The investment game in incomplete markets

Similar documents
The investment game in incomplete markets.

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Incorporating Managerial Cash-Flow Estimates and Risk Aversion to Value Real Options Projects. The Fields Institute for Mathematical Sciences

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Introduction to Real Options

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Option Pricing Models for European Options

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Real Option Analysis for Adjacent Gas Producers to Choose Optimal Operating Strategy, such as Gas Plant Size, Leasing rate, and Entry Point

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

VII. Incomplete Markets. Tomas Björk

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Capacity Expansion Games with Application to Competition in Power May 19, Generation 2017 Investmen 1 / 24

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

2.4 Industrial implementation: KMV model. Expected default frequency

Real Options and Signaling in Strategic Investment Games

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Valuing Early Stage Investments with Market Related Timing Risk

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Economic Risk and Decision Analysis for Oil and Gas Industry CE School of Engineering and Technology Asian Institute of Technology

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Martingale Pricing Applied to Dynamic Portfolio Optimization and Real Options

The Black-Scholes Equation

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Change of Measure (Cameron-Martin-Girsanov Theorem)

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

Lattice (Binomial Trees) Version 1.2

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

The Black-Scholes Model

Pricing and hedging in incomplete markets

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers

Limits to Arbitrage. George Pennacchi. Finance 591 Asset Pricing Theory

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Prospect Theory, Partial Liquidation and the Disposition Effect

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

1. Traditional investment theory versus the options approach

Calibration Lecture 4: LSV and Model Uncertainty

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

LECTURES ON REAL OPTIONS: PART III SOME APPLICATIONS AND EXTENSIONS

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

The Multistep Binomial Model

Homework Assignments

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Luca Taschini. 6th Bachelier World Congress Toronto, June 25, 2010

Financial Risk Management

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Information Acquisition under Persuasive Precedent versus Binding Precedent (Preliminary and Incomplete)

A Stochastic Discount Factor Approach to Investment under Uncertainty

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Prospect Theory: A New Paradigm for Portfolio Choice

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

Game Theory: Normal Form Games

Robust Investment Decisions and The Value of Waiting to Invest

A VALUATION MODEL FOR INDETERMINATE CONVERTIBLES by Jayanth Rama Varma

Hedging Credit Derivatives in Intensity Based Models

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

CHAPTER 12. Hedging. hedging strategy = replicating strategy. Question : How to find a hedging strategy? In other words, for an attainable contingent

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Pricing levered warrants with dilution using observable variables

In chapter 5, we approximated the Black-Scholes model

Fourier Space Time-stepping Method for Option Pricing with Lévy Processes

Errata and updates for ASM Exam MFE/3F (Ninth Edition) sorted by page.

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Bluff Your Way Through Black-Scholes

MSC FINANCIAL ENGINEERING PRICING I, AUTUMN LECTURE 6: EXTENSIONS OF BLACK AND SCHOLES RAYMOND BRUMMELHUIS DEPARTMENT EMS BIRKBECK

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

FINANCIAL OPTIMIZATION. Lecture 5: Dynamic Programming and a Visit to the Soft Side

Transcription:

The investment game in incomplete markets M. R. Grasselli Mathematics and Statistics McMaster University Pisa, May 23, 2008

Strategic decision making We are interested in assigning monetary values to strategic decisions. Traditional, these include the decision to: create a new firm;

Strategic decision making We are interested in assigning monetary values to strategic decisions. Traditional, these include the decision to: create a new firm; invest in a new project;

Strategic decision making We are interested in assigning monetary values to strategic decisions. Traditional, these include the decision to: create a new firm; invest in a new project; start a real estate development;

Strategic decision making We are interested in assigning monetary values to strategic decisions. Traditional, these include the decision to: create a new firm; invest in a new project; start a real estate development; finance R&D;

Strategic decision making We are interested in assigning monetary values to strategic decisions. Traditional, these include the decision to: create a new firm; invest in a new project; start a real estate development; finance R&D; abandon a non-profitable project;

Strategic decision making We are interested in assigning monetary values to strategic decisions. Traditional, these include the decision to: create a new firm; invest in a new project; start a real estate development; finance R&D; abandon a non-profitable project; temporarily suspend operations under adverse conditions.

