Lecture 2: Taxation of Earnings. Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation

Similar documents
Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation:

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation:

Empirical Evidence and Tax Reform: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Econ 3007 Economic Policy Analysis. Reforming the Tax System Lecture I: The Taxation of Earnings. February 2017

Empirical Evidence and Tax Policy Design: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

Tax Reform and its Implications for Inequality

Taxation of Earnings and the Impact on Labor Supply and Human Capital

TAX POLICY REFORM: THE ROLE OF EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

Labour Supply and Taxes

Empirical Evidence and Tax Policy Design: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY

Empirical Evidence and Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Viewpoint: Empirical evidence and tax policy design: lessons from the Mirrlees Review

Lessons from the Mirrlees Review

The long-term effects of in-work benefits in a lifecycle model for policy evaluation

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Taxation of Earnings and the Impact on Labor Supply and Human Capital. Discussion by Henrik Kleven (LSE)

Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families

The Microeconometric Analysis of Consumption, Savings and Labour Supply

Policy Design: Lessons from the

Structural models of the labour market and the impact and design of tax policies

Labour Supply Responses and the Extensive Margin: The US, UK and France

Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Taxation of Low Income Families

The Welfare Effects of Welfare and Tax Reform during the Great Recession

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

Extensive and Intensive Margins of Labour Supply: Work and Working Hours in the US, UK and France

The effect of UK welfare reforms on the distribution of income and work incentives

Using Differences in Knowledge Across Neighborhoods to Uncover the Impacts of the EITC on Earnings

Effective Policy for Reducing Inequality: The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Distribution of Income

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley PE Handbook Conference, Berkeley December 2011

Evaluating the labour market impact of Working Families. Tax Credit using difference-in-differences

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

Microsimulation Models for Fiscal Policies: CPB The Netherlands. Egbert Jongen

Optimal Household Labor Income Tax and Transfer Programs: An Application to the UK

Extensive and Intensive Margins of Labour Supply: Working Hours in the US, UK and France

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Means-testing and tax rates on earnings

Working Families Tax Credit: A Review of the Evidence, Issues and Prospects for Further Research

Channels of labour supply responses of lone parents to changed work incentives

Taxes and Labour Supply

Labor supply models. Thor O. Thoresen Room 1125, Friday

Redistribution and Tax Expenditures: The Earned Income Tax Credit

CEP Discussion Paper No 724 Revised and republished June 2015

Empirical public economics (31.3, 7.4, seminar questions) Thor O. Thoresen, room 1125, Friday

Labour Supply Estimation Project - Briefing Note

Distributional Impacts of the Self Sufficiency Project

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Analyzing Female Labor Supply: Evidence from a Dutch Tax Reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform

The Impact of In-Work Benefits on Poverty and Household Labour Supply A simulation study for Switzerland. Michael Gerfin Robert E.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES FEMALE LABOUR SUPPLY, HUMAN CAPITAL AND WELFARE REFORM. Richard Blundell Monica Costa Dias Costas Meghir Jonathan M.

Optimal tax and transfer policy

The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Labor Supply of Married Couples

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

Adjust Me if I Can t: The Effect of Firm. Firm Incentives and Labor Supply Responses to Taxes.

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

Welfare-to-Work: Which Policies Work and Why? Keynes Lecture in Economics: 2001

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Female Labor Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform

Reforms to Universal Credit

Financial work incentives and the long-term unemployed

Anatomy of Welfare Reform:

Tax Transfer Policy and Labor Market Outcomes

The Rise of the In-Work Safety Net: Implications for Income Inequality and Family Health and Well-being

From Welfare to Work: Evaluating a Proposed Tax and Benefit Reform Targeted at Single Mothers in Sweden

Centre for Economic Policy Research

Optimal Household Labor Income Tax and Transfer Programs: An Application to the UK

Making Work Pay: Increasing Labour Supply of Secondary Earners in Low Income Families with Children

microsimulation Antoine Bozio Master PPD Paris January 2018 Paris School of Economics (PSE) École des hautes études en sciences sociales (EHESS)

Optimal Household Labor Income Tax and Transfer Programs: An Application to the UK

THE CENTRAL ROLE OF A WELL-DESIGNED INCOME TAX IN THE MODERN ECONOMY

Active labour market policy vs employment tax credits: lessons from recent UK reforms

The redistribution and insurance value of welfare reform

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Welfare Reform

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

Optimal Taxation of Secondary Earners in the Netherlands: Has Equity Lost Ground?

