Conditional convergence: how long is the long-run? Paul Ormerod. Volterra Consulting. April Abstract

Similar documents
Financial wealth of private households worldwide

Annuities: a private solution to longevity risk

New in 2013: Greater emphasis on capital flows Refinements to EBA methodology Individual country assessments

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

EVCA Private Equity Activity Survey 2007 Europe

International comparison of poverty amongst the elderly

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

T5-Europe The Jus Semper Global Alliance 01/09/16 1 6

2012 Canazei Winter Workshop on Inequality

Macroeconomics II. Growth. Recent phenomenon Great diversity of growth experiences across countries. Why do some countries grow and others not?

INTERIM MANAGEMENT STATEMENT QUARTER ENDED 30 SEPTEMBER 2010

2014 September. Trends in donor spending on gender in development. Introduction.

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July

Global Business Barometer April 2008

DETERMINANT FACTORS OF FDI IN DEVELOPED AND DEVELOPING COUNTRIES IN THE E.U.

The Velocity of Money and Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Developed and Latin-American Countries

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

BLS Spotlight on Statistics: International Labor Comparisons

Statistics Brief. OECD Countries Spend 1% of GDP on Road and Rail Infrastructure on Average. Infrastructure Investment. June

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Issue Brief for Congress

Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions

INTERIM MANAGEMENT STATEMENT QUARTER ENDED 30 SEPTEMBER 2011

Quarterly Investment Update First Quarter 2018

The Johns Hopkins Center for Civil Society Studies UN NONPROFIT HANDBOOK PROJECT. Lester M. Salamon

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

Global Economy is Expected to Grow by 3.4 % in 2016 GDP growth in 2016, %

Fiscal Policy and Income Inequality

SKEMA BUSINESS SCHOOL Global risk and the mounting wealth gap Michel Henry Bouchet

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

Implications of Increases in Life Expectancy for Policy

PREDICTING VEHICLE SALES FROM GDP

San Francisco Retiree Health Care Trust Fund Education Materials on Public Equity

COUNTRY COST INDEX JUNE 2013

International Trade: Mainstream and Heterodox Perspectives

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

Double-Taxing Capital Income: How Bad Is the Problem?

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

WikiLeaks Document Release

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

Turkey s Saving Deficit Issue From an Institutional Perspective

TAXATION OF TRUSTS IN ISRAEL. An Opportunity For Foreign Residents. Dr. Avi Nov

Developing Housing Finance Systems

ManpowerGroup Employment Outlook Survey Global

International Statistical Release

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

All-Country Equity Allocator February 2018

RECENT EVOLUTION AND OUTLOOK OF THE MEXICAN ECONOMY BANCO DE MÉXICO OCTOBER 2003

Capital Access Index 2006 Gauging Entrepreneurial Access to Capital

International Statistical Release

FCCC/SBI/2010/10/Add.1

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

The Economics of Public Health Care Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

Statistical Annex ANNEX

This DataWatch provides current information on health spending

No. 1. Key Economic Indicators. Bank Austria Economics & Market Analysis Austria

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

PREZENTĀCIJAS NOSAUKUMS

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

Currency Undervaluation: A Time-Tested Policy for Growth

Investment Newsletter

Economics Program Working Paper Series

Some Basic Facts about Government Expenditures and Taxation in Canada. Econ 525

OECD Health Policy Unit. 10 June, 2001

OECD HEALTH SYSTEM CHARACTERISTICS SURVEY 2012

ManpowerGroup Employment Outlook Survey UK

Travel Insurance and Assistance in the Asia-Pacific Region

HIGHLIGHTS 2016 OECD PERFORMANCE BUDGETING SURVEY: Integrating performance and results in budgeting

Indicator B3 How much public and private investment in education is there?

