Econ 230B Spring FINAL EXAM: Solutions

Similar documents
ECON 4624 Income taxation 1/24

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley PE Handbook Conference, Berkeley December 2011

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Top MTR. Threshold/Averag e Income. US Top Marginal Tax Rate and Top Bracket Threshold. Top MTR (Federal Individual Income Tax)

Characterization of the Optimum

Lectures 9 and 10: Optimal Income Taxes and Transfers

Lecture 4: Optimal Labor Income Taxation

Econ 131 Spring 2017 Emmanuel Saez. Problem Set 2. DUE DATE: March 8. Student Name: Student ID: GSI Name:

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Optimal Labor Income Taxation (follows loosely Chapters of Gruber) 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Econ 131 Spring 2017 Emmanuel Saez. Problem Set 2. DUE DATE: March 8. Student Name: Student ID: GSI Name:

Optimal tax and transfer policy

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Optimal Progressivity

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Reflections on capital taxation

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

EC426 Public Economics Optimal Income Taxation Class 4, question 1. Monica Rodriguez

Closed book/notes exam. No computer, calculator, or any electronic device allowed.

Econ 551 Government Finance: Revenues Winter 2018

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 7: Optimal Top Income Taxation

Topic 2-3: Policy Design: Unemployment Insurance and Moral Hazard

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Hilary Hoynes UC Davis EC230. Taxes and the High Income Population

Principles of Optimal Taxation

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Generalized Social Marginal Welfare Weights for Optimal Tax Theory

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Final Examination: Economics 210A December, 2015

ECON 2001: Intermediate Microeconomics

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

1 Excess burden of taxation

Econ 100B: Macroeconomic Analysis Fall 2008

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Public Finance and Public Policy: Responsibilities and Limitations of Government. Presentation notes, chapter 9. Arye L. Hillman

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Lecture 4: Taxation and income distribution

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Political Economy. Pierre Boyer. Master in Economics Fall 2018 Schedule: Every Wednesday 08:30 to 11:45. École Polytechnique - CREST

PhD Qualifier Examination

Pareto Efficient Income Taxation

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON835: Development Economics Instructor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

GPP 501 Microeconomic Analysis for Public Policy Fall 2017

Closed book/notes exam. No computer, calculator, or any electronic device allowed.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

On the Potential for Pareto Improving Social Security Reform with Second-Best Taxes

Problems. the net marginal product of capital, MP'

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Lecture on Taxable Income Elasticities PhD Course in Uppsala

1 Unemployment Insurance

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DIRECT OR INDIRECT TAX INSTRUMENTS FOR REDISTRIBUTION: SHORT-RUN VERSUS LONG-RUN. Emmanuel Saez

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Mock Examination 2010

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Inequality in developed countries - how good is a good state. Åsa Hansson Lunds universitet

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Social Choice

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

TAXABLE INCOME RESPONSES. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for MSc Public Economics (EC426): Lent Term 2014

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Taxation of Earnings and the Impact on Labor Supply and Human Capital. Discussion by Henrik Kleven (LSE)

Topic 1: Policy Design: Unemployment Insurance and Moral Hazard

Retirement Financing: An Optimal Reform Approach. QSPS Summer Workshop 2016 May 19-21

ECON Micro Foundations

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 28 February 2008.

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

International Tax Competition: Zero Tax Rate at the Top Re-established

Topic 11: Disability Insurance

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Problem set 2. Filip Rozsypal November 23, 2011

Economics of Uncertainty and Insurance

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics SOLUTIONS

Online Appendix. income and saving-consumption preferences in the context of dividend and interest income).

