A Comparison of Methods for Portfolio Optimization

Similar documents
FINC3017: Investment and Portfolio Management

Markowitz portfolio theory

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Financial Analysis The Price of Risk. Skema Business School. Portfolio Management 1.

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics. The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns

Mean-Variance Analysis

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

International Finance. Estimation Error. Campbell R. Harvey Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc.

RiskTorrent: Using Portfolio Optimisation for Media Streaming

A Simple Utility Approach to Private Equity Sales

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

KELLY CAPITAL GROWTH

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

CSCI 1951-G Optimization Methods in Finance Part 07: Portfolio Optimization

Optimal Portfolio Selection

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Optimization of a Real Estate Portfolio with Contingent Portfolio Programming

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

VOLATILITY EFFECTS AND VIRTUAL ASSETS: HOW TO PRICE AND HEDGE AN ENERGY PORTFOLIO

(IIEC 2018) TEHRAN, IRAN. Robust portfolio optimization based on minimax regret approach in Tehran stock exchange market

Portfolio Management

23.1. Assumptions of Capital Market Theory

Market Risk Analysis Volume I

8 th International Scientific Conference

Equation Chapter 1 Section 1 A Primer on Quantitative Risk Measures

Comparison of Static and Dynamic Asset Allocation Models

Applications of Linear Programming

Some useful optimization problems in portfolio theory

CHAPTER III RISK MANAGEMENT

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Motif Capital Horizon Models: A robust asset allocation framework

Modern Portfolio Theory -Markowitz Model

MS&E 348 Winter 2011 BOND PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT: INCORPORATING CORPORATE BOND DEFAULT

Equilibrium Asset Returns

Value-at-Risk Based Portfolio Management in Electric Power Sector

Asset Selection Model Based on the VaR Adjusted High-Frequency Sharp Index

An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

NATIONWIDE ASSET ALLOCATION INVESTMENT PROCESS

Multi-Period Stochastic Programming Models for Dynamic Asset Allocation

( 0) ,...,S N ,S 2 ( 0)... S N S 2. N and a portfolio is created that way, the value of the portfolio at time 0 is: (0) N S N ( 1, ) +...

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Markowitz portfolio theory. May 4, 2017

A Study on Optimal Limit Order Strategy using Multi-Period Stochastic Programming considering Nonexecution Risk

The Duration Derby: A Comparison of Duration Based Strategies in Asset Liability Management

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Does Portfolio Theory Work During Financial Crises?

Continuous-Time Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Vanguard Global Capital Markets Model

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

EE365: Risk Averse Control

Mean-Variance Analysis

Maximization of utility and portfolio selection models

Mean Variance Portfolio Theory

Diversification. Chris Gan; For educational use only

Chapter 8: CAPM. 1. Single Index Model. 2. Adding a Riskless Asset. 3. The Capital Market Line 4. CAPM. 5. The One-Fund Theorem

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Expected utility theory; Expected Utility Theory; risk aversion and utility functions

Characterization of the Optimum

AGENERATION company s (Genco s) objective, in a competitive

ON SOME ASPECTS OF PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT. Mengrong Kang A THESIS

Applied Macro Finance

Improving equity diversification via industry-wide market segmentation

Models and Decision with Financial Applications UNIT 1: Elements of Decision under Uncertainty

EQUITY RESEARCH AND PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT

Aversion to Risk and Optimal Portfolio Selection in the Mean- Variance Framework

Mean-Variance Portfolio Choice in Excel

A Simple, Adjustably Robust, Dynamic Portfolio Policy under Expected Return Ambiguity

1 The Solow Growth Model

A Simple Approach to CAPM and Option Pricing. Riccardo Cesari and Carlo D Adda (University of Bologna)

Asset-Liability Management

Yale ICF Working Paper No First Draft: February 21, 1992 This Draft: June 29, Safety First Portfolio Insurance

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio

Key investment insights

A Simple Method for Solving Multiperiod Mean-Variance Asset-Liability Management Problem

Robust portfolio optimization using second-order cone programming

Lecture 2: Fundamentals of meanvariance

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Econ 424/CFRM 462 Portfolio Risk Budgeting

FISHER TOTAL FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY INDEX FOR TIME SERIES DATA WITH UNKNOWN PRICES. Thanh Ngo ψ School of Aviation, Massey University, New Zealand

The duration derby : a comparison of duration based strategies in asset liability management

Quantitative Portfolio Theory & Performance Analysis

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Mathematics in Finance

Aversion to Risk and Optimal Portfolio Selection in the Mean- Variance Framework

A Robust Quantitative Framework Can Help Plan Sponsors Manage Pension Risk Through Glide Path Design.