Many other non-financial decisions can be addressed in the same framework. For instance, the decision to: enroll in an MBA program;

Many other non-financial decisions can be addressed in the same framework. For instance, the decision to: enroll in an MBA program; get married;

Many other non-financial decisions can be addressed in the same framework. For instance, the decision to: enroll in an MBA program; get married; change the constitution of a country;

Many other non-financial decisions can be addressed in the same framework. For instance, the decision to: enroll in an MBA program; get married; change the constitution of a country; introduce environmental laws;

Many other non-financial decisions can be addressed in the same framework. For instance, the decision to: enroll in an MBA program; get married; change the constitution of a country; introduce environmental laws; develop a controversial highway;

Many other non-financial decisions can be addressed in the same framework. For instance, the decision to: enroll in an MBA program; get married; change the constitution of a country; introduce environmental laws; develop a controversial highway; commit suicide!

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools:

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; some degree of irreversibility; To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools:

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; some degree of irreversibility; timing flexibility; To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools:

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; some degree of irreversibility; timing flexibility; interaction with other people s decisions. To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools:

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; some degree of irreversibility; timing flexibility; interaction with other people s decisions. To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools: Net Present Value: intrinsic advantages

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; some degree of irreversibility; timing flexibility; interaction with other people s decisions. To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools: Net Present Value: intrinsic advantages Real Options: value of waiting

Elements of Valuation In all of the previous problems, we can identify the following common elements: uncertainty about the future; some degree of irreversibility; timing flexibility; interaction with other people s decisions. To account for these elements, we are going to base our decisions on values obtained using the following theoretical tools: Net Present Value: intrinsic advantages Real Options: value of waiting Game Theory: erosion of creation of value due to competition

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition. Though some problems have long time horizons (30 years or more), most strategic decisions involve much shorter times.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition. Though some problems have long time horizons (30 years or more), most strategic decisions involve much shorter times. The vast majority of underlying projects are not perfectly correlated to any asset traded in financial markets.

Successes and Limitations of Real Options Real options accurately describe the value of flexibility in decision making under uncertainty. According to a recent survey, 26% of CFOs in North America always or almost always consider the value of real options in projects. This is due to familiarity with the option valuation paradigm in financial markets and its lessons. But most of the literature in Real Options is based on different combinations of the following unrealistic assumptions: (1) infinite time horizon, (2) perfectly correlated spanning asset, (3) absence of competition. Though some problems have long time horizons (30 years or more), most strategic decisions involve much shorter times. The vast majority of underlying projects are not perfectly correlated to any asset traded in financial markets. In general, competition erodes the value of flexibility.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming. This approach lacks the intuitive understanding of opportunities as options.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming. This approach lacks the intuitive understanding of opportunities as options. Finally, competition is generally introduced using game theory.

Alternatives The use of well known numerical methods (e.g finite differences) allows for finite time horizons. As for the spanning asset assumption, the absence of perfect correlation with a financial asset leads to an incomplete market. Replication arguments can no longer be applied to value managerial opportunities. The most widespread alternative to replication in the decision-making literature is to introduce a risk-adjusted rate of return, which replaces the risk free rate, and use dynamic programming. This approach lacks the intuitive understanding of opportunities as options. Finally, competition is generally introduced using game theory. Surprisingly, game theory is almost exclusively combined with real options under the hypothesis of risk-neutrality!

A one period investment model Consider a two factor market where the discounted prices for the project V and a correlated traded asset S follow: (us 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 1, (us (S T, V T ) = 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 2, (1) (ds 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 3, (ds 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 4, where 0 < d < 1 < u and 0 < l < 1 < h, for positive initial values S 0, V 0 and historical probabilities p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4.

A one period investment model Consider a two factor market where the discounted prices for the project V and a correlated traded asset S follow: (us 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 1, (us (S T, V T ) = 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 2, (1) (ds 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 3, (ds 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 4, where 0 < d < 1 < u and 0 < l < 1 < h, for positive initial values S 0, V 0 and historical probabilities p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4. Let the risk preferences be specified through an exponential utility U(x) = e γx.