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population

International Tax Competition: Zero Tax Rate at the Top Re-established

Overview of Econometric Approaches of Policy Evaluation. Xiaodong Gong

The impact of in-work benefits on employment and poverty

Lone parents, time-limited in-work benefits and the dynamics of work and welfare

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Evaluation of Four Tax Reforms in the United States: Labor Supply and Welfare Effects for Single Mothers

TAXABLE INCOME RESPONSES. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for MSc Public Economics (EC426): Lent Term 2014

Dynamic Analysis of EITC Expansion

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Discussion Papers. Peter Haan Katharina Wrohlich. Optimal Taxation: The Design of Child Related Cash- and In-Kind-Benefits

Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay

Labour Supply. Lecture notes. Dan Anderberg Royal Holloway College January 2003

Tax Simplicity and Heterogeneous Learning

GPP 501 Microeconomic Analysis for Public Policy Fall 2017

Topic 11: Disability Insurance

Education, labour supply and welfare

What we know and are learning about the EITC Kartik Athreya March 31, 2015

Transcription:

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation: Lessons from the Mirrlees Review Lecture 2: Taxation of Earnings Munich Lectures in Economics 2010 CESifo November 2010 Richard Blundell University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies Institute for Fiscal Studies Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation This lecture will analyse the context, the impact and the design of earnings tax reforms It will focus on two questions: How should we measure the impact of taxation on work decisions and earnings? How should we assess the optimality of tax reforms?

Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation A discussion on the role of evidence loosely organised under five headings: 1. Key margins of adjustment to tax reform 2. Measurement of effective tax rates 3. The importance of information and complexity 4. Evidence on the size of responses 5. Implications for tax design Empirical Evidence and Earnings Taxation Sub-heading (and subtext) for the lecture: Labor Supply Responses at the Extensive Margin: What Do We Know and Why Does It Matter? Key chapter (in Mirrlees Review): Brewer, Saez and Shephard, http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview + commentaries by Moffitt, Laroque and Hoynes

The extensive intensive distinction is important for a number of reasons: Understanding responses to tax and welfare reform Jim Heckman, David Wise, Ed Prescott, etc.. all highlight the importance of extensive labour supply margin, perhaps too much. The size of extensive and intensive responses are also key parameters in the recent literature on earnings tax design used heavily in the Mirrlees Review. But the relative importance of the extensive margin is specific to particular groups I ll examine a specific case of low earning families (from Blundell and Shephard, 2010) in more detail in what follows Draw on new empirical evidence: some examples labour supply responses for individuals and families at the intensive and extensive margins by age and demographic structure taxable income elasticities top of the income distribution using tax return information income uncertainty persistence and magnitude of earnings shocks over the life-cycle ability to (micro-)simulate marginal and average rates simulate reforms

So where are the key margins of response? Evidence suggests they are not all the extensive margin.. intensive and extensive margins both matter they matter for tax policy evaluation and earnings tax design and they matter in different ways by age and demographic groups Getting it right for men Employment for men by age FR, UK and US 2007 100% 90% 80% 70% FR UK US 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010)

Total Hours for men by age FR, UK and US 2007 2000 1750 FR UK US 1500 1250 1000 750 500 250 0 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) Key Margins of Adjustment and for women..

Female Total Hours by age US, FR and UK 2007 1600 1400 1200 FR UK US 1000 800 600 400 200 0 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) Female Hours by age US, FR and UK 1977 1600 1400 1200 FR UK US 1000 800 600 400 200 0 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 60 62 64 66 68 70 72 74 Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010)

Decomposition of change in annual hours worked (1977-2007) 1400 1300 1977: 1212 hours 2007: 1308 hours United-States 1200 1100 1977: 1148 hours 1977: 1124 hours 2007: 1094 hours 1000 2007: 953 hours United-Kingdom 900 France 800 Institute for Fiscal Studies Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) Change in structure Women 55-74 Men 55-74 Women 30-54 Men 30-54 Women 16-29 Men 16-29 Thinking about Responses at the Intensive and Extensive Margin Write within period utility as 11/ h c if h 0 U 1 1/ c if h 0 α is the intensive labour supply elasticity and she works when the value of working at wage w exceeds the fixed cost β. Convenient to describe the distribution of heterogeneity through the conditional distribution of β given α, F(β α) and the marginal distribution of α. The labour supply and employment rate for individuals of type α, is 1 w hw (, ) w and pw (, ) F 1

Thinking about Responses at the Intensive and Extensive Margin The intensive and the employment rate elasticity are 1 ) 1 ) 1 ) w w I( ) and E( ) w f / F 1 1 The aggregate hours elasticity is a weighted sum across the intensive and extensive margins dln H 1 [ w 1 w wf ww f ] dg ( ) dln w H 1 1 1 pw (, ) hw (, )[ I( ) E( )] dg( ) H Of course, quasi-linear utility is highly restrictive and we expect income effects to matter, at least for some types of households we use more general models with fixed costs Measuring Responses at the Intensive and Extensive Margin Suppose the population share at time t of type j is qjt, then total hours J H q H and H p h t jt jt jt jt jt j 1 Changes in total hours per person written as the sum of changes across all types of workers and the change in structure of the population H H S J t t 1 t t where wit h q [ H H ] t j 1 jt jt jt 1 jt jt 1 We can also mirror the weighted elasticity decomposition H 1 J hj p j qj pjhj pjhj H H j 1 hj pj And derive bounds on extensive and intensive responses for finite changes