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Dynamic Asset Allocation for Hedging Downside Risk

Running Money. McGraw-Hill Irwin. Professional Portfolio Management. Scott D. Stewart, PhD, CFA. Christopher D. Piros, PhD, CFA

1 Unemployment Insurance

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

35.1 Passive Management Strategy

Transcription:

87 32nd ORSNZ Conference Proceedings A Comparison of Methods for Portfolio Optimization Sonya Rennie Department of Engineering Science University of Auckland New Zealand rennie@es v 1. auckland. ac. nz Abstract Fund managers face the problem of allocating investor s funds to different securities such that the return from the investment is maximized while the risk of the investm ent is kept to a minimum. This is known as the portfolio optim ization problem. The traditional Markowitz model computes an investm ent portfolio th a t maximizes the expected return for a given level of risk. The model assumes th a t the returns from individual securities are independent over time. However, this assum ption is not valid for all securities. Returns from some investm ent securities follow m ean-reverting processes. Presented in this paper are different m ethods for solving the portfolio optim ization problem, with and without serial correlation of returns. 1 S ta tic P ortfolio Selection M odels Portfolio selection involves deciding how best to allocate wealth am ong several risky assets. Static models for portfolio selection restrict the decision m aking process and the future foresight to a single time period. Portfolio revisions can occur as often as required however each revision is made independently of any other revision. Most static portfolio selection models utilize an expected utility approach. The traditional method for portfolio selection, the Markowitz model, is a static model th at uses a quadratic utility function. In practice, most fund m anagers consider a different static model th at maximizes a value-added utility function in term s of a benchmark portfolio. Both methods are described in detail below. 1.1 The M arkowitz M odel Markowitz [5] investigated portfolio selection according to the expected returnsvariance of returns rule. This rule states th at when building a portfolio, one wishes to maximise expected return while minimizing the variance (risk) of return. As a consequence, a diversified portfolio is always preferable to a non-diversified portfolio.

32nd ORSNZ Conference Proceedings 88 The Markowitz model seeks an optimal portfolio th at either minimizes risk for a given level of return, or maximizes expected return for a given level of risk. In the m athem atical development of his model Markowitz assumes th at the returns on each investm ent are static random variables, independent from period to period, and th a t the returns of different securities may be correlated at each tim e step. The Markowitz portfolio selection model can be stated as maximize etx - p xtv x N subject to ~ 1, j =i xj > 0 j = where e is the expected return vector, V is the variance-covariance m atrix for the securities, p is a risk aversion factor, and Xj gives the proportion of funds invested in security j. For any given portfolio an expected return, E = etx, and a variance, V' = Efficiency Frontier x T~Vx, can be calculated. Any portfolio with m inimum V for a given E, or maxim um E for a given V is term ed an efficient portfolio by Markowitz. The set of efficient portfolios make up the efficiency frontier, shown in Figure 1. According to M arkowitz s expected returns-variance of returns rule, an investor would only want to select a portfolio on this efficiency frontier. 1.1.1 M ean-variance and U tility attainable E, V combinations Variance, V Figure 1: Efficiency Frontier. W hittle [9] shows how the mean-variance approach can be viewed as an approxim a tion to a utility maxim ization model. Formally, let r be the vector of (uncertain) future returns for a set of securities. The problem of portfolio optim ization can be thought of as maximizing the utility function f( x ) = E [H (rr x)\ (1) where E is the expectation operator, x is the resulting portfolio and H is a concave function, subject to constraints on the portfolio ( x = 1, z > 0 ). Let the expected value and variance of the portfolio return, r Tx, be denoted by p. and v respectively. If H can be expanded in powers of deviation of r Tx, and assum ing that powers higher than the second are negligible, then f ( x ) = E [H (rr x)) ~ H in ) + \v H " ip ) (2) where the prim e indicates differentiation. Using a Taylor s series expansion and ignoring powers higher than the second, (3)