Top incomes and the shape of the upper tail

Comparative study of social expenditure in Japan and Korea

Quarterly Investment Update First Quarter 2017

No. 2. Key Economic Indicators. Bank Austria Economics & Market Analysis Austria

ManpowerGroup Employment Outlook Survey Finland

Internet Appendix to accompany Currency Momentum Strategies. by Lukas Menkhoff Lucio Sarno Maik Schmeling Andreas Schrimpf

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

A NOTE ON PUBLIC SPENDING EFFICIENCY

INTERIM MANAGEMENT STATEMENT QUARTER ENDED 31 MARCH April 2013

INTERIM MANAGEMENT STATEMENT QUARTER ENDED 31 MARCH 2012

6. CHALLENGES FOR REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT POLICY

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

No. 1. Key Economic Indicators. Bank Austria Economics & Market Analysis Austria

THE DETERMINANTS OF SECTORAL INWARD FDI PERFORMANCE INDEX IN OECD COUNTRIES

Global Consumer Confidence

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

Key Issues in the Design of Capital Gains Tax Regimes: Taxing Non- Residents. 18 July 2014

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

No. 2. Key Economic Indicators. Bank Austria Economics & Market Analysis Austria

IPD Global Annual Property Index launch 15 April 2013

Regional convergence in Spain:

10 GREAT MYTHS OF GLOBAL CIVIL SOCIETY

SADC Workshop on Statistics of International Trade in Services. FATS Compilation. Gaborone, Botswana January 2014

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

IFC / CWDI 2010 Report: Accelerating Board Diversity

Budget repair and the size of Australia s government. Melbourne Economic Forum John Daley, Grattan Institute December 2015

Transcription:

Conditional convergence: how long is the long-run? Paul Ormerod Volterra Consulting April 2003 pormerod@volterra.co.uk Abstract Mainstream theories of economic growth predict that countries across the world will converge in per capita income. This has not happened. The theory has been modified, hypothesises that conditional convergence takes place not across all countries, but within groups of countries which have similar political and cultural backgrounds. Much of the literature analyses data sets which cover short periods of just a few decades in the late 20 th century. This paper uses a much longer period, in particular 1820-1998. A wide range of countries is examined. The paper examines two concepts of convergence: the dispersion of incomes across countries at a point in time; the mobility of countries across time Even within the culturally homogenous group of countries which make up Western Europe, the time scale of convergence is of the order of 150 years from the spread of industrial capitalism some 200 years ago. Data sets which focus purely on the second half of the 20 th century alone will give a misleading picture of convergence. 1. Introduction The neo-classical growth model is still a widely used framework for analysing growth. Its proponents recognise that its prediction of convergence in per capita income has not been fulfilled across the world as a whole. The concept has therefore been developed of conditional convergence (for example, Mankiw et.al.1992, Hall and Jones 1999). In other words, growth in output per worker depends not just on capital per worker and technology, but on a wide range of factors such as the political and cultural system in which the economy operates. This concept implies that convergence will take place within countries which have similar 1

political and cultural backgrounds, but not necessarily otherwise. A phrase often used to describe the outcome of such a process is growth clubs. Much of the applied literature analyses data sets such as that of Summers and Heston (1988) which cover relatively short periods of at most three or four decades, and relate to the period after the Second World War. The aim of this paper is to examine the evidence for convergence over a much longer period, spanning the entire period over which capitalist organisation can be thought to have existed on any reasonable scale. Data for real per capita GDP over very long periods is provided by Maddison (2001). Section 2 discusses the data and the approach I adopt. Section 3 sets out the results, and section 4 gives a brief conclusion. 2. Data and methodology Maddison (1995) provides estimates of real per capita GDP in 1990 dollars for a large range of countries since the early 19 th century. Recently, he has extended this further back, providing estimates as far back as 1500, and even before then, for a selected group of countries. The precise date at which the capitalist mode of production began to develop and spread is open to argument, but it cannot realistically be placed earlier than 1500. Modest increases in per capita GDP are estimated to have taken place during the 16 th century in most of Western Europe, with the Netherlands rising by 80 per cent. Growth continued slowly during the 17 th century, with the Netherlands again and to some extent the UK showing historically very large increases. During the 18 th century, the capitalist mode of production strengthened considerably in Western Europe and its offshoots in North America. By the early nineteenth century, manufacturing had already overtaken agriculture as the largest sector of the UK economy, for example. 2