Bounds on Intensive and Extensive Responses (1977-2007) Year Men 16-29 Women 16-29 Men 30-54 Women 30-54 Men 55-74 Women 55-74 FR I-P, I-L [-37,-28] [-23, -19] [-59, -56] [-49, -35] [-11, -8] [-10, -9] E-L, E-P [-54, -45] [-19, -16] [-27, -23] [71, 85] [-28, -25] [6, 7] Δ -82-38 -82 36-36 -3 UK I-P, I-L [-42, -36] [-26, -23] [-48, -45] [-3, -2] [-22, -19] [-8, -6] E-L, E-P [-35, -29] [14, 17] [-25, -22] [41, 41] [-23, -20] [15, 17] Δ -71-9 -70 39-42 10 US I-P, I-L [-6, -6] [1, 1] [-5, -5] [14, 19] [3, 3] [3, 5] E-L, E-P [-13, -13] [21, 21] [-14, -14] [72, 77] [3, 3] [33, 35] Δ -19 22-19 90 6 38 Institute for Fiscal Studies Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010) Bounds on Intensive and Extensive Responses (1977-2007) Year Men 16-29 Women 16-29 Men 30-54 Women 30-54 Men 55-74 Women 55-74 FR I-P, I-L [-37,-28] [-23, -19] [-59, -56] [-49, -35] [-11, -8] [-10, -9] E-L, E-P [-54, -45] [-19, -16] [-27, -23] [71, 85] [-28, -25] [6, 7] Δ -82-38 -82 36-36 -3 UK I-P, I-L [-42, -36] [-26, -23] [-48, -45] [-3, -2] [-22, -19] [-8, -6] E-L, E-P [-35, -29] [14, 17] [-25, -22] [41, 41] [-23, -20] [15, 17] Δ -71-9 -70 39-42 10 US I-P, I-L [-6, -6] [1, 1] [-5, -5] [14, 19] [3, 3] [3, 5] E-L, E-P [-13, -13] [21, 21] [-14, -14] [72, 77] [3, 3] [33, 35] Δ -19 22-19 90 6 38 Institute for Fiscal Studies Blundell, Bozio and Laroque (2010)

Why is this distinction important for tax design? Some key lessons from recent tax design theory (Saez (2002, Laroque (2005),..) A large extensive elasticity at low earnings can turn around the impact of declining social weights implying a higher optimal transfer to low earning workers than to those out of work a role for earned income tax credits But how do individuals perceive the tax rates on earnings implicit in the tax credit and benefit system - salience? are individuals more likely to take-up if generosity increases? marginal rates become endogenous Importance of margins other than labour supply/hours use of taxable income elasticities to guide choice of top tax rates Importance of dynamics and frictions An Empirical Analysis in Two Steps The first step (impact) is a positive analysis of household decisions. There are two dominant empirical approaches to the measurement of the impact of tax reform both prove useful: 1. A quasi-experimental evaluation of the impact of historic reforms /and randomised experiments 2. A structural estimation based on a general discrete choice model with (unobserved) heterogeneity The second step (optimality) is the normative analysis or optimal policy analysis Examines how to best design benefits, in-work tax credits and earnings tax rates with (un)observed heterogeneity and unobserved earnings capacity

Focus first on tax rates on lower incomes Main defects in current welfare/benefit systems Participation tax rates at the bottom remain very high in UK and elsewhere Marginal tax rates are well over 80% for some low income working families because of phasing-out of means-tested benefits and tax credits Working Families Tax Credit + Housing Benefit in UK and interactions with the income tax system for example, we can examine a typical budget constraint for a single mother in the UK Particular Features of the UK Working Tax Credit hours of work condition minimum hours rule - 16 hours per week an additional hours-contingent payment at 30 hours family eligibility children (in full time education or younger) adult credit plus amounts for each child income eligibility family net income below a certain threshold credit is tapered away at 55% (previously 70% under FC)

The UK Working Families Tax Credit 6,000 5,000 WFTC 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 Gross income ( /year) Institute for Fiscal Studies The US EITC and the UK WFTC compared 6,000 5,000 WFTC 4,000 3,000 EITC 2,000 1,000 0 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 Gross income ( /year) Puzzle: WFTC about twice as generous as the US EITC but Institute with for Fiscal about Studies half the impact. Why?