89 32nd ORSNZ Conference Proceedings If H 1 is m onotone increasing in the effective range of f(x), then the m axim ization of f(x) is equivalent to the maximization of H~1(f(x)) or of /* (x ) = fi- (4) where 6 equals H " (n )/H '(n ). W hen H is exponential 0 is independent of n and expression (4) is a quadratic function of x. Thus the m ean-variance model can be thought of as an approxim ation to the exponential utility function with different levels of absolute risk aversion. 1.1.2 Im plem entation The Markowitz model takes as input the expected returns and variance-covariance of the securities th at will be in the portfolio. The solution given by the Markowitz model will only be as good as the d ata th at are input. There are many ways to estim ate the expected returns and the variance-covariance m atrix of the securities. Some examples are included below: 1. Given a tim e series of past returns for the securities, the variance-covariance m atrix can be estim ated by the sample variances and covariances from a set of observations taken from the tim e series, and the sam ple average return for each security can be used as an estim ate of the expected return for th a t security. 2. M ultivariate regression or time series models can be fitted to a tim e series of past returns. These models can then be used to estim ate future expected returns and the variance-covariance matrix. 3. Various m ethods can be used to transform raw information, such as tips and buy and sell recommendations, into forecasts of expected returns. Refer to Grinold and Kahn [2]. 1.1.3 A ssum ptions and Lim itations The m ajor assum ption made in the derivation of the Markowitz portfolio optim ization model is th at the returns of the securities are independent over tim e. If this assum ption is true then the Markowitz model is statistically correct (see Samuelson [8]). However this assumption is not valid for all securities. R eturns from some investment securities have been shown to follow mean-reverting processes. If returns are serially correlated then the Markowitz model is not optim al. Hakansson [4] proves that when returns are serially correlated only the logarithmic utility function is independent of future returns. Thus with tim e dependent returns, it is not optim al to consider only a one-period horizon using a quadratic utility function. The quadratic utility function of the Markowitz model has also been criticised [3] for the way it implies that risk aversion increases with wealth. The Markowitz model is also limited in the way it uses variance as a measure of investment risk. In the calculation of variance positive and negative deviations contribute equally. This means that over performance relative to a mean is penalised

32nd ORSNZ Conference Proceedings 90 as much as under performance. Because of this the concept of downside risk was developed. The idea of downside risk is th at risk can be measured by the probability of the return falling below a specified level or benchmark. This benchm ark will be different for different investors, and is related to the investor s objectives. 1.2 P ortfolio Selection in Practice In practice, portfolio selection begins with a benchmark portfolio. A benchmark portfolio is used by the trustee of a fund as a way of conveying to a portfolio m anager clear instructions regarding their responsibilities and lim itations. For example, a benchm ark for a New Zealand equity m anager may be the portfolio of equities m aking up the NZSE40 index. The performance of the m anager is then judged relative to the perform ance of the benchmark. There are two styles of portfolio m anagem ent. Passive portfolio management involves trying to replicate the perform ance of the benchm ark. Active portfolio management involves applying analysis and process to try and outperform a benchmark. Assuming the benchm ark is an efficient portfolio, consensus forecasts for risk and return can be calculated. These consensus forecasts will result in an efficiency frontier (refer to Figure 1) that includes the benchmark portfolio. A passive m anager would chose a portfolio on this frontier. Active managem ent starts when the managers forecasts differ from the consensus. In this case the benchm ark portfolio will not necessarily be an efficient portfolio. The portfolio chosen on the new efficiency frontier will depend on the the m anager s objective function. The traditional Markowitz approach of using the m ean/variance criterion to choose the portfolio typically leads to portfolios th at are too risky for active m anagers. Active m anagers are much more adverse to the risk of deviation from the benchm ark than they are to risk in return of the benchm ark portfolio. This is because the investor bears the risk of the benchmark, whereas the m anager bears the risk of deviating from the benchmark. Instead of looking at total return, active m anagers focus on the active component of return and look at active risk/return tradeoffs. Active return is defined as the difference between the return on the m anager s portfolio and the benchmark portfolio. Active managers choose a portfolio th a t maximizes a value added utility function. Value added is a risk adjusted expected return th at ignores any contribution from the benchm ark to risk and expected return. 1.2.1 Com parison w ith the Markowitz M odel Like the Markowitz model, active portfolio managers solve the portfolio optim ization problem by maximising a quadratic utility function in terms of expected return and variance. The two m ethods differ in the definition of risk and return. The Markowitz model considers total risk and total return whereas active managers consider risk and return relative to a benchmark. W hen comparing the performance of these two m ethods one would expect the Markowitz m ethod to outperform the active m anagem ent m ethod. This is because of the active m anagement m ethod restricts the set of possible portfolios th at can be chosen to be close to the benchmark. Future work is to be done on performance analysis of these two methods. Active portfolio m anagem ent suffers from the same problem as the Markowitz model when returns are serially correlated.