A one period investment model Consider a two factor market where the discounted prices for the project V and a correlated traded asset S follow: (us 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 1, (us (S T, V T ) = 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 2, (1) (ds 0, hv 0 ) with probability p 3, (ds 0, lv 0 ) with probability p 4, where 0 < d < 1 < u and 0 < l < 1 < h, for positive initial values S 0, V 0 and historical probabilities p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4. Let the risk preferences be specified through an exponential utility U(x) = e γx. An investment opportunity is model as an option with discounted payoff C t = (V e rt I ) +, for t = 0, T.

European Indifference Price The indifference price for the option to invest in the final period as the amount π that solves the equation max E[U(x +H(S T S 0 )] = max E[U(x π+h(s T S 0 )+C T ] H H

European Indifference Price The indifference price for the option to invest in the final period as the amount π that solves the equation max E[U(x +H(S T S 0 )] = max E[U(x π+h(s T S 0 )+C T ] H H Denoting the two possible pay-offs at the terminal time by C h and C l, the European indifference price is explicitly given by π = g(c h, C l ) (2) where, for fixed parameters (u, d, p 1, p 2, p 3, p 4 ) the function g : R R R is defined as g(x 1, x 2 ) = q ( ) γ log p 1 + p 2 p 1 e γx 1 + p2 e γx (3) 2 + 1 q ( ) p 3 + p 4 log γ p 3 e γx 1 + p4 e γx, 2 with q = 1 d u d.

Early exercise When investment at time t = 0 is allowed, it is clear that immediate exercise of this option will occur whenever its exercise value (V 0 I ) + is larger than its continuation value π C.

Early exercise When investment at time t = 0 is allowed, it is clear that immediate exercise of this option will occur whenever its exercise value (V 0 I ) + is larger than its continuation value π C. That is, from the point of view of this agent, the value at time zero for the opportunity to invest in the project either at t = 0 or t = T is given by C 0 = max{(v 0 I ) +, g((hv 0 e rt I ) +, (lv 0 e rt I ) + )}.

A multi period model Consider now a continuous-time two factor market of the form ds t = (µ 1 r)s t dt + σ 1 S t dw dv t = (µ 2 r)v t dt + σ 2 V t (ρdw + 1 ρ 2 dz).

A multi period model Consider now a continuous-time two factor market of the form ds t = (µ 1 r)s t dt + σ 1 S t dw dv t = (µ 2 r)v t dt + σ 2 V t (ρdw + 1 ρ 2 dz). We want to approximate this market by a discrete time processes (S n, V n ) following the one period dynamics (1).

A multi period model Consider now a continuous-time two factor market of the form ds t = (µ 1 r)s t dt + σ 1 S t dw dv t = (µ 2 r)v t dt + σ 2 V t (ρdw + 1 ρ 2 dz). We want to approximate this market by a discrete time processes (S n, V n ) following the one period dynamics (1). This leads to the following choice of parameters: u = e σ 1 t, h = e σ 2 t, d = e σ 1 t, l = e σ 2 t, p 1 + p 2 = e(µ 1 r) t d, p 1 + p 3 = e(µ 2 r) t l u d h l ρσ 1 σ 2 t = (u d)(h l)[p 1 p 4 p 2 p 3 ], supplemented by the condition p 1 + p 2 + p 3 + p 4 = 1.

Numerical Experiments We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters.