The interaction of WFTC with other benefits in the UK 300 Low wage lone parent 250 200 150 100 WFTC Net earnings Other income 50 0 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 hours of work The interaction of WFTC with other benefits in the UK 300 Low wage lone parent 250 200 150 100 WFTC Income Support Net earnings Other income 50 0 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 hours of work

The interaction of WFTC with other benefits in the UK 300 Low wage lone parent 250 200 150 100 50 0 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 hours of work Local tax rebate Rent rebate WFTC Income Support Net earnings Other income Strong implications for EMTRs, PTRs and labour supply The interaction between taxes, tax credits and benefits Net weekly income 350,0 300,0 250,0 200,0 150,0 100,0 50,0,0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220 Gross weekly earnings Income support Council tax benefit Housing benefit Working tax credit Child tax credit Child benefit Net earnings less council tax Notes: Lone parent, with one child aged between one and four, earning the minimum wage ( 5.80 per hour), with no other private income and no childcare costs, paying 80 per week in rent to live in a council tax Band B property in a local authority setting council tax rates at the national average

But this is just an example. What does the tax and benefit system imply across the distribution of earnings and different family types? What do effective marginal tax rates look like? the proportion of a small increase in earnings taken in tax and withdrawn benefits What do participation tax rates look like? the incentive to be in paid work at all defined by the proportion of total earnings taken in tax and withdrawn benefits. Average EMTRs for different family types 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200 Employer cost ( /week) Single, no children Partner not working, no children Partner working, no children Lone parent Partner not working, children Partner working, children

Average PTRs for different family types 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200 Employer cost ( /week) Single, no children Partner not working, no children Partner working, no children Lone parent Partner not working, children Partner working, children Can the reforms explain weekly hours worked? Single Women (aged 18-45) - 2002 Blundell and Shephard (2009)

Hours distribution for lone parents, before WFTC Blundell and Shephard (2010) Hours distribution for lone parents, after WFTC Blundell and Shephard (2010)

Hours trend for low ed lone parents in UK 1600 1550 1500 1450 1400 1350 1300 1250 1200 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Employment trends for lone parents in UK 0,8 0,75 0,7 0,65 0,6 0,55 College No College 0,5 0,45 0,4 0,35 0,3 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

WFTC Reform: Quasi-experimental Evaluation Matched Difference-in-Differences Average Impact on % Employment Rate of Single Mothers Single Mothers Family Resources Survey Labour Force Survey Marginal Effect Standard Error Sample Size 4.5 1.55 25,163 4.7 0.55 233,208 Data: FRS, 45,000 adults per year, Spring 1996 Spring 2002. Base employment level: 45% in Spring 1998. Matching Covariates: age, education, region, ethnicity,.. Alternative approaches to measuring the impact: Structural model Simulate effect of actual or hypothetical reforms Useful for (optimal) design too, but, robust? Quasi experiment/difference in differences Compares outcomes of eligibles and non eligibles and estimates average impact of past reform Only indirectly related to what is needed for optimal design Can use this quasi experimental evidence to (partially) validate the structural model Randomised experiment? SSP?

Canadian Self Sufficiency Program Randomised Control experimental design Do financial incentives encourage work among low skilled lone parents? The aim was to encourage employment among single parents on welfare 50% earnings supplement as a tax credit at least 30 hours per week job On earnings up to an annual limit of $36000 provided to the individual, not the employer, as in EITCs 39 Canadian Self Sufficiency Program Budget Constraint for a Single Parent on Minimum Wage Income per Month ($1995) 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 SSP IA 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 Weekly Hours of Work Income Assistance Self Sufficiency Program 40

SSP: Employment Rate by months after RA Employment rate.1.15.2.25.3 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Months after random assignment control experimental Key features of the structural model Preferences Uc (, hpx, ;, ) h typically approximated by shape constrained sieves Structural model allows for - unobserved work-related fixed costs - childcare costs - observed and unobserved heterogeneity - programme participation take-up costs See Blundell and Shephard (2010)

Importance of take-up and information/hassle costs Variation in take-up probability with entitlement to WFTC Probability of take-up 0.2.4.6.8 1 0 50 100 150 200 WFTC entitlement ( /week, 2002 prices) Lone parents Couples Institute for Fiscal Studies Net Income schedule : Tax P: take-up y wh I twhi (, ) C ( whi,, ) P ( whi,, ) hp h 0 1 or y (,, ) hp y P 1 w h I hp Transfers the tax-credit payment function depends on: hours (through the hours condition of entitlement) other income I ( whi,, ) 1 demographic characteristics X 44