91 32nd ORSNZ Conference Proceedings 2 D yn am ic Portfolio Selection An alternative approach to static portfolio selection is to consider the entire planning horizon at the same time. This requires the portfolio optim ization problem to be reformulated in term s of a multi-period framework. The dynam ic nature of the portfolio selection problem, for example the fluctuating security returns over tim e, can then be modelled as a m ulti-stage stochastic program. As well as capturing the dynamic nature of the problem, this also allows for a number of realizations for the uncertain quantities. Stochastic programming models for the portfolio selection problem are discussed in detail below. 2.1 S toch astic Program m ing for Portfolio O p tim ization Dynamic portfolio selection problems can be modelled as either stochastic network models [7] or multi-stage stochastic programs [1]. Stochastic network models formulate the problem as a tim e-expanded network flow problem. A network model is constructed by associating a network node with each security-tim e period pair, and an arc with each transaction decision. Each arc may have an associated multiplier th at can be used to represent, for example, exchange, return or borrowing rates. External deposits or withdrawals correspond to supplies and demands at the nodes, and flow conservation constraints are present at the nodes. M ulti-stage stochastic programming models formulate the problem as a linear (or non-linear) program with a dynamic m atrix structure. The m atrix appears as a staircase pattern of blocks, with each block corresponding to a different tim e period. U ncertainty in both models is represented by a number of distinct realizations. Each complete realization of all unknown param eters is known as a scenario. As the scenarios and their corresponding probabilities are m ajor inputs into the stochastic models, it is im portant th at the scenario set is representative. A num ber of authors discuss scenario generation techniques (for example, see Mulvev and Vladim irou [6])- The aim of both m ethods is to generate an investment recom m endation for the current period th at does not depend on previous events, but takes into account all postulated scenarios and their respective probabilities. The goal is to maximise the expected utility of the value of the portfolio at the end of the planning horizon. 2.1.1 Comparison w ith Static Portfolio O ptim ization M ulti-stage stochastic models for portfolio optim ization have a num ber of advantages over static portfolio optim ization. Stochastic models allow for serial correlation of the returns. The serial correlation is incorporated into the model via the return scenarios. Future liabilities, anticipated external deposit/w ithdraw al cash stream s and liquidity requirements can also be considered in a stochastic m ultistage model. However, if the security returns are independent over tim e then the Markowitz model has an advantage over multi-stage stochastic models. The scenarios th a t are used in the stochastic models are (usually) generated from a variance-covariance m atrix of the security returns. The variance-covariance of the resulting scenario

32nd ORSNZ Conference Proceedings 92 set thus provides only an approxim ation to the original variance-covariance m atrix. The Markowitz model uses the actual variance-covariance m atrix of returns. As static models are statistically correct when returns are independent, the Markowitz model therefore has an added advantage. Future work is to be done on performance analysis of the Markowitz model and stochastic m ulti-stage program m ing models, with and w ithout serial correlation of yields. Acknow ledgem ents I would like to thank the Foundation for Research, Science and Technology for there generous support. I would also like to thank Tower Portfolio Management for supplying the necessary d ata for my experiments, and Associate Professor Andy P hilpott for providing excellent supervision of my work. References [1] G. Dantzig, G. Infanger, Multi-Stage Stochastic Linear Programs fo r Portfolio O ptim ization, Annals of operation Research, 45 (1993), pp59-76. [2] R. Grinold, R. Kahn, Active Portfolio Management. Quantitative Theory and Applications, Probus publishing. [3] M.S. Feldstein, Mean-Variance Analysis in the Theory of Liquidity Preference and Portfolio Selection, The Review of Economic Studies, 36 (January 1969), pp5-12. [4] N.H. Hakansson, On Optimal Myopic Portfolio Policies, with and without Serial Correlation of Yields, The Journal of Business, Vol. 44, 3 (1971), pp 324-334. [5] H. Markowitz, Portfolio Selection, Journal of Finance, 3 (1952), pp 77-91. [6] J. Mulvey, H. Vladim irou, Stochastic Network Optimization Models for Investm ent Planning, Annals of Operations Research, 20 (1989), pp 187-217. [7] J. Mulvey, H. Vladimirou, Stochastic Network Programming fo r Financial Planning Problems, M anagement Science, 38 (1992), pp 1642-1664. [8] P. A. Samuelson, The Fundamental Approximation Theorem of Portfolio Analysis in terms of Means, Variances and Higher M oments, The Review of Economic Studies, 4 (1970), pp537-542. [9] P. W hittle, Optimization Under Constraints, Wiley (1971).