I begin by calculating measures of convergence amongst the countries of Western Europe, which have had very similar cultural and historical backgrounds for a very long period. Maddison provides data for the years 1500, 1600, 1700, 1820, 1870, 1913, 1950, 1973 and 1998 for the following countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland and the UK. These countries account for almost the entire GDP of Western Europe I examine two distinct, though related, concepts of convergence: the dispersion, or spread, of incomes across countries at a point in time the mobility, or change of position, of countries across time I calculate dispersion for each of the years given by Maddison. Mobility is estimated a range of periods. To examine this issue, I regress growth in each country over a given period of time against the per capita income levels at the start of the relevant period. Convergence implies that the coefficient in the regression is negatively signed (for example, Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992). Initially, I estimate mobility over the periods 1500-1600, 1500-1700, 1500-1820, 1500-1913 and 1500-1998. The base year is advanced to 1600, and 1600-1700, 1600-1820, 1600-1913 and 1600-1998 are estimated. Finally, the base year is advanced to 1700, 1820 and 1913 respectively. I then examine in finer detail the period in which industrial capitalism has been established unequivocally, namely 1820-1998. Taking the base year 1820, I estimate mobility for each of the possible periods in Maddison s data, namely 1820-1870, 1820-1913, 1820-1950, 1820-1973 and 1820-1998. Again, the base year is moved on to 1870, 1913 and so on, and each possible period is examined. The next step is then, again within the period of unequivocal capitalism namely 1820-1998, to add to the data set countries or areas in the Maddison data, in order of 3

their closeness to Western Europe in terms of cultural and historical backgrounds. Details are provided in section 3 below. 3. The results 3.1 Dispersion of income at a point in time Table 1 sets out information on the dispersion of real GDP per capita across Western Europe on each of the dates for which Maddison provides estimates. In terms of dispersion, I examine: the ratio of highest income to the lowest the ratio of the inter-quartile range the coefficient of variation Information is also set out for the Western Europe average per capita GDP. Table 1 Dispersion of real per capita GDP across 14 countries of Western Europe Date Max/Min Inter-quartile Coefficient of Average real ratio ratio variation GDP per capita 1990 US $ 1500 2.43 1.09 0.19 774 1600 2.54 1.21 0.21 894 1700 3.30 1.21 0.32 1024 1820 2.33 1.19 0.22 1232 1870 3.20 1.49 0.34 1974 1913 3.96 1.60 0.31 3473 1950 4.38 1.75 0.38 4594 1973 2.48 1.18 0.21 11534 1998 1.83 1.12 0.15 17921 Dispersion has clearly moved in an irregular fashion: 4

the widening in the 17 th century and subsequent narrowing 1700-1820 is mainly due to the rise and temporary decline of the Netherlands dispersion widened dramatically over the 1820-1950 period 1 the narrowing of dispersion is a feature of the second half of the 20 th century as late as 1973, dispersion was similar to that obtaining in 1820 The evidence shows that even within a group of countries with very similar cultural and historical backgrounds, the concept of the long-run in practice appears to be very long-run indeed. It seems to be at least 150 years, the length of time from the start of the unequivocal capitalist take-off in per capita incomes in 1820 through to 1973, and could arguably be thought of as even longer. 3.2 Mobility of income over time There is a fairly wide range of permutations of periods available, but I examine growth from 1500, 1600, 1700, 1820 and 1913. The year 1820 is unequivocally at the beginning of the period of take-off into industrial growth rates, and per capita incomes in 1913 describe the outcome of the first century of unequivocal capitalist development. Table 2. Regression of the difference of the logs of per capita income on the level of per capita income, 1990 US dollars 000s, at the start of the period 14 Western European countries, 1500-1998 Period Coefficient T-statistic R 2 (absolute) 1500-1600 -0.026 0.98 0.074 1500-1700 -0.044 0.99 0.075 1 the 1950 figures are not really distorted by the war. Every country except Germany (1953) had exceeded its pre-war 1938 level of real GDP per capita by 1950 5