Structural Model Elasticities low education lone parents (a) Youngest Child Aged 5-10 Weekly Density Extensive Intensive Earnings 0 0.4327 50 0.1575 0.280 (.020) 0.085 (.009) 150 0.1655 0.321 (.009) 0.219 (.025) 250 0.1298 0.152 (.005) 0.194 (.020) 350 0.028 0.058 (.003) 0.132 (.010) Employment elasticity 0.820 (.042) Structural Model Elasticities low education lone parents (c) Youngest Child Aged 0-4 Weekly Density Extensive Intensive Earnings 0 0.5942 50 0.1694 0.168 (.017) 0.025 (.003) 150 0.0984 0.128 (.012) 0.077 (.012) 250 0.0767 0.043 (.004) 0.066 (.010) 350 0.0613 0.016 (.002) 0.035 (.005) Participation elasticity 0.536 (.047) Differences in intensive and extensive margins by age and demographics have strong implications for the design of the tax schedule... But do we believe the structural model estimates?

Structural Simulation of the WFTC Reform: WFTC Tax Credit Reform All y-child y-child y-child y-child 0 to 2 3 to 4 5 to 10 11 to 18 Change in employment rate: 6.95 3.09 7.56 7.54 4.96 0.74 0.59 0.91 0.85 0.68 Average change in hours: 1.79 0.71 2.09 2.35 1.65 0.2 0.14 0.23 0.34 0.2 Notes: Simulated on FRS data; Standard errors in italics. relatively large impact Blundell and Shephard (2010) Impact of WFTC reform on lone parent, 2 children Weekly net income 300 250 200 150 100 1997 2002 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 Hours/week Notes: Two children under 5. Assumes hourly wage of 4.10, no housing costs or council tax liability and no childcare costs.

Impact of WFTC and IS reforms on lone parent, 2 children Weekly net income 300 250 200 150 100 1997 2002 0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36 40 44 48 Hours/week Notes: Two children under 5. Assumes hourly wage of 4.10, no housing costs or council tax liability and no childcare costs. Structural Simulation of the WFTC Reform: Impact of all Reforms (WFTC and IS) All y-child y-child y-child y-child 0 to 2 3 to 4 5 to 10 11 to 18 Change in employment rate: 4.89 0.65 5.53 6.83 4.03 0.84 0.6 0.99 0.94 0.71 Average change in hours: 1.02 0.01 1.15 1.41 1.24 0.23 0.21 0.28 0.28 0.22 shows the importance of getting the effective tax rates right especially when comparing with quasi-experiments. compare with experiment or quasi-experiment.

Evaluation of the ex-ante structural model The diff-in-diff impact parameter can be identified from the structural evaluation model Simulated diff-in-diff parameter The structural model then defines the average impact of the policy on the treated as: ( X ) Pr[ h 0 X, D 1] Pr[ h SEM 0 X, D 0] Compare simulated diff-in-diff moment with diff-in-diff f ( X,, D 1) df df f( X,, D 0) df df DD T 1, t 1 T 1, t 0 SEM X X X X X T 0, t 1 T 0, t 0 f( X,, D 0) df dfx f( X,, D 0) df df X X Evaluation of the ex-ante model The simulated diff-in-diff parameter from the structural evaluation model is precise and does not differ significantly from the diff-in-diff estimate Compare simulated diff-in-diff moment with diff-in-diff.21 (.73), chi-square p-value.57 Consider additional moments education: low education: 0.33 (.41) youngest child interaction Youngest child aged < 5:.59 (. 51) Youngest child aged 5-10:.31 (.35)

How do we think about an optimal design? Assume we want to redistribute R to low ed. single parents, what is the optimal way to do this? Recover optimal tax/credit schedule in terms of earnings use Diamond-Saez approximation in terms of extensive and intensive elasticities at different earnings T T 1 T T c c eh c c I i i 1 j 0 hj 1 g j j. i i 1 i i j i j 0 also complete Mirrlees optimal tax computation A microeconometric optimal tax design framework Assume earnings (and certain characteristics) are all that is observable to the tax authority relax below to allow for partial observability of hours Social welfare, for individuals of type X W ( U( wh T( w, h ; X), h ; X, )) df( ) dg( w; X) wx, The tax structure T(.) is chosen to maximise W, subject to: T( wh, h ; X) df( ) dg( w; X) T( R) wx, for a given R.

