Emerging Markets: can diversification protect against contagion?

Similar documents
Threats to Financial Stability in Emerging Markets: The New (Very Active) Role of Central Banks. LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ Chicago, November 2011

Tracking the Growth Catalysts in Emerging Markets

Can Emerging Economies Decouple?

Chi on China Up or Down? The Knowns and Unknowns of the RMB New Normal

What is driving US Treasury yields higher?

2015 FUZZY DAY CONFERENCE Facts that are Not Facts. The US dollar Safe Haven Myth and the United States Hedge Fund.

Chi on China Up or Down? The Knowns and Unknowns of the RMB New Normal

Asian Monetary Coordination and Global Imbalances

Emerging market equities

.Mean KBank S Capital Markets Perspectives

Neoliberalism, Investment and Growth in Latin America

Investing in international equities: not scary just practical

WTO lowers forecast after sub-par trade growth in first half of 2014

ROUNDTABLE COMMENTS ON MONETARY AND REGULATORY POLICY IN AN ERA OF GLOBAL MARKETS

Creating a More Efficient Fixed Income Portfolio with Asia Bonds

All the BRICs dampening world trade in 2015

Lessons of the Financial Crisis for the Design of the New International Financial Architecture

EM FX Doing the rounds Nordea Research, 14 February 2014

Schroder Asian Income Monthly Fund Update

Schroders Emerging markets - time for trustees to look again?

Reducing Currency Mismatching: A Domestic Agenda

GLOBAL MARKET OUTLOOK

STRUCTURAL CHALLENGES FACING THE SINGAPORE ECONOMY

INSIGHT JAE LEE & ANISHA A. GOODLY JUNE 21, Improving Growth Rates in EM Economies

INTERIM SHORT REPORT. Henderson Institutional Emerging Markets Fund. For the six months ended 30 April 2015

PRODUCT KEY FACTS. Principal Global Investors Funds Global Equity Fund April 2018

EconWatch. Qualms of forex volatility; strong USD prior to policy tightening in the US. 21 August 2015

PRODUCT KEY FACTS. Principal Global Investors Funds Global Equity Fund April 2017

Weekly Market Commentary

Axioma Risk Monitor Emerging Markets 3 May 2018

Bond Basics July 2007

Why Invest Internationally?

Axioma Risk Monitor Emerging Markets 6 November 2018

Nationwide Funds. A Nationwide Financial White Paper. Executive summary

No use buying the best house in a bad neighbourhood

Asia Total Return Fund

U.S. Global Investors Searching for Opportunities, Managing Risk

Global Debt and The New Neutral

The Outlook for the Global Economy and World Trade

ANGLORAND INVESTMENT INSIGHTS

Sovereign Risks and Financial Spillovers

MASTER INVESTOR SHOW APRIL

Capturing Opportunity, Managing Risk

Seven-year asset class forecast returns

The Future of Globalization

A CASE FOR GLOBAL LISTED REAL ESTATE SECURITIES IN A MIXED ASSET PORTFOLIO

Asia s Debt Risks The risk of financial crises is limited, but attention should be paid to slowing domestic demand.

JPMorgan Europe Strategic Dividend Fund

Lazard Insights. China A-Shares: A New Chapter for EM Investors. Summary. John Burge, Director, Product Manager

SPDR MSCI Emerging Markets StrategicFactors SM ETF

HSBC GIF Managed Solutions - Asia Focused Growth Quarterly fund report Q2 2014

Emerging markets: Individual country or broad-market exposure?

Investment. Insights. Emerging Markets. Invesco Global Equity. A 2012 outlook

Oxford Economics: Macromodelling. contagion & downside risks. Keith Church Director of Macroeconomic Modelling.

