Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1

Similar documents
Has the Inflation Process Changed?

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

A measure of supercore inflation for the eurozone

Monetary Policy in Euroland

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Assessing integration of EU banking sectors using lending margins

HOUSEHOLDS LENDING MARKET IN THE ENLARGED EUROPE. Debora Revoltella and Fabio Mucci copyright with the author New Europe Research

Themes Income and wages in Europe Wages, productivity and the wage share Working poverty and minimum wage The gender pay gap

The Yield Curve as a Predictor of Economic Activity the Case of the EU- 15

Private and public risk-sharing in the euro area

Recent developments and challenges for the Portuguese economy

Optimum Monetary Policy in European Monetary Union

November 5, Very preliminary work in progress

Inflation Differentials in the Euro Area

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

Business cycle volatility and country zize :evidence for a sample of OECD countries. Abstract

Is harmonization sufficient?

The Stability and Growth Pact Status in 2001

Bank Loan Officers Expectations for Credit Standards: evidence from the European Bank Lending Survey

Use of survey data Inflation perceptions: a cross country analysis

Revista Economică 69:4 (2017) TOWARDS SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT: REAL CONVERGENCE AND GROWTH IN ROMANIA. Felicia Elisabeta RUGEA 1

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Filling the gap: open economy considerations for more reliable potential output estimates

Inflation Differentials among the Euro Area Countries: Potential Causes and Consequences

Real Exchange Rate Movements and Endogenous OCA Analysis: Lessons from the Euro Area for Asia

Determinants of intra-euro area government bond spreads during the financial crisis

Cyclical Convergence and Divergence in the Euro Area

Bank Contagion in Europe

Mind the Gap: Disentangling Credit and Liquidity in Risk Spreads *

INFLATION TARGETING AND INDIA

Irish Retail Interest Rates: Why do they differ from the rest of Europe?

This presentation. Downward wage rigidity in EU countries. Based on recent papers on wage rigidity in European countries:

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

International Summer Program June 26 th to July 17 th, 2006

Inflation and competitiveness divergences in the euro area countries:

II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SITUATION ON THE LABOUR MARKET IN EUROPEAN UNION MEMBER COUNTRIES

YOUTH UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE EURO AREA

An Estimated Fiscal Taylor Rule for the Postwar United States. by Christopher Phillip Reicher

Are inflation expectations differently formed when countries are part of a Monetary Union?

Taylor rules for CEE-EU countries: How much heterogeneity?

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

Macroeconomic Policies in Europe: Quo Vadis A Comment

The gains from variety in the European Union

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

The Velocity of Money and Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Developed and Latin-American Countries

Analysis of European Union Economy in Terms of GDP Components

Can the euro still be saved? Morning session: the threats

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. How Far From the Euro Area? Measuring Convergence of Inflation Rates in Eastern Europe

Time-varying wage Phillips curves in the euro area with a new measure for labor market slack

School of Economics and Management

ARE LEISURE AND WORK PRODUCTIVITY CORRELATED? A MACROECONOMIC INVESTIGATION

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Survey on the access to finance of enterprises in the euro area. October 2014 to March 2015

Monetary and Fiscal Policy

IS READY ROMANIA FOR EURO ADOPTION? FROM STRUCTURAL CONVERGENCE TO BUSINESS CYCLE SYNCHRONIZATION

The Bilateral J-Curve: Sweden versus her 17 Major Trading Partners

Mergers & Acquisitions in Banking: The effect of the Economic Business Cycle

IS THERE ANY PREFERED COMPETITIVENESS INDICATOR IN EXPLAINING FOREING TRADE IN EURO AREA COUNTRIES? COMPNET December 12 th 2013

PUBLIC FINANCE IN THE EU: FROM THE MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA TO THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT

THE TRADEOFF BETWEEN EFFICIENCY AND MACROECONOMIC STABILIZATION

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

International Income Smoothing and Foreign Asset Holdings.

Monetary Policy, Financial Stability and Interest Rate Rules Giorgio Di Giorgio and Zeno Rotondi

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Portfolio Diversification : Alive and well in Euroland!

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade

Potential value of processing of telecom metadata for the European economy

to 4 per cent annual growth in the US.