Expected utility theory; Expected Utility Theory; risk aversion and utility functions

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Transcription:

Econ 230B Spring 2017 FINAL EXAM: Solutions The average grade for the final exam is 45.82 (out of 60 points). The average grade including all assignments is 79.38. The distribution of course grades is: 4 A+, 4 A, 4 A-, 6 B+, 5 B, 1-B, 1 C+. True/False Questions: 30 points Answer all 10 questions (3 pts each). Explain your answer fully, since all the credit is based on the explanation. Only short answers provided here. Full detailed in the class notes and relevant references. 1. Disability insurance has small negative effects on labor supply because empirical evidence shows that rejected disability insurance applicants work very little. Solution: True based on the famous paper by Bound (1989) and subsequently verified on a bigger scale by Von Waechter-Manchester-Song (2011). Caveat: it is possible that the process of applying to DI, which requires not working for a number of months, could reduce labor supply of rejected applicants. See the recent evidence by Autor et al. 2015 discussed in class. Even with these effects factored in however, the negative effect of DI on work remains relatively small. 2. The US social security system discourages labor supply of the elderly because a significant fraction of US workers stop working at age 62. This response is predicted by the standard life-cycle model. Solution: First part is true: there is a spike in retirement hazards at age 62 in the US that is driven by the early retirement age available at age 62 (nothing else changes at age 62 and this spike at 62 did not exist when the early retirement age was 65). Second part is false, if individuals were fully rational and as actuarial adjustment is close to fair, we should not observe a retirement spike at age 62. 3. The 2013 top tax rate increase in the United States led to a surge in reported top incomes in 2012 implying that tax rates on the rich have high efficiency costs. Solution: Empirical statement is true. We do observe a spike in 2012 top incomes (see Saez TPE 2017) due to retiming of income from 2013 to 2012 to escape the higher 2013 1

rates. The efficiency statement is in part false because large retiming does not necessarily imply that the long-term response will be large (indeed findings by Saez TPE 2017 suggest small longer term responses). For tax policies that last many years, the relevant response to judge efficiency costs is the long-term response. 4. Evidence from lottery winners show that there are substantial income effects on labor supply. Solution: Empirical evidence does show negative effects of lottery winnings on labor supply. Imbens et al. AER 2001 for the United States and Cesarini et al. 2015 for Sweden present compelling evidence comparing winners and non-winners conditional on playing. However, the magnitude of income effects is pretty small: $1 reduces earnings by about $0.1 so the empirical effects are not substantial. 5. If individuals with no earnings are considered as less deserving than average by society, then an EITC with negative marginal tax rates at the bottom of the income distribution would be optimal even in the traditional Mirrlees model of optimal taxation. Solution: This is true. The optimal tax rate at the bottom in the Mirrlees model takes the form T (0) = (g 0 1)/(g 0 1+e 0 ) with e 0 > 0 the elasticity of the fraction non-working wrt to 1 T (0) and g 0 the social marginal welfare weight on non workers. If individuals with no earnings are considered as less deserving than average by society, then g 0 < 1 and therefore T (0) < 0. Note that this result does not require responses along the extensive margin as in Saez QJE 02 (with extensive margin responses, T (0) < 0 can be obtained under weaker conditions: low income workers more deserving than average). 6. An rise in the ratio of aggregate wealth to national income always leads to a rise in the capital share of national income, which in turn, everything else equal, usually leads to an increase in income inequality. Solution: First part of the statement is false: this depends on the elasticity of substitution σ between capital and labor in production; the capital share rises if and only if σ > 1. The second part of the statement is true: because capital income is more unequally distributed than labor income, everything else equal a rise in the capital share tends to increase income inequality. 7. If the average rate of return to capital in the economy is 4%, an annual tax on wealth at a rate τ 1 = 1% is strictly equivalent to an annual tax on the flow of capital income at rate 2