Presentation The role of fixed income today. Quentin Fitzsimmons. Senior Portfolio Manager, Fixed Income T. Rowe Price

PRODUCT KEY FACTS BNY MELLON EMERGING MARKETS DEBT LOCAL CURRENCY FUND 30 April 2018

Panel on. Policymaking in a Global Context. Remarks by. Robert T. Parry. President and Chief Executive Officer Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

All about the markets and where we stand

First Quadrant Emerging Market Debt

ASIAN ECONOMIC INTEGRATION REPORT 2017

Replies to memo questions, 09/09/03

A Country Picker's Market

HSBC GIF Managed Solutions - Asia Focused Income Quarterly fund report Q2 2014

No October 2013

Emerging Markets Weekly Economic Briefing

The international environment

Distribution Number 9

Third Quarter of the Fiscal Year Ending December 31, 2016 Unicharm Presentation Materials for Investor Meeting

Global Business Economics. Mark Crosby SEMBA International Economics

Challenges for financial institutions today. Summary

Global Select International Select International Select Hedged Emerging Market Select

GLOBAL FDI OUTFLOWS CONTINUED TO RISE IN 2011 DESPITE ECONOMIC UNCERTAINTIES; HOWEVER PROSPECTS REMAIN GUARDED HIGHLIGHTS

Quarterly market summary

PIMCO Global Advantage Government Bond Index. Index Specification

Cosa ci riserva il 2008?

3. Debt Indicators of Households and Corporations

International Money and Banking: 6. Problems with Monetarism

Fund Management Diary

Monthly Outlook. June Summary

Macro Briefing A monthly review of the economy and markets January 2014

Income. Income Amounts. Income Segments. As part of the Core survey, GWI asks all respondents about their annual household income.

Does short-term investment performance matter?

contagion (Pericoli & Sbracia, 2003). A generalized definition of financial crisis is turmoil in

Annual Market Review Portfolio Management

Japan s Economy: Monthly Review

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

NEUBERGER BERMAN INVESTMENT FUNDS PLC

Ten Lessons Learned from the Korean Crisis Center for International Development, 11/19/99. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Harpel Professor, Harvard University

Seeking Diversification Through Emerging Markets July 2009

Primer: building a case for infrastructure finance Rising rates, reduced returns?

Schroders Institutional Investor Study Institutional perspectives on sustainable investing

Global growth weakening as some risks materialise

Xtrackers MSCI All World ex US High Dividend Yield Equity ETF

Growth has peaked amidst escalating risks

Keeping you informed matters Economic review. October matters

Macroeconomics II. Growth. Recent phenomenon Great diversity of growth experiences across countries. Why do some countries grow and others not?

OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

External shocks, the exchange rate and macroprudential policy

Asset Allocation THE CHANGING FACE OF EMERGING MARKETS

Transcription:

Marketing material for professional investors or advisers only Emerging Markets: can diversification protect against contagion? February 218 Ring-a-ring o roses, a pocket full of posies, A-tishoo! A-tishoo! We all fall down Old British nursery rhyme. Craig Botham Emerging Markets Economist Diversification is important for any investment portfolio, but particularly so in emerging markets (EMs), where risks are arguably higher than elsewhere. However, the evidence suggests that there are only limited benefits to be had from diversifying within EMs. Although correlations appear to have reduced since the financial crisis in 27 and 28, it may be that the market has been distorted by the quantitative easing introduced to combat the financial fallout from the crash. A central theory for any investor is that diversification should serve to reduce risk. Across countries, this is because most economic and market disturbances are country specific. Consequently, equity markets (and other assets) in different countries should be fairly uncorrelated. By spreading investment across a range of countries, or spreading our eggs across multiple baskets, portfolio risk is therefore reduced and returns increased. Is this true within EM? The universe is after all very diverse, economically and geographically: Korea and Brazil are incredibly different economies, for example. Korea s economy is small, open, and focused on high tech products, while Brazil s is large, more closed and reliant on commodities for export revenues. Does this difference translate to a divergence in equity performance? The table in Figure 1, shows some equity market correlations over a near-2 year period. We compare Brazil and Korea, as well as the broader MSCI Emerging Markets equity index. It is immediately apparent that there is some very high comovement of equity indices within EM, with certain regions moving together closely. Brazil is particularly correlated with Chile and Mexico, while Korea exhibits a strong relationship with Malaysia, Thailand, India and Indonesia. Even worse for our theory of diversification, Brazil and Korea have a pretty strong correlation despite their fundamental differences, and most individual EM equity indices seem strongly correlated to the MSCI Emerging Markets index. On this basis, there would seem to be little benefit in diversifying across EM (though Brazil does show some value as a diversifier for exposure to Taiwan or the Philippines). Figure 1: EM Equity Correlations (1998 217) Brazil Korea MSCI EM Brazil 1..76.89 Chile.87.89.92 Malaysia.76.91.9 Thailand.55.88.81 S Africa.83.97.98 Indonesia.73.91.89 Korea.76 1..96 Mexico.82.96.96 India.76.95.94 Philippines.45.82.73 Czech Rep..82.74.83 China.87.82.9 Taiwan.66.78.79 Poland.57.78.76 Russia.81.92.95 MSCI EM.89.96 1. Colour scale from red to green denotes high to low correlations. Equity indices used are local indices, converted to US dollars. Source: Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217.