Estimating and forecasting using simple fiscal rules for euro area countries

Exchange Rate Pass-through in India

Schwerpunkt Außenwirtschaft 2016/17 Austrian economic activity, Austria's price competitiveness and a summary on external trade

Survey on the Access to Finance of Enterprises in the euro area. April to September 2017

DATA SET ON INVESTMENT FUNDS (IVF) Naming Conventions

Taylor Rule and Macroeconomic Performance: The Case of Pakistan

Monetary Transmission in Simple Backward-Looking Models: The IS Puzzle

46 ECB FISCAL CHALLENGES FROM POPULATION AGEING: NEW EVIDENCE FOR THE EURO AREA

Exchange-Rate and Interest-Rate Driven Competitive Advantages in the EMU

Elisabetta Basilico and Tommi Johnsen. Disentangling the Accruals Mispricing in Europe: Is It an Industry Effect? Working Paper n.

Are All Sovereigns Equal? A Test of the Common Determination of Sovereign Spreads in the Euro Area

EFFECT OF GENERAL UNCERTAINTY ON EARLY AND LATE VENTURE- CAPITAL INVESTMENTS: A CROSS-COUNTRY STUDY. Rajeev K. Goel* Illinois State University

The Eurozone (Some Thoughts about the Long Term Dynamic Forces in the EMU)

1. a. The accompanying table shows each nation s real GDP per capita in terms of its. per capita per capita. Percentage of 1960 real GDP per capita

In 2009 a 6.5 % rise in per capita social protection expenditure matched a 6.1 % drop in EU-27 GDP

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

Volume 31, Issue 1. Florence Huart University Lille 1

A Cross Country Empirical Analysis of Inflation Persistence. Fernando N. de Oliveira 1 (Central Bank of Brazil and IBMEC/RJ)

May 2009 Euro area annual inflation down to 0.0% EU down to 0.7%

Is There a Relationship between Company Profitability and Salary Level? A Pan-European Empirical Study

Common Macroeconomic Shocks and Business Cycle Fluctuations in Euro Area Countries. Antonella Cavallo and Antonio Ribba*

Fiscal Reaction Functions of Different Euro Area Countries

Exchange Rates and Inflation under EMU: An Update

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

Transcription:

Exchange Rates and Inflation in EMU Countries: Preliminary Empirical Evidence 1 Marco Moscianese Santori Fabio Sdogati Politecnico di Milano, piazza Leonardo da Vinci 32, 20133, Milan, Italy Abstract In this paper we assess the role of exchange rate changes in the determination of national inflation rates for EMU member countries. Furthermore, we argue that the reaction of the national inflation rate is different across countries, and that three groups can be identified within the EMU with respect to this reaction: fast adjustment, slow adjustment, no adjustment. These findings are consistent with other findings in the recent empirical literature on inflation convergence in the EMU. 1. Introduction The aim of this paper is to provide empirical evidence on the (differential) effects of exchange rate movements on national inflation rates of European Monetary Union countries. While there is widespread acceptance, both from the theoretical and empirical point of view, on the proposition that Euro depreciation positively affects aggregate inflation in the EMU, only recent preliminary empirical work has explicitly tackled the issue of whether and to what extent such a disturbance can cause different effects in different countries within the Monetary Union. As it is shown in figure 1 2, the aggregate EMU inflation rate hides important differences among individual members of the MU. If we allow for an initial period of adjustment (immediately following the birth of the MU), in which the Euro depreciated sharply, Corresponding author. Tel.: +39 02 2399 2758; fax: +39 02 2399 2710. Email address: marco.moscianese@polimi.it (Marco Moscianese Santori). 1 We thank Filippo Spazzini for useful comments. 2 The figure shows the 12-period moving average of annualized month-on-month inflation rates for the EMU (computed as the simple average of the eleven countries considered in this paper, i.e. all members except Luxembourg and Slovenia) and three individual members against the percentage month-on-month change in Euro/Dollar nominal exchange rate, smoothed in the same way. Preliminary Comments welcome JEL classification: E31, F41

Fig. 1. Inflation rates and Euro/Dollar exchange rate changes (a) EMU (b) Germany (c) Ireland (d) France while inflation rose sensibly after having dropped during the preceding years, we can see that the aggregate inflation rate [fig. 1(a)] has been following with a lag the movements of the Euro/Dollar exchange rate ever since. However, this aggregate behavior is the result of different underlying movements of the individual inflation rates: in most member countries, the inflation rate does follow Euro/Dollar movements, although the adjustment may be quick [fig. 1(b)] as well as very slow [fig. 1(c)]; conversely, in some other cases, the inflation rate seems to behave independently of exchange rate movements, as it happens in France [fig. 1(d)]. A recent strand of empirical literature has investigated the issue of inflation convergence/divergence [Angeloni and Ehrmann (2004), Busetti et al. (2006)], but few papers explicitly posit the existence of a relationship between the valuation of the Euro (either against the Dollar, or in effective terms) and inflation differentials (Honohan and Lane, 2003, 2005). The theoretical tools we have for explaining the influence that exchange rates exert upon consumer price inflation, and hence upon inflation differentials in the EMU, are abundant, ranging from purchasing power parity (PPP) and the closely connected monetary approach, to the Norwegian model as presented by Aukrust (1977), to the New Keynesian open-economy Phillips curve 3. 3 For an excellent survey, see Kara and Nelson (2003). 2