τ 2 = 25%. Solution: False. The taxes τ 1 and τ 2 are equivalent for taxpayers who earn a rate of return of 4% on their wealth, but in practice there is significant heterogeneity in rates of returns across the distribution, due in particular to differences in portfolio composition. For taxpayers who have a rate of return different than 4%, the two taxes are different. 8. Formulary apportionment for the corporate income tax removes incentives for firms to move capital to low-tax countries. Solution: Generally speaking this is false: it depends on the apportionment factors used in the formula. If capital enters the formula then incentives to move capital to low tax countries remain. Sales-based apportionment removes any such incentive. 9. Evidence from random audit studies show that there is not a lot of tax evasion in rich countries, especially at the bottom and middle of the income distribution. Solution: True. Danish random audit studies find very low rates of evasion (tax gap of about 2.5%; see Kleven et al. 2011). US random audit studies find low levels of tax evasion too. The rates are blown up by a factor of about in the IRS tax gap studies but this factor is essentially arbitrary. Random audit studies, however, are not very informative about evasion at the top of the distribution as they miss sophisticated forms of evasion through legal and financial foreign intermediaries. 10. Because the US runs a trade deficit, a destination-based corporate cash-flow tax (DBCFT) would generate more revenue than the curent US corporate tax keeping the corporate tax rate unchanged. Solution: This is true in the short-run, but uncertain in the long-run. In present value terms the net trade balance of the US cannot be negative; therefore at some point the US will have to run a trade surplus, which would reduce the revenue from the DBCFT... unless the US is able to actually run persistent trade deficits (due, e.g., to a persistent returns differentials between US foreign assets and liabilities). 3

PROBLEM (30 pts): 2. Optimal Linear Income Taxation: Consider the following linear income tax problem. Individual utility is given by u(c, l) where c is consumption and l is labor supply. u(c, l) naturally increases with c and decreases with l. Each individual has an exogenous wage rate w distributed with density f(w) in the population (normalized to one). The minimum w is zero in the population. The government uses a linear tax with rate τ. Tax revenue is redistributed as a uniform lumpsum grant R (no other government expenses). Individuals choose labor supply l to maximize u(w l (1 τ) + R, l). Let us denote by l(w (1 τ), R) the Marshallian labor supply function. Let us denote by Z = wlf(w)dw aggregate earnings in the economy. In what follows a subscript denotes a partial derivative. a) (2 pts) Let us assume throughout this problem set that the uncompensated elasticity of labor supply is positive and that leisure is a normal good. Show that this implies that l increases with w (1 τ) and decreases with R. Solution: By definition, the uncompensated elasticity is e u = (w(1 τ)/l) l/ (w(1 τ)) so e u > 0 implies l increases with w(1 τ). If leisure is a normal good, then leisure increases with R which implies that labor supply decreases with R (income effect parameter η = w(1 τ) l/ R is negative or zero). b) (3 pts) Show that the government budget constraint is R = τ Z and that this defines R as an implicit function of τ. Show that R(τ = 0) = R(τ = 1) = 0 and that R(τ) > 0 when 0 < τ < 1. Plot R as a function of τ. Solution: Taxes collected are τz and fund R hence R = τz. From l(w(1 τ), R) we have that Z is a function of 1 τ and R. Hence R = τz(1 τ, R) defines R implicitly. R(τ = 0) = 0 Z(1, R) = 0. If τ = 1, then l = 0 (not worth working), and hence Z = 0 so that R = 0. If 0 < τ < 1 then l > 0 for those with w > 0. Hence, Z > 0 and R > 0. R(τ) is the inversely U-shaped Laffer curve. c) (3 pts) Using the fact from b) that R = τ Z is a function of τ, show that Z is an increasing function of 1 τ. 4