Numerical Experiments We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters. The fixed parameters are I = 1, r = 0.04, T = 10 µ 1 = 0.115, σ 1 = 0.25, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1

Numerical Experiments We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters. The fixed parameters are I = 1, r = 0.04, T = 10 µ 1 = 0.115, σ 1 = 0.25, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1 Given these parameters, the CAPM equilibrium expected rate of return on the project for a given correlation ρ is ( ) µ1 r µ 2 = r + ρ σ 2. (4) σ 1

Numerical Experiments We now investigate how the exercise threshold varies with the different model parameters. The fixed parameters are I = 1, r = 0.04, T = 10 µ 1 = 0.115, σ 1 = 0.25, S 0 = 1 σ 2 = 0.2, V 0 = 1 Given these parameters, the CAPM equilibrium expected rate of return on the project for a given correlation ρ is ( ) µ1 r µ 2 = r + ρ σ 2. (4) The difference δ = µ 2 µ 2 is the below equilibrium rate of return shortfall and plays the role of a dividend rate paid by the project, which we fix at δ = 0.04. σ 1

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2.

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2. This should be contrasted with the NPV criterion (that is, invest whenever the net present value for the project is positive) which in this case gives V NPV = 1.

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2. This should be contrasted with the NPV criterion (that is, invest whenever the net present value for the project is positive) which in this case gives V NPV = 1. The limit γ 0 in our model corresponds to the McDonald and Siegel (1986) threshold, obtained by assuming that investors are averse to market risk but neutral towards idiosyncratic risk.

Known Thresholds In the limit ρ ±1 (complete market), the closed form expression for the investment threshold obtained in the case T = gives V DP = 2. This should be contrasted with the NPV criterion (that is, invest whenever the net present value for the project is positive) which in this case gives V NPV = 1. The limit γ 0 in our model corresponds to the McDonald and Siegel (1986) threshold, obtained by assuming that investors are averse to market risk but neutral towards idiosyncratic risk. For our parameters, the adjustment to market risks is accounted by CAPM and this threshold coincides with V DP = 2

Dependence with Correlation and Risk Aversion 2 1.9 1.8!=0.5!=2!=8 2 1.9 1.8 "=0 "=0.6 "=0.9 1.7 1.7 1.6 1.6 threshold 1.5 threshold 1.5 1.4 1.4 1.3 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.1 1.1 1!1!0.5 0 0.5 1 correlation 1 0 2 4 6 8 10 risk aversion

Dependence with Volatility 5.5 5.5 5.5 5 4.5!=0!=0.6!=0.9 5 4.5!=0!=0.6!=0.9 5 4.5!=0!=0.6!=0.9 4 4 4 threshold 3.5 3 threshold 3.5 3 threshold 3.5 3 2.5 2.5 2.5 2 2 2 1.5 1.5 1.5 1 0.4 0.6 0.8 volatility 1 0.4 0.6 0.8 volatility 1 0.4 0.6 0.8 volatility

Dependence with Dividend Rate 14 12 10 threshold 8 6 "=0 "=0.6 "=0.9 4 2 0!0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3!

Dependence with Time to Maturity 1.5 Low risk aversion!=0.5 1.5 Higher risk aversion!=4 1.45 1.4 1.45 1.4 "=0 "=0.6 "=0.9 1.35 1.35 threshold 1.3 1.25 "=0 "=0.6 "=0.9 threshold 1.3 1.25 1.2 1.2 1.15 1.15 1.1 10 20 30 40 50 time to maturity 1.1 10 20 30 40 50 time to maturity

Values for the option to invest 0.5 0.4!=0!=0.99 (V!I) + option value 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 V Figure: Option value as a function of underlying project value. The threshold for ρ = 0 is 1.1972 and the one for ρ = 0.99 is 1.7507.

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules:

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules: 1. Outcomes of a given game that involve a wait and see strategy should be calculated by option value arguments.

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules: 1. Outcomes of a given game that involve a wait and see strategy should be calculated by option value arguments. 2. Once the solution for a given game is found on a decision node, its value becomes the pay-off for an option at that node.

Combining options and games For a systematic application of both real options and game theory in strategic decisions, we consider the following rules: 1. Outcomes of a given game that involve a wait and see strategy should be calculated by option value arguments. 2. Once the solution for a given game is found on a decision node, its value becomes the pay-off for an option at that node. In this way, option valuation and game theoretical equilibrium become dynamically related in a decision tree.