1500-1820 -0.075 * 2.06 0.262 1500-1913 -0.058 0.84 0.056 1500-1998 -0.124 ** 3.84 0.552 1600-1700 +0.023 1.59 0.174 1600-1820 -0.019 1.00 0.077 1600-1913 -0.026 0.53 0.023 1600-1998 -0.099 ** 3.96 0.567 1700-1820 -0.023 ** 3.38 0.487 1700-1913 -0.024 0.93 0.067 1700-1998 -0.064 ** 4.83 0.661 1820-1913 +0.019 0.72 0.041 1820-1998 -0.057 ** 3.67 0.529 1913-1998 -0.026 ** 8.52 0.858 Note: * indicates significantly different from zero at 5 per cent level (one-tail) ** indicates significantly different from zero at 1 per cent level (one-tail) The table again shows the decisive role of the most recent period of capitalism in Western Europe in the convergence process. Essentially, even within this group of countries with very similar cultural backgrounds, we can only really speak of convergence if the data for the 20 th century is included. Convergence did not take place during the first century of industrial capitalism, namely the 19 th. 6

Table 3 looks more finely at the 1820-1913 period. Table 3. Regression of the difference of the logs of per capita income on the level of per capita income, 1990 US dollars 000s, at the start of the period 14 Western European countries, 1820-1998 Period Coefficient T-statistic R 2 (absolute) 1820-1870 +0.031 * 1.91 0.233 1820-1913 +0.019 0.72 0.041 1820-1950 +0.007 0.19 0.003 1820-1973 -0.045 * 2.23 0.293 1820-1998 -0.057 ** 3.67 0.529 1870-1913 -0.002 0.26 0.006 1870-1950 -0.009 0.69 0.038 7

1870-1973 -0.034 ** 5.05 0.681 1870-1998 -0.041 ** 7.50 0.824 1913-1950 -0.004 0.49 0.019 1913-1973 -0.020 ** 5.56 0.681 1913-1998 -0.026 ** 8.55 0.858 1950-1973 -0.011 ** 7.68 0.831 1950-1998 -0.015 ** 14.40 0.945 1973-1998 -0.004 ** 3.69 0.532 Note: * indicates significantly different from zero at 5 per cent level (one-tail) ** indicates significantly different from zero at 1 per cent level (one-tail) Table shows that data during the second half of the 20 th century needs to be included in the sample before convergence can be said to have taken place within Western Europe. As with the evidence on the spread of incomes at a point in time, the long run appears to be of the order of 150 years. We can examine the robustness of results when the sample of countries is extended. Maddison provides information on the United States, other Western offshoots (essentially, Canada, Australia and New Zealand), Eastern Europe, Russia (the former USSR), Latin America, Japan, China, India, other Asia and Africa. Cultural and historical similarities between countries or groups of countries are not given to precise analysis. But the two Maddison areas most closely linked in this respect to Western Europe are obviously the United States and other Western offshoots. Not surprisingly, the inclusion of these makes no qualitative difference to the results. For example, over the 1820-1998 period, the estimated coefficient in the regression is 0.065 with a t-statistic of 3.97 when these two observations are included, compared to the 0.057 and -3.67 reported above when Western European countries only are included. 8

The countries of Eastern Europe, excluding Russia but including Poland, the Czech Republic and Hungary, have very long cultural and historical links with Western Europe. Maddison groups these into a single data set, Eastern Europe. The inclusion of just this single additional variable begins to weaken the evidence for convergence. For example, in Table 3, with all 9 periods which end in either 1973 or 1998, the coefficient in the regression is significantly different from zero at p = 0.05 and is correctly signed. These are the only periods for which this is the case. However, when the Eastern European variable is added to the Western European countries, only 6 out of these 9 remain significant and correctly signed. The periods 1820-1973, 1820-1998 and 1973-1998 give coefficients which are not significantly different from zero even at p = 0.10. Tables 4a and b summarises the effect of including further variables on the nine sample periods in which the coefficient in the regression is correctly signed and significantly different from zero at p = 0.05. Russia has had links with the West over many centuries, and Latin America has had close connections for over 400 years. India was the major part of the British Empire, and its elite use English quite naturally. Table 4a. Significance of the coefficient in the regression of the difference of the logs of per capita income on the level of per capita income, 1990 US dollars 000s, at the start of the period. All Maddison periods ending in 1973 Country 1820-1973 1870-1973 1913-1973 1950-1973 /period Western Europe * * * * plus US and Western * * * * offshoots 9