Solution: We have Z(1 τ) = l(w(1 τ), τz(1 τ))wf(w)dw. Hence Z (1 τ) = [wl w(1 τ) + ( Z + τz (1 τ))l R ]wf(w)dw [1 τl R wf(w)dw]z (1 τ) = [wl w(1 τ) Zl R ]wf(w)dw. l R < 0 and l w(1 τ) > 0 proves the result that Z (1 τ) > 0. d) (2 pts) Who is the worst off individual in this economy? What is the labor supply and utility of the worst off individual? Solution: The worst off individual has w = 0 and hence does not work l = 0 and has utility u(r, 0). e) (4 pts) Suppose the government is Rawlsian, i.e., government wants to maximize the utility of the worst off individual. Show that this implies that the government wants to set τ to maximize R. Find a formula for the optimal τ as a function of the elasticity e of aggregate earnings Z with respect to 1 τ. Solution: Maximizing the welfare u(r, 0) of the worst off individual is equivalent to maximizing R. Hence, the government chooses τ to maximize R = τz(1 τ). The FOC in τ is Z τz (1 τ) = 0 which can be rewritten as τz /Z = 1 or τ/(1 τ) e = 1 where e = (1 τ)z /Z is the elasticity. Hence, we have τ = 1/(1 + e). f) (4 pts) Suppose that the government is utilitarian and maximizes: W = u(w l (1 τ) + R, l)f(w)dw subject to R = τ Z. Derive the first order condition of the government program with respect to τ. Show that the optimal τ can be written as: τ 1 τ = 1 g, (1) e where g = w l u c f(w)dw/(z u c f(w)dw). Solution: The government chooses τ to maximize: 5

W = u(wl(1 τ) + τz(1 τ), l)f(w)dw Thanks to the envelope condition, l is optimized by the individual and hence can be ignored in the government FOC which can be written as: 0 = [ wl + Z τz (1 τ)]u c f(w)dw, which can be rewritten as: τ/(1 τ) (1 τ)z /Z u c f(w)dw = u c f(w)dw wlu c f(w)dw/z hence, using g = wlu c f(w)dw/(z u c f(w)dw), we have: τ 1 τ = 1 g. e g) (3 pts) Assuming that u(c, l) = u(c) v(l) with u(c) concave increasing and v(l) convex and increasing, show that u c decreases with w (for any tax rate τ). Show that this implies that 0 < g < 1 in question f). Solution: u c = u (c) = u (w(1 τ)l + R). As l increases with w(1 τ), we have w(1 τ)l + R increases with w, and hence (as u decreases), u c decreases with w. wl increases with w. Hence, wl and u c are negatively correlated, which implies that: g = E(wl u c )/E(wl)E(u c ) < 1 h) (3 pts) Assuming that u(c, l) = c v(l) with v(l) convex and increasing. Show that there are no income effects in labor supply in this case. What is the optimal utilitarian τ from question f) in that case? Explain the economic intuition. Solution: In this case u c = 1 for all individuals and hence g = 1 and hence τ = 0. With utility linear in consumption, everybody has the same marginal utility of consumption and hence there are no utilitarian benefits from redistributing from rich to poor. As taxes create efficiency costs (and no benefits), the optimal tax is zero. i) (3 pts) Suppose the government wants to estimate e in this economy using data on wage rates w i and labor supply l i for a small survey of individuals. Suppose that the economy is indeed exactly defined as in this problem set (i.e., this is NOT a real world question). What 6

labor supply parameter would a regression of log l i on log w i identify? Would this labor supply parameter be sufficient to provide an estimate of the elasticity e relevant for the optimal tax formula (1) from question f) above? Solution: The relationship between log l i on log w i captures the uncompensated elasticity of labor supply (changing w (1 τ) but keeping R fixed). The elasticity e also includes income effects (as R adjusts upwards to an increase in τ further reducing labor supply through income effects). Hence, e is larger than the uncompensated elasticity. j) (3 pts) In the set-up of question i), let us now assume that the government is Rawlsian as in question e). Would a regression of log l i on log w i identify the elasticity e relevant for the Rawlsian tax formula obtained in question e)? Solution: In the Rawlsian case however, e does not include income effects because at the Rawlsian optimum, the lumpsum R is maximized. Therefore, a small change in τ does not have a first order effect on R and hence generates a pure compensated effect. In fact, e = ē u where ē u is the average of the individual uncompensated labor supply elasticities e u (weighted by earnings). Hence, in the Rawlsian case, the analysis of the relationship between log l i on log w i captures the relevant elasticity e for tax policy. 7