Control preference for equality by transformation function: 1 ( U ) (exp U) 1 when θ is negative, the function favors the equality of utilities. θ is the coefficient of absolute inequality aversion. If θ < 0 then analytical solution to integral over (Type I extreme-value) j state specific errors (BS, 2010) 1 (1 ) ( exp u( j)) 1 h Objective: robust policies for fairly general social welfare weights, document the weights in each case Implied Optimal Schedule, Youngest Child Aged 5-10 Weekly earnings March 2002 prices Blundell and Shephard (2010)

Implied Optimal Schedule, Youngest Child Aged 5-10 Results Suggests dynamic tax incentives according to age of (youngest) child Redistributing towards early years (see Table 10 in Blundell and Shephard, 2010) Implications for Tax Reform Change transfer/tax rate structure to match lessons from new optimal tax analysis and empirical evidence in the Review we use a similar design framework for family labour supply and early retirement Key role of labour supply responses at the extensive and intensive margins Both matter but differ by gender, age, education and family composition lone parents, married parents, pre-retirement low earners. Results for lone parents suggest lower marginal rates at the bottom means-testing should be less aggressive at least for some key groups =>

Implications for Tax Reform Life-cycle view of taxation distinguish by age of (youngest) child for mothers/parents pre-retirement ages effectively redistributing across the life-cycle a life-cycle rearrangement of tax incentives and welfare payments to match elasticities and early years investments results in Tax by Design show significant employment and earnings increases Hours rules? at full time for older kids, welfare gains depend on ability to monitor hours Dynamics and frictions? some time to adjust but little in the way of experience effects for low-skilled Dynamic effects on wages for low income welfare recipients? SSP: Hourly wages by months after RA Hourly real wages 6 6.5 7 7.5 8 8.5 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Months after random assignment control experimental Institute for Fiscal Studies

SSP: Monthly earnings by months after RA Monthly earnings 100 200 300 400 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 Months after random assignment control experimental Institute for Fiscal Studies Evidence on experience effects from the SSP Little evidence of employment enhancement or wage progression Other evidence, Taber etc, show some progression but quite small Remains a key area of research ERA Policy in UK. Institute for Fiscal Studies

At the top too the income tax system lacks coherence Income tax schedule for those aged under 65, 2010 11 70% 60% Marginal income tax rate 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 Gross annual income ( 000s) Top tax rates and taxable income elasticities An optimal top tax rate (Brewer, Saez and Shephard, MRI) e taxable income elasticity t = 1 / (1 + a e) where a is the Pareto parameter. Estimate e from the evolution of top incomes in tax return data following large top MTR reductions in the 1980s Estimate a ( 1.8) from the empirical distribution

Top incomes and taxable income elasticities A. Top 1% Income Share and M TR, 1962-2003 80% 16% 70% 14% 60% Marginal Tax Rate 50% 40% 30% Top 1% MTR Top 1% income share 12% 10% 8% Income Share 20% 10% 6% 0% 4% 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 Source: MR1, UK SPI (tax return data) B. Top 5-1% Income and M TR, 1962-2003 80% 16% 70% 14% Marginal Tax Rate 60% 50% 40% 30% 12% 10% 8% 20% 10% 0% 1962 1966 1970 1974 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 Income Share Top 5-1% M TR Top 5-1% income share 6% 4%

Taxable Income Elasticities at the Top Simple Difference (top 1%) DD using top 5-1% as control 1978 vs 1981 0.32 0.08 1986 vs 1989 0.38 0.41 1978 vs 1962 0.63 0.86 2003 vs 1978 0.89 0.64 Full time series 0.69 0.46 (0.12) (0.13) With updated data the estimate remains in the.35 -.55 range with a central estimate of.46, but remain quite fragile Note also the key relationship between the size of elasticity and the tax base (Slemrod and Kopczuk, 2002) Pareto distribution as an approximation to the income distribution Probability density (log scale) 0.0100 0.0010 0.0001 0.0000 Pareto distribution Actual income distribution 0.0000 100,000 150,000 200,000 250,000 300,000 350,000 400,000 450,000 500,000 Pareto parameter quite accurately estimated at 1.8 => revenue maximising tax rate for top 1% of 55%.

Reforming Taxation of Earnings Change transfer/tax rate structure to match lessons from new optimal tax analysis lower marginal rates at the bottom means-testing should be less aggressive distinguish by age of youngest child age-based taxation pre-retirement ages limits to tax rises at the top, but base reforms - anti-avoidance, domicile rules, revenue shifting Integrate different benefits and tax credits improve administration, transparency, take-up, facilitate coherent design Undo distributional effects of the rest of the package http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview Richard Blundell University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies Institute for Fiscal Studies