However, it turns out that if we reduce the sample period to the post crisis era (211 onwards), many of these correlations are significantly weakened. As shown by the table in Figure 2, Korea and Brazil are now close to uncorrelated, and markets like India and the Philippines actually move in the opposite direction to Brazil, so offer definite diversification benefits. All the same, it is clear that correlations can change over time, and this should be a cause of concern for us as investors. How do we know when diversifying within EM will reduce risk, and when will it not? Happily, we can find some answers (of a sort) in the study of contagion. When Latin America sneezes, will Asia catch a cold? To borrow from academia 1, contagion in general is used to refer to the spread of market disturbances from one country to the other, a process observed through comovements in exchange rates, stock prices, sovereign spreads, and capital flows. Many academic papers go further and divide contagion into two categories. 1 Dornbusch, R., Park, Y., and Claessens, S., Contagion: How it spreads and how it can be stopped? World Bank Research Observer, vol. 15, no. 2 (August 2), pp. 177 97. The first focuses on spill-overs which result from normal interdependence among economies: economic and financial linkages which exist in all states of the world. It is worth elaborating on these linkages a little. One real linkage is trade; any country which is hit by financial crisis is likely to see a fall in demand, which will hurt trade partners economically and lead to asset price reductions as investors price this shock to growth. A second economic link can be competitive devaluation or depreciation. A country undergoing a crisis may deliberately devalue its currency, and will in any case be under depreciation pressure from the market. This hurts trade partners and trade competitors who may in turn feel pressured to weaken their own currencies. Again, anticipating this, investors may begin shorting the currencies of those economies in advance. On the financial side, a crisis in a country s financial system is highly likely to see a reduction in the provision of credit by that country to the rest of the world. Foreign direct investment, trade credit, and other capital flows will be adversely affected. Figure 2: EM Equity correlations 211 217 Brazil Korea MSCI EM Brazil 1..15.76 Chile.9.22.76 Malaysia.49.18.59 Thailand -.32.46.2 S Africa.63.57.9 Indonesia.58.3.65 Korea.15 1..69 Mexico.47.34.69 India -.3.6.12 Philippines -.73.27 -.23 Czech Rep..85.29.78 China.94.15.73 Taiwan -.42.17 -.14 Poland -.1.88.54 Russia.3.8.76 MSCI EM.76.69 1. Colour scale from red to green denotes high to low correlations. Source: Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217. 2