plus Eastern Europe * * * plus Russia * * * plus Latin America * * * plus India full sample of countries Note: * indicates correctly signed and statistically significant from zero at p = 0.05 row 1 is the 14 countries of Western Europe; row 2 is the 14 countries of Western Europe plus the US and Western offshoots, etc. The coefficient is correctly signed and significant for all periods when the data set includes either just Western Europe, or Western Europe plus the US and Western offshoots. However, the coefficient is not significant 1820-1973 when Eastern Europe alone, and Eastern Europe plus Russia are included. The same result holds when Latin America is added. However, the addition of India alone leads the coefficient to become not significant in all four periods. Table 4b. Significance of the coefficient in the regression of the difference of the logs of per capita income on the level of per capita income, 1990 US dollars 000s, at the start of the period. All Maddison periods ending in 1998 Country 1820-1998 1870-1998 1913-1998 1950-1998 1973-98 /period Western Europe * * * * * plus US and Western * * * * * offshoots plus Eastern Europe * * * 10

plus Russia plus Latin America plus India full sample Note: * indicates correctly signed and statistically significant from zero at p = 0.05 row 1 is the 14 countries of Western Europe; row 2 is the 14 countries of Western Europe plus the US and Western offshoots, etc. Over the longer period ending in 1998 the evidence of convergence over wider data sets is much weaker. As with the period ending in 1973, the addition of Eastern Europe leads the relevant coefficient to become insignificant for some of the periods. But the simple addition of Russia to the data set leads to the coefficient becoming insignificant in each of the relevant periods. 4 Conclusion The neo-classical growth model is still a widely used framework for analysing growth. Its proponents recognise that its prediction of convergence in per capita income has not been fulfilled across the world as a whole. The concept has therefore been developed of conditional convergence. In other words, growth in output per worker depends not just on capital per worker and technology, but on a wide range of factors such as the political and cultural system in which the economy operates. This concept implies that convergence will take place within countries which have similar political and cultural backgrounds, but not necessarily otherwise. Much of the applied literature uses relatively short data sets which include data purely from the second half of the 20 th century. In this paper, I examine convergence using a much longer data set, beginning as early as 1500. 11

I examine two aspects of convergence: the dispersion of per capita income at a point in time, and mobility in per capita income over time. I focus initially on 14 countries in Western Europe, which have very close cultural and historical links. On both measures of convergence, evidence for convergence only exists if data for the second half of the 20 th century is included in the sample. A range of periods over which convergence can be calculated is available in the primary data source, beginning in 1500 and ending in 1998. But it is only the inclusion of the most recent fifty years of data which generates evidence of convergence. I then focus more closely on the 1820-1998 period and various sub-periods within this. The addition of the data for the United States and Western offshoots (Australia, Canada, New Zealand) makes no qualitative difference to the results. Both these areas have had strong historical connections with Western Europe. But the addition of data for Eastern Europe (excluding Russia), which has also had strong cultural links with Western Europe, begins to weaken the evidence for convergence. And over the full sample period, 1820-1998, the inclusion of Russia in the data set removes the evidence supporting the concept of convergence. Even within the culturally homogenous group of countries which make up Western Europe, the time scale of convergence in per capita incomes appears to be of the order of at least 150 years from the general spread of industrial capitalism some 200 years ago. Data sets which focus on the second half of the 20 th century alone will therefore tend to give a misleading picture of convergence, because it is only during this period that convergence can be said to have taken place in any meaningful sense. For much of the history of capitalism, even within Western Europe, evidence for the existence of convergence is at best weak and at worst non-existent. References N.G.Mankiw, D.Romer and D.N.Weil, 1992, A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 408-437 12

R.E.Hall and C.I.Jones, 1999, Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83-116 R.Summers and A.Heston, 1988, A New Set of International Comparisons of Real Product and Price Levels Estimates for 130 Countries, 1950-1985, Review of Income and Wealth, 1-25. A. Maddison, 2002, The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective, OECD, Paris Robert J. Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 1992, Convergence, Journal of Political Economy, 223-251 13