One period expansion option under monopoly Suppose now that a firm faces the decision to expand capacity for a product with uncertain demand: { hy0 with probability p Y 1 = ly 0 with probability 1 p, (5) correlated with a traded asset

One period expansion option under monopoly Suppose now that a firm faces the decision to expand capacity for a product with uncertain demand: { hy0 with probability p Y 1 = ly 0 with probability 1 p, (5) correlated with a traded asset The expansion requires a sunk cost I.

One period expansion option under monopoly Suppose now that a firm faces the decision to expand capacity for a product with uncertain demand: { hy0 with probability p Y 1 = ly 0 with probability 1 p, (5) correlated with a traded asset The expansion requires a sunk cost I. The state of the firm after the investment decision at time t k is { 1 if the firm invests at time tk x(k) = (6) 0 if the does not invest at time t k

One period expansion option under monopoly Suppose now that a firm faces the decision to expand capacity for a product with uncertain demand: { hy0 with probability p Y 1 = ly 0 with probability 1 p, (5) correlated with a traded asset The expansion requires a sunk cost I. The state of the firm after the investment decision at time t k is { 1 if the firm invests at time tk x(k) = (6) 0 if the does not invest at time t k The cash flow per unit demand for the firm is denoted by D x(k).

The NPV solution If no expansion occurs at time t 0, then the value of the project at time t 0 is v out = D 0 Y 0 + g(d 0 hy 0, D 0 ly 0 ) = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (D 0 Y 1 ).

The NPV solution If no expansion occurs at time t 0, then the value of the project at time t 0 is v out = D 0 Y 0 + g(d 0 hy 0, D 0 ly 0 ) = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (D 0 Y 1 ). If expansion occurs, then the value of the project at time t 0 is v in = (D 1 Y 0 I ) + g(d 1 hy 0, D 1 ly 0 ) = D 1 Y 0 + π 0 (D 1 Y 1 ).

The NPV solution If no expansion occurs at time t 0, then the value of the project at time t 0 is v out = D 0 Y 0 + g(d 0 hy 0, D 0 ly 0 ) = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (D 0 Y 1 ). If expansion occurs, then the value of the project at time t 0 is v in = (D 1 Y 0 I ) + g(d 1 hy 0, D 1 ly 0 ) = D 1 Y 0 + π 0 (D 1 Y 1 ). textcolorredif the decision needs to be taken at time t 0, then according to NPV the firm should expand provided v in v out, that is, if the sunk cost I is smaller then I NPV = (D 1 D 0 )Y 0 + (π 0 (D 1 Y 1 ) π 0 (D 0 Y 1 )). (7)

The RO solution By contrast, if the decision to invest can be postponed until time t 1, then the value of the project when no investment occurs at time t 0 is v wait = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (C 1 ), where C 1 denotes the random variable C 1 = C 1 (Y 1 ) = max{d 0 Y 1, D 1 Y 1 I } D 0 Y 1.

The RO solution By contrast, if the decision to invest can be postponed until time t 1, then the value of the project when no investment occurs at time t 0 is v wait = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (C 1 ), where C 1 denotes the random variable C 1 = C 1 (Y 1 ) = max{d 0 Y 1, D 1 Y 1 I } D 0 Y 1. Accordingly, the firm should invest at time t 0 provided v in v wait, that is, if the sunk cost is smaller than I RO = (D 1 D 0 )Y 0 + (π 0 (D 1 Y 1 ) π 0 (C 1 )). (8)

The RO solution By contrast, if the decision to invest can be postponed until time t 1, then the value of the project when no investment occurs at time t 0 is v wait = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (C 1 ), where C 1 denotes the random variable C 1 = C 1 (Y 1 ) = max{d 0 Y 1, D 1 Y 1 I } D 0 Y 1. Accordingly, the firm should invest at time t 0 provided v in v wait, that is, if the sunk cost is smaller than I RO = (D 1 D 0 )Y 0 + (π 0 (D 1 Y 1 ) π 0 (C 1 )). (8) Since the function g is non-decreasing in each of its arguments, I NPV I RO = π 0 (C 1 ) π 0 (D 0 Y 1 ) 0. (9)