The second category of contagion involves a financial crisis which is not the result of a change in fundamentals but is instead generated by investor behaviour (rational or otherwise). In such cases, co-movement increases despite no change in the underlying fundamentals. As one example, consider the liquidity constraints faced by lenders and investors. Large capital losses incurred in one market may induce institutional investors to sell other assets to raise funds in anticipation of redemptions, while international lenders may reduce high risk exposures elsewhere in response to a significant deterioration in asset quality in one market. Tougher capital regulations will amplify this effect as banks attempt to maintain capital ratios. Another consideration is that investors may be tracking a benchmark, or investing in EM via an index, so that losses and selling of one EM equity market necessitates a reduction in their holdings of all EM equity markets. As the chart in Figure 3 shows, this could generate some rather unexpected correlations. Separately, but still within this category, are problems of limited information. Investors will often not have complete information about every market in their investment universe. This is obviously linked to practical constraints, but also to behavioural biases: we all tend to look for simple rules of thumb to help reduce information overload. This can mean a crisis in one country leads investors to think other economies with some similar characteristics could face the same problems. In this way, a crisis in one emerging economy can be transmitted to EM economies. Figure 3: MSCI EM benchmark weights Brazil There are a couple of questions to address. The first is whether the lower correlations seen in the post-financial crisis period are because we have removed the distortion of assorted crises. The second is whether the first category of contagion connections, related to economic and financial linkages, have reduced in importance since 211. If not it would imply that correlations will again spike in the next crisis, reducing the usefulness of intra-em diversification. Only contagious in a crisis? So beginning with our first question, let s explore the idea that perhaps correlations are normally more like those seen in the table in Figure 2 than in the table in Figure 1, and that the higher correlations of Figure 1 are the result of crises temporarily boosting co-movement through the channels described in the second category above. Figure 4 shows the average correlation coefficient for EM equity indices during different periods: during financial crises (defined here as the Asian crisis which ran from 1997 21, and the global crisis of 27 which we treat as ending in 21), and outside of them, and before and after the global financial crisis (GFC). It seems clear that the correlations we saw in the table in Figure 2 are a recent development, and that actually prior to the GFC, equity indices were quite highly correlated whether there was a crisis or not. Figure 4: Reduction in contagion is a recent phenomenon EM equities, average pairwise correlation coefficient.9.8.7 2% 8% 8% China India.6.5 12% Indonesia.4 6% 3% 3% 2% 15% 2% 9% 3% Korea Malaysia Mexico Russia S Africa Taiwan Thailand Other Other contains several markets whose weight in the overall index is less than 2%. Source: Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217. Evidently this second category of contagion only occurs in a crisis, but it is also the case that contagion via the first channel (real and financial linkages) will also be amplified in a crisis. This is because the magnitude of changes in fundamentals can be far greater than in normal economic times. What we are suggesting here then is that the strong correlations observed in the table in Figure 1 may be the result of economic crises boosting correlations to above normal levels..3.2.1 In crisis periods* Non-crisis Pre-GFC (22-6) Post-GFC (211 17) *Crisis periods 1997-1, 27-21. Source: Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217. However, we are looking at averages here, so perhaps there is some distortion by particularly highly correlated markets. Figure 5 shows correlation averages for individual EM equity markets, in the crisis and non-crisis periods. There are a handful of countries where we might argue for crisisinduced contagion, but overall there is only weak evidence at best that crises strongly boost equity correlations. So if crises are not to blame for the fairly highly correlated nature of equity markets, what is? And, in answer to our second question above, how can we explain the breakdown in correlations since the financial crisis? 3

Figure 5: Some limited evidence at country level of a crisis effect EM equities, average pairwise correlation coefficient 1..9.8.7.6.5.4.3.2.1. BRL CLP MYR THB ZAR IDR KRW MXN INR PHP CZK RUB CNY TWD PLN Non-crisis Crisis Source: Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217. Have emerging markets gained herd immunity? Perhaps, following the GFC, the real and financial linkages between EM countries have begun to break down, limiting the possibilities for contagion and thus reducing correlations. Perhaps the retreat of globalisation is responsible for the step change in co-movement? Beginning with perhaps the main real economy link, trade, recall that we are focusing here on the ability of one emerging market economy to transmit a shock to the other. With that in mind, Figure 6 shows how much of EM trade is conducted with other EMs. From 196 to 2, the share was fairly steady, before rising to touch 4% by 212. The first explanation to come to mind for the increase is China, but note also that EM Asia ex China also grew its total share at that time, while other regions remained constant. Figure 6: EM trade with EM has grown in importance % 45 EM exports as share of total, by destination 4 35 3 25 2 15 1 5 6 62 64 66 68 7 72 74 76 78 8 82 84 86 88 9 92 94 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 12 14 16 China Asia ex China LatAm EM Europe Other Intra EM Source: Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217. 4