Some References: Besley, T. and S. Coate (1992), Workfare versus Welfare: Incentive Arguments for Work Requirement in Poverty Alleviation Programs, American Economic Review, 82(1), 249-261. Blundell, R. (2006), Earned income tax policies: Impact and Optimality, The 2005 Adam Smith Lecture to the Society of Labor Economics, Labour Economics, 423-443. Blundell, R.W., Duncan, A. and Meghir, C. (1998), "Estimating Labour Supply Responses using Tax Policy Reforms", Econometrica, 66, 827-861. Blundell, R, Duncan, A, McCrae, J and Meghir, C. (2000), "The Labour Market Impact of the Working Families' Tax Credit", Fiscal Studies, 21(1). Blundell, R. and Hoynes, H. (2004), "In-Work Benefit Reform and the Labour Market", in Richard Blundell, David Card and Richard.B. Freeman (eds) Seeking a Premier League Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Blundell, R. and MaCurdy, T. (1999), "Labour Supply: A Review of Alternative Approaches", in Ashenfelter and Card (eds), Handbook of Labour Economics, Elsevier North-Holland. Blundell, R. and Shephard, A. (2008), Employment, Hours of Work and the Optimal Design of Earned Income Tax Credits IFS WP 08/01, revised 2010. Brewer, M. (2003), The New Tax Credits, IFS Briefing Note No. 25, www.ifs.org.uk Brewer, M. A. Duncan, A. Shephard, M-J Suárez, (2006), Did the Working Families Tax Credit Work?, Labour Economics, 13(6), 699-720. Brewer, M. E. Saez and A. Shephard, (2010) Means-testing and tax rates on earnings, Mirrlees Review, IFS, www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview Card, David and Philip K. Robins (1998), "Do Financial Incentives Encourage Welfare Recipients To Work?", Research in Labor Economics, 17, pp 1-56. Diamond, P. (1980): "Income Taxation with Fixed Hours of Work," Journal of Public Economics, 13, 101-110. Eissa, Nada and Jeffrey Liebman (1996), "Labor Supply Response to the Earned Income Tax Credit", Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXI, 605-637. Gregg, P. and S. Harkness (2003), Welfare Reform and Lone Parents in the UK, CMPO Working Paper Series, 03/072. Gruber, Jon, and Saez, Emmanuel (2002) The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications, Journal of Public Economics, 84, 1-32. Immervoll, H. Kleven, H. Kreiner, C, and Saez, E. (2005), `Welfare Reform in European Countries: A Micro-Simulation Analysis CEPR DP 4324, Economic Journal.

Laroque, G. (2005), Income Maintenance and Labour Force Participation, Econometrica, 73(2), 341-376. Liebman, J. (2002), The Optimal Design of the Earned Income Tax Credit, in Bruce Meyer and Douglas Holtz-Eakin (eds.), Making Work Pay: The Earned Income Tax Credit and Its Impact on American Families, New-York: Russell Sage Foundation. Mirrlees, J.A. (1971), The Theory of Optimal Income Taxation, Review of Economic Studies, 38, 175-208. Moffitt, R. (1983), "An Economic Model of Welfare Stigma", American Economic Review, 73(5), 1023-1035. Phelps, E.S. (1994), Raising the Employment and Pay for the Working Poor, American Economic Review, 84 (2), 54-58. Saez, E. (2002): "Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive versus Extensive Labor Supply Responses," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1039-1073. Slemrod, J. and W. Kopczuk (2002), The optimal elasticity of taxable income, Journal of Public Economics 84 (2002) 91 112 Strengthen work incentives where they are most effective I. for families whose youngest child is of school age reflecting the finding that the mothers of older children are more responsive to the incentives in the tax and benefit system. One way of achieving this: make CTC more generous (and so means-testing more extensive) for families a child aged under five, and less generous (with less means-testing) for families whose youngest child is aged five or older. Simulations point to a net addition to employment of over 50,000 and to earnings of nearly 1bn.

Strengthen work incentives where they are most effective II. for those in their later working life, aged 55-70 a group which is highly responsive to incentives. This could be achieved in the current system by raising the age of eligibility for pension credit to 70, reducing to 55 the age at which employees no longer have to pay NI and the age at which the higher tax free personal allowance becomes available. Our simulations point to an increase in net employment of more than 150,000 and in earnings of just under 2bn. As with our child tax credit proposals, much of the distributional impact would consist of offsetting effects over the life-cycle. Summary We are still bound by the trade-off between incentives and redistribution But the current system is unnecessarily complicated and induces too many people not to work or to work too little The rate structure of income tax should be simplified, and income tax and NICs should be merged. A single integrated benefit should be introduced rationalising the way in which total support varies with income and other characteristics. Work incentives should be targeted where they are most effective Placing us in a good position to address the distributional implications of other aspects of our reform package

Pareto Improving Reforms Results so far derived for a specific class of social welfare function with varying degrees of inequality aversion. suppose we are concerned with the extent to which these features are also implied solely by efficiency identify a set of reforms that result in Pareto improvements. We take the actual tax/transfer system T and calculate the maximized value of utility for all X and all (ε) subject to the individual incentive compatibility constraint and individual budget constraint (Table 13, BS (2010)). results point to a small increase in out-of-work income, together with a reduction in the size of the part- time hours bonus and a large increase in the full-time hours bonus. Decomposing Responses at the Intensive and Extensive Margin Changes in average hours H worked in sub-population j decompose according to index bounds into hours per worker h and participation p H jt [ hjt hjt 1] pit [ pjt pjt 1] hjt 1 H [ h h ] p [ p p ] h jt jt jt it 1 jt jt 1 jt