The RO solution By contrast, if the decision to invest can be postponed until time t 1, then the value of the project when no investment occurs at time t 0 is v wait = D 0 Y 0 + π 0 (C 1 ), where C 1 denotes the random variable C 1 = C 1 (Y 1 ) = max{d 0 Y 1, D 1 Y 1 I } D 0 Y 1. Accordingly, the firm should invest at time t 0 provided v in v wait, that is, if the sunk cost is smaller than I RO = (D 1 D 0 )Y 0 + (π 0 (D 1 Y 1 ) π 0 (C 1 )). (8) Since the function g is non-decreasing in each of its arguments, I NPV I RO = π 0 (C 1 ) π 0 (D 0 Y 1 ) 0. (9) That is, according to RO, the firm is less likely to expand at time t 0.

One period duopoly Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to the uncertain demand Y.

One period duopoly Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to the uncertain demand Y. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i.

One period duopoly Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to the uncertain demand Y. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i. Assume that D 10 > D 11 > D 00 > D 01.

One period duopoly Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to the uncertain demand Y. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i. Assume that D 10 > D 11 > D 00 > D 01. We say that there is FMA is (D 10 D 00 ) > (D 11 D 01 ) and that there is SMA otherwise.

Equilibrium strategies Lemma Under FMA: 1. If I < IF h, then the equilibrium strategy is (1, 1) for high and low demand. 2. If IF l < I < I F h and I < I L l, then the equilibrium strategy is (1, 1) for high demand and (1, 0) for low demand. 3. If IF h < I < I L l, then the equilibrium strategy is (1, 0) for high and low demand. 4. If IF l < I < I F h and I L l < I, then the equilibrium strategy is (1, 1) for high demand and (0, 0) for low demand. 5. If IL l < I < I L h and I F h < I, then the equilibrium strategy is (1, 0) for high demand and (0, 0) for low demand. 6. If I > I h F, then the equilibrium strategy is (0, 0) for high and low demand.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i. Assume that D 10 > D 11 > D 00 > D 01.

A multi-period investment game Consider two firms L and F each operating a project with an option to re-invest at cost I and increase cash flow according to an uncertain demand dy t = µ(t, Y t )dt + σ(t, Y t )dw. Suppose that the option to re-invest has maturity T, let t m, m = 0,..., M be a partition of the interval [0, T ] and denote by (x L (t m ), x F (t m ) {(0, 0), (0, 1), (1, 0), (1, 1)} the possible states of the firms after a decision has been at time t m. Let D xi (t m)x j (t m) denote the cash flow per unit of demand of firm i. Assume that D 10 > D 11 > D 00 > D 01. We say that there is FMA is (D 10 D 00 ) > (D 11 D 01 ) and that there is SMA otherwise.

Derivation of project values (1) Let V (x i (t m 1 ),x j (t m 1 )) i (t m, y) denote the project value for firm i at time t m and demand level y.

Derivation of project values (1) Let V (x i (t m 1 ),x j (t m 1 )) i (t m, y) denote the project value for firm i at time t m and demand level y. Denote by v (x i (t m),x j (t m)) i (t m, y) the continuation values: v (1,1) (1,1) g(v i (t m+1, y u ), (V (1,1) i (t m+1, y d )) i (t m, y) = D 11 y t + e r t v (1,0) (1,0) g(v L (t m+1, y u ), (V (1,0) L (t m+1, y d )) L (t m, y) = D 10 y t + e r t v (0,1) (0,1) g(v L (t m+1, y u ), (V (0,1) L (t m+1, y d )) L (t m, y) = D 01 y t + e r t v (1,0) (1,0) g(v F (t m+1, y u ), (V (1,0) F (t m+1, y d )) F (t m, y) = D 01 y t + e r t v (0,1) (0,1) g(v F (t m+1, y u ), (V (0,1) F (t m+1, y d )) F (t m, y) = D 10 y t + e r t v (0,0) (0,0) g(v i (t m+1, y u ), (V (0,0) i (t m+1, y d )) i (t m, y) = D 00 y t + e r t

Derivation of project values (2) For fully invested firms, the project values are simply given by V (1,1) i (t m, y) = v (1,1) i (t m, y).