In comparing the periods before and after the GFC, the trade link then looks stronger, if anything. So the scope for contagion through this channel seems greater, with China and the rest of EM Asia growing in their potential to transmit shocks to the rest of the EM area. As for financial linkages, it is unfortunately very difficult to find data on capital flows between EM economies. Most do not provide the data, though the Bank for International Settlements does have a handful. Instead, we will make do with looking at total cross border bank claims on EMs by the rest of the world (which will include other EM economies). This will give an indication of EM integration into the global financial system and also the importance of these flows to their economies. Figure 7 shows both claims on and liabilities to EMs excluding China, and claims on and liabilities to China itself separately. For the EM area overall, claims as a share of GDP declined heading into the crisis and have fluctuated since. It is hard to conclude that EM reliance on foreign banks has been that different after the GFC to the average beforehand. Interestingly, liabilities to EMs remain depressed compared to pre-gfc levels. Note however that these data are based on bank residency rather than nationality. As a result, an Indian bank in Russia would count as a Russian bank, for example. A reduction in liabilities to India could just mean locals have moved money onshore, rather than implying that India is lending less money to the Russian economy. Still, this is perhaps weak evidence of a reduced transmission mechanism from EMs to the rest of the world, including other EM economies. The case of China seems less ambiguous. Both claims and liabilities increased rapidly post crisis. So it is difficult to argue that China has become a smaller source of contagion via financial channels. Figure 7: Cross border bank claims % Share of EM ex China GDP % 2 7 Share of Chinese GDP 18 6 16 14 5 12 4 1 8 3 6 2 4 1 2 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 12 14 16 96 98 2 4 6 8 1 12 14 16 Liabilities to EM ex China Claims on EM ex China Liabilities to China Claims on China Source: Bank for International Settlements, Schroders Economics Group and Thomson Datastream, 25 October 217. 5

Squaring the circle All of this is somewhat confusing. Crises do not seem to cause additional contagion, and the non-crisis channels for contagion do not appear to have atrophied at a time when correlations have fallen. How can we explain what we see in the data? A paper 2 written in the aftermath of the EM crises of the late 199s argued that correlation coefficients can be affected by the size of market moves, even when transmission mechanisms are unchanged. The authors point can be demonstrated by a relatively simple example, which we adapt from their paper. Imagine a game in which you flip two coins, a ten cent piece and a euro: heads you win the value of the coin, tails you lose the value of the coin. Your reward at the end of the game is 1% of your first win or loss (so 1% of 1c), plus your second win or loss. This means you can win between - 1.1 and 1.1. Now imagine a second game where, instead of the 1c, you flip a specially made 1 coin. The same rules apply, but the outcomes now range from - 11 and 11. Crucially, the contagion from the first game to the second is still only 1%. Yet when we look at the correlation between the 2 Forbes, K., Rigobon, R., Measuring Contagion: Conceptual and Empirical Issues International Financial Contagion, ed. by Claessens, S., and Forbes, K., 21. payoff from each game with the first round, the difference is massive (Figure 8). Imagine that instead of a coin toss, the table represents shocks in EM. Game 1 is a time of only small market moves in patient zero, the source of contagion. Its contagion to the rest of EM is given by the payoff. The correlation at this time of muted market and economic disturbances is very low, around 1%. Now look what happens when the shocks are far larger. The pass-through to the overall outcome is still only 1%, but the correlation jumps to essentially 1%. In other words, with very small stakes, correlations are correspondingly low. But increase the stakes, and correlations skyrocket, even though the degree of passthrough is unchanged. How does this apply to our discussion? Our contention would be that by massively reducing volatility, quantitative easing (QE) has created a world which resembles game 1 more than game 2. This would imply that the transmission mechanisms remain largely unchanged and that a more volatile world would see an increase in correlations between EM equity indices. We recognise that this is a strong assertion, and hope to do further work to investigate the connection, as well as to expand this analysis to other EM assets. Figure 8: The problem with correlations Round 1 Round 2 Payoff Correlation of payoff with first round Game 1 1 1 11 1-1 -99-1 1 99 ~ -1-1 -11 Game 2 1, 1 1,1 1, -1 9-1, 1-9 ~1-1, -1-1,1 Payoff is 1% of Round 1 outcome + 1% of Round 2 outcome. Source: Forbes and Rigobon (21) and Schroders Economics Group, 25 October 217. 6