Structural Model Elasticities low education lone parents (b) Youngest Child Aged 11-18 Weekly Density Extensive Intensive Earnings 0 0.3966 50 0.1240 0.164 (.018) 0.130 (.016) 150 0.1453 0.193 (.008) 0.387 (.042) 250 0.1723 0.107 (.004) 0.340 (.035) 350 0.1618 0.045 (.002) 0.170 (.015) Employment elasticity 0.720 (.036) Implied Optimal Schedule, Youngest Child Aged 11-18 Suggests dynamic tax incentives according to age of (youngest) child Redistributing towards early years (see Table 10 in Blundell and Shephard)

Our guiding principles The personal tax and benefit system should be progressive, coherent and transparent It should be designed to reflect the shape of the income distribution and responses to work incentives It will need to take much of the strain of distributional adjustments from other parts of the reform package Where do we start from? 1. A highly complex array of welfare benefits and tax credits which do not fit together well Are difficult and costly for people to deal with impose some very high effective tax rates on low earners 2. An income tax system that is opaque and unnecessarily complex a bizarre marginal rate structure two entirely separate taxes on earnings income tax and NICs 3. A system that does not take proper account of what we know about how different people respond to tax incentives

Increased empirical knowledge: some examples labour supply responses for individuals and families at the intensive and extensive margins by age and demographic structure taxable income elasticities top of the income distribution using tax return information income uncertainty persistence and magnitude of earnings shocks over the life-cycle ability to (micro-)simulate marginal and average rates simulate reforms Sub-heading (and subtext) for the lecture: Labor Supply Responses at the Extensive Margin: What Do We Know and Why Does It Matter?

So where are the key margins of response? Evidence suggests they are not all the extensive margin.. intensive and extensive margins both matter they matter for tax policy evaluation and earnings tax design and they matter in different ways by age and demographic groups Getting it right for men Implications Coherence and transparency requires that the income tax system itself be sensibly structured we need to move away from complexities such as that which sees the marginal rate rise from 40% to 60% at 100,000 of income before falling back to 40% at 112,950

Interpretation of the empirical results Small impact effects of WFTC are due to: interaction with other taxes and benefits and the rise in low income family allowances rather than small response elasticities. Reconciles the different employment impacts of the WFTC reforms and the EITC expansion Also suggests that the structural model predictions are quite accurate Differences in responses at the intensive and extensive margins by age and demographics have strong implications for the design of the tax schedule... Reforming Tax Rates The child-age tax reforms redistribute to families with younger children and increase employment by 40,000, aggregate earnings up by.7m Similar important employment increases also from preretirement age tax reforms retirement incentives highlight the interaction between the taxation of earnings and the taxation of savings/pensions Effective tax rates on earnings are a combination of the tax rate on earnings and on savings/pensions how do individual s perceive pension contributions? assumptions about intertemporal behaviour are critical

Structural Model Comparisons Institute for Fiscal Studies Blundell and Shephard (2009) Implied Optimal Schedule, Youngest Child Aged 5-11 Blundell and Shephard (2009, Figure 3) Weekly earnings April 2002 prices

Implied Optimal Schedule, Youngest Child Aged 0-4 Part-time Optimal Hours rule Blundell and Shephard (2009) Weekly earnings April 2002 prices Our key proposals 1. Simplify and integrate the benefit system 2. Merge income tax and NICs, and end practice of tapering personal allowances 3. Target work incentives where they are most effective Strengthen incentives for parents with school age children Strengthen incentives for those in their later working life

and these EMTRs and PTRs are just averages. The current structure of multiple benefits with an array of overlapping means-tests leaves some people facing effective marginal tax rates of over 90%. Implications for reform: For the tax and benefit system to be effective requires simplification and integration of the benefit and tax credit system What about redesigning the tax rate schedule? Use what we know about behavioural responses so people face strengthened work incentives: parents with school age children, people aged 55-70. People face stronger incentives at the times they are most responsive to them Reforms can be designed which redistribute mainly across the life-cycle The specific reforms we have simulated would generate large increases in employment rates

Expenditure on in-work programmes in the UK 7,000 Expenditure ( m, 2002 prices) 6,000 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 WFTC FC 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-2000 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03 Employment trends for lone parents in UK 0,8 0,75 WFTC 0,7 0,65 0,6 0,55 College No College 0,5 0,45 0,4 0,35 0,3 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Quasi experiment - matching and anticipation