Derivation of project values (2) For fully invested firms, the project values are simply given by V (1,1) i (t m, y) = v (1,1) i (t m, y). Now consider the project value for firm F when L has already invested and F hasn t: V (1,0) F (t m, y) = max{v (1,1) F (t m, y) I, v (1,0) F (t m, y)}.

Derivation of project values (2) For fully invested firms, the project values are simply given by V (1,1) i (t m, y) = v (1,1) i (t m, y). Now consider the project value for firm F when L has already invested and F hasn t: V (1,0) F (t m, y) = max{v (1,1) F (t m, y) I, v (1,0) F (t m, y)}. Similarly, the project value for L when F has invested and L hasn t is V (0,1) L (t m, y) = max{v (1,1) L (t m, y) I, v (0,1) L (t m, y)}.

Derivation of project values (3) Next consider the project value for L when it has already invest and F hasn t: { V (1,0) v (1,1) L (t m, y) = L (t m, y) if v (1,1) F (t m, y) I > v (1,0) F (t m, y), (t m, y) otherwise. v (1,0) L

Derivation of project values (3) Next consider the project value for L when it has already invest and F hasn t: { V (1,0) v (1,1) L (t m, y) = L (t m, y) if v (1,1) F (t m, y) I > v (1,0) F (t m, y), (t m, y) otherwise. v (1,0) L Similarly, the project value for F when it has already invest and L hasn t is { V (0,1) v (1,1) F (t m, y) = F (t m, y) if v (1,1) L (t m, y) I > v (0,1) L (t m, y), (t m, y) otherwise. v (0,0) F

Derivation of project values (4) Finally, the project values V (0,0) i are obtained as a Nash equilibrium, since both firms still have the option to invest.

Derivation of project values (4) Finally, the project values V (0,0) i are obtained as a Nash equilibrium, since both firms still have the option to invest. The pay-off matrix for the game is Firm F Invest Wait Invest (v (1,1) Firm L L I, v (1,1) F I ) (v (1,0) L I, v (1,0) F ) Wait (v (0,1) L, v (0,1) F I ) (v (0,0) L, v (0,0) F )

FMA: dependence on risk aversion. 200 Gamma = 0.01 Rho = 0.5 200 Gamma = 0.1 Rho = 0.5 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand 200 Gamma = 1 Rho = 0.5 200 Gamma = 2 Rho = 0.5 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 250 300 Demand Figure: Project values in FMA case for different risk aversions.

FMA: dependence on correlation. 90 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma=1 Rho = 0.5 90 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma = 2 Rho = 0.5 80 80 70 70 Project Value 60 50 Project Value 60 50 40 40 30 V00F V00L 20!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 30 V00F V00L 20!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 90 VL Gamma = 2 VF Gamma = 1 Rho = 0.5 80 70 Project Value 60 50 40 30 V00F V00L 20!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation Figure: Project values in FMA case as function of correlation.

SMA: dependence on risk aversion 200 SMA Gamma=0.01 200 SMA Gamma=0.1 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Demand!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Demand 200 SMA Gamma=1 200 SMA Gamma = 2 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Demand Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F V00L V11L!I V10L!I V01L!200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 Demand Figure: Project values in SMA case for different risk aversions.

SMA: dependence on correlation. 200 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma = 1 Y0=105 200 VL Gamma = 1 VF Gamma = 2 Y0=105 150 150 Project Value 100 Project Value 100 50 50 0 V00F V00L!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 0 V00F V00L!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation 200 VL Gamma = 2 VF Gamma = 1 Y0=105 150 Project Value 100 50 0 V00F V00L!0.8!0.6!0.4!0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Correlation Figure: Project values in SMA case as function of correlation.

SMA x FMA 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=0.01 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=0.1 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=1 200 FMA/SMA Gamma=2 150 150 100 100 Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA Project Value 50 0!50!100!150 V00F FMA V00L FMA V11L!I V01L V00L SMA V00F SMA!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand!200 0 50 100 150 200 Demand Figure: Project values for FMA and SMA.