horizons matter We came up with two questions to address following the lower for the post-gfc period than the long term average. increase in correlations, and the other was whether the scope for contagion has diminished since the GFC. The end useful hedging tool, or if correlations are likely to spike in the next crisis. A look at correlations in crisis and non-crisis periods was not hugely supportive of the idea that it is only times of extreme stress that generate high intra-em co-movement. There were some markets where correlations were noticeably higher, so we would not rule it out altogether, the basis of an investment strategy. On the second question, we would conclude that if anything the channels for contagion between EM economies have strengthened over time. This makes sense in a globalising world where countries become more deeply embedded in global supply chains and more most to EM Asia (with or without China), so shocks from this region could be more readily transmitted today than With these two questions answered we are left with a new conundrum. Why are correlations lower since the GFC? Here we would offer the tentative hypothesis that a reduction in volatility occasioned by global QE has reduced statistical correlations, even while transmission mechanisms remain as strong as ever. A potential implication of this then would be that the withdrawal of QE and subsequent increase in volatility could see intra-em equity correlations rise back to former levels, eroding the Again, we have not looked at shorter-term behaviour of relative value trades within EM will never work. Plenty of investors can and do make money from such trades. At the begin to unwind their QE policies, long-term investors should bear this in mind. Conclusion We have not found compelling evidence that diversifying within emerging markets will save investors at time of market stress. If, therefore, investors are happy with the hedging properties of their portfolio outside of a crisis, they strongly over shorter time horizons, so perhaps a caveat here should be that this applies only for investors happy to hold through short-term volatility. Investors should also be aware that what has passed for normal in markets over the last 1 years may change once monetary policy starts running again along more conventional lines. Important information: Any security(s) mentioned above is for illustrative purpose only, not a recommendation to invest or divest. This document is intended to be for information purposes only and it is not intended as promotional material in any respect. The views and opinions contained herein are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily represent views expressed or r in other Schroders communications, strategies or funds. The material is not intended to provide, and should not be relied on for investment advice or recommendation. Opinions stated are matters of judgment, which may change. Information herein is believed to be reliable, but Schroder Investment Management (Hong Kong) Limited does not warrant its completeness or accuracy. Investment involves risks. Past performance and any forecasts are not necessarily a guide to future or likely performance. You should remember that the value of investments can go down as well as up and is not guaranteed. Exchange rate changes may cause the value of the overseas investments to rise or fall. For risks associated with investment in securities in emerging and less developed markets, please refer to the relevant offering document. The information contained in this document is provided for information purpose only and does not constitute any solicitation and offering of investment products. Potential investors should be aware that such investments involve market risk and should be regarded as long-term investments. Derivatives carry a high degree of risk and should only be considered by sophisticated investors. This material including the website has not been reviewed by the SFC. Issued by Schroder Investment Management (Hong Kong) Limited.