument that withdrawing family payments as income rises achieves a cost /revenue saving by reducing middle class welfare. Example: Re:think: Reducing effective tax rates is not straightforward because reducing the rate at which payments are withdrawn, or removing them altogether, would extend assistance to higher income levels. View contradicts one of the most important lessons of modern tax theory: any tax system that gives a payment and then withdraws it as income rises is equivalent to one with the same universal payment and a new structure of MTRs and lump sums. The relevant basis for evaluating the cost of a tax system is not the universality of the payment, but the value of the payment and the incentive effects of the MTR structure.

Quasi joint family taxation By targeting family payments the Howard system replaced the progressive rate scale of the PIT with an inverted U-shaped scale. MTRs on partnered mothers rose sharply while the top PIT rate fell. The additional revenue from the growth in the tax base with the rise in female participation since the 1960s offered a source of funding for productivity-improving investment in a public child care system. Instead the revenue funded cuts in top tax rates with little to no gain. Male wage elasticity tends to zero towards the top percentiles. High tax rates on second earners under joint taxation have long been rejected in the literature due to evidence of strong disincentive effects on female labour supply.

Saving tracks 2 nd hours Using household income as a measure of living standards also leads to a serious misreading of the data on household saving. Table: phases 2 to 4 are split into household types, H1 and H2, according to median second hours within each primary income quintile. Primary income quintiles 34265 54701 71982 96648 201855 H1: 2 nd earnings $pa 330 9745 9494 16794 12835 Saving $pa -8227 331 4095 14268 54642 H2: 2nd earnings $pa 24425 37410 43001 60451 67281 Saving $pa 297 9075 16167 30634 76973 Table reports regression estimates of household saving by primary income that control for demographics within each quintile. By switching from H1 to H2, saving in q2 to q4 rises above that of H1 in q5.

GST assumption 1 Standard argument for shifting from income to consumption taxation (see Henry Review + recent Treasury papers) is based on two mistaken assumptions. Assumption 1: The optimal tax rate on capital income is zero. (Note that under a GST capital income is tax exempt.) Contradicts the central tenet of modern tax theory, that the optimal tax rate on a given source of income, whether labour or capital, can only be determined on the basis of empirical evidence on distributional outcomes and behavioral effects because we are in a second best setting. With a shift in the tax burden from capital to labour, female hours and, in turn, household saving can be expected to fall as indicated above.

GST assumption 2 Assumption 2: A consumption tax is equivalent to a tax on earnings. We label this the equivalence fallacy. The proposition draws on a model of intertemporal choice that assumes: 1. A perfect capital market 2. All households are single-person 3. Consumption and leisure are weakly separable All three reflect very poor powers of observation: 1. Life cycle profiles: borrowing rate > lending rate (Apps & Rees, 2010) 2. Most adults live in couple households and most have two earners 3. Consumption (e.g. bought-in child care) and leisure (e.g. home child care) tend to be substitutes

Efficiency merits an income tax A well-designed labour income tax will always be superior to a consumption tax because it is a less constrained policy instrument. Individual earnings can be observed and taxed progressively, allowing a lower tax rate on the 2 nd earner, typically the female partner with the more responsive labour supply and higher saving rate at a given wage. Individual consumptions cannot be observed. We can never observe whose consumption has been reduced to fund household saving A broad based consumption tax is inevitably a flat rate joint tax.

GST vs income tax couples Additional tax burden under a 5 percentage point rise in GST rate and under an increment in all income tax rates that raises same revenue. Primary income deciles Additional tax, dollars/1000 pa 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 5% GST RISE INCOME TAX RISE Much of the GST revenue will be spent on compensation targeted on the basis of joint income MTRs on female labour will rise. A rise in the GST will hit the middle and women (Apps, 2013).

GST fictional efficiency claims RE:think Draws on Treasury Working Paper (TWP), Cao et al. (2015). TWP claims that GST is more efficient than a flat rate earnings tax using a computable general equilibrium model (CGE) Model is entirely fictional. Household is represented as a single person with a single uncompensated elasticity of labour supply of 0.15 Whose labour supply elasticity? Whose saving elasticity? Makes no sense to model the household as single person. Similar findings in Treasury funded KPMG (2010, 2011) studies. Why is Treasury presenting fictional results for a GST?

Superannuation defined contribution Australia s defined contribution superannuation system, with employer contributions and entity earnings taxed at 15%, has also directed billions of dollars of tax cuts towards the top percentiles of income. According to modern public economic theory, the key objective of a retirement incomes policy is the provision of insurance against longevity and aggregate (or social) risk. A defined contribution superannuation system fails on both counts. The system is essentially a tax advantaged saving scheme that is now justified in terms of lowering taxes on capital income (Henry Review). The greatest gains go to those with the most income to save.

Super: gains go mostly to high income primary earners With the concentration of women in lower paid jobs, women as a group cannot gain. The system widens the overall net-of-tax gender pay gap. Primary income deciles Super balances, dollars/1000 pa 0 50 100 150 200 250 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Second/female Primary Gender equity requires a public sector retirement income insurance policy.

Demographic change Tax advantaged saving is not a solution to the perceived problem of fiscal sustainability with demographic change. The solution lies in raising female labour supply and productivity. We require tax and expenditure policies that rank well in terms of gender equity and labour supply incentive effects. Two key policy directions: A return to a highly progressive income tax with universal family payments Incremental investment in a learning focused public child care system Nothing can be gained by raising the GST and lowing taxes on capital income.

References Apps, P (2015), Closing the Gender Gap in Labour Supply, in Australia s Future Workforce?, CEDA, Ch 3.2, 167-178. Apps, P (2015), The central role of a well-designed income tax in the modern economy, forthcoming, Australian Tax Forum. Apps, P (2010), Why the Henry Review Fails on Family Tax Reform, in Australia s Future Tax System: The Prospects after Henry, C Evans, R Krever and P Mellor (eds), Thomson Reuter Australia Ltd, Ch 5, 103-127. Apps, P and R Rees (2013), Raise Top Tax Rates, Not the GST, Australian Tax Forum, 28, 679-693. Apps, P and R Rees (2010) Family Labour Supply, Taxation and Saving in an Imperfect Capital Market, Review of Economics of the Household, 8, 297-323. Cao, L, A Hosking, M Kouparitsas, D Mullaly, X Rimmer, Q Shi, W Stark and S Wende (2015), Understanding the Economy-Wide Efficiency and Incidence of Major Australian Taxes, Treasury WP 2015-01, Australian Government. KPMG (2011), Economic Analysis of the Impact of Using GST to Reform Taxes, A report for CPA Australia. KPMG (2010), GCE Analysis of the Current Australian Tax System, Department of Treasury, Canberra. OECD (2014), Achieving Stronger Growth by Promoting a More Gender Balanced Economy, Report prepared for the G20 Labour and Employment Ministerial Meeting, Melbourne, 10-11 Sept.