In a much cited paper, Svensson (2000) has listed three channels through which the exchange rate can affect consumer price inflation: the direct channel, i.e. the presence of imported final goods in the consumer price index; the additional aggregate demand channel, arising from the sensitivity of the trade balance to the exchange rate; the imported intermediate input (III) channel, arising from the impact of the exchange rate on domestic production costs, in an internationally integrated production process. It is this latter channel that is of particular interest to us, as it could account for much of the diversity we observe within the EMU. The relevance of the issue notwithstanding, formal models of this channel lack somewhat in the literature. A notable example is McCallum and Nelson (1999), where imports are included as an input in the production function, thereby allowing for an effect of the exchange rate on production costs. This paper is part of a larger research project, involving empirical as well as theoretical developments, in which the relevance of the productive specialization of countries, and their role in the internationally fragmented production process, will be emphasized in relation to both real and nominal variables. In the present study, we start focusing our attention on the supply side of the economy, by estimating a simple form of the Phillips curve for eleven EMU countries, in which the exchange rate enters as an exogenous variable. Section 2 presents the model and the data set used. In section 3 the empirical results are discussed and some economic considerations proposed. In section 4 we draw some conclusions and suggest directions of further research. 2. Empirical model and data issues The aim of our empirical model is to assess the effects of exchange rate variations on the individual inflation rates of EMU countries. We estimate the following system of eleven 4 equations for the inflation rates: π it = α + β 1i e t 2 + β 2i e t 4 + β 3i e t 8 + β 4i oil t + β 5i gap i(t 1) + ε it (1) where π it is the annualized quarter-on-quarter inflation rate for country i between quarters t and t 1; e t and oil t are, respectively, the percentage changes in the Euro/Dollar exchange rate and in oil price between quarters t and t 1; gap it is the output gap for country i in quarter t, expressed in percentage points with respect to potential output, and ε it is a disturbance term. The series for inflation rates, exchange rate and oil price have been smoothed using a 4-period moving average, to adjust for seasonality. The inflation rate is calculated from the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices 5. The output gap has been computed using a Hodrick-Prescott filter from the seasonally adjusted quarterly real output. The series span from 1999:q1 to 2006:q4, i.e. for the whole part of the life of the EMU for which data are available. All data are from the ECB Statistical Data Warehouse. 4 All countries in the Monetary Union ] are considered, except Luxembourg and Slovenia. 5 π it = 100 [ ( HICP it HICP i(t 1) ) 4 1. 3

Model (1) is a system of equations where all regressors are the same across countries, except for the output gap, which is a country-specific variable. This system can be estimated using Zellner s seemingly unrelated regression estimation method. Each equation of the model can be seen as a Phillips curve to which the nominal exchange rate has been added. This differs somewhat from what is done by Svensson (2000), who includes the real exchange rate in his Phillips curve specification. In fact, looking at the ratio between the consumer price indexes during the last seven years, one can be easily convinced that changes in the nominal Euro/Dollar exchange rate are tantamount to real changes. Furthermore, we are more interested here in assessing whether and to what extent nominal exchange rate changes spill into domestic inflation (see section 1). Some authors (see, for example, Favero and Rovelli, 2003), control for some commodity price index in their Phillips curve specification, as we also do here by including the change in the oil price. This control variable is not lagged, as the effect of energy prices on the consumer price index can safely be assumed to be quite fast 6. Conversely, the output gap appears with one lag, as the effect of this variable is generally slower. 3. Empirical results The results of our estimation are shown in table 1 7. The point estimates of the coefficients are reported, along with the associated p-values. For each equation, the R-squared associated with the regression is reported in the last column. As for the standard, or closed economy part of the Phillips curve, the results seem to fit both the theory and reality well: the coefficients for oil inflation are generally positive and significant; the coefficients for the national output gaps are generally negative as expected, albeit not always significant; finally, the constant terms are not far from what can be reasonably believed to be the average inflation rate for each country, clearly separating lower inflation countries (such as Germany and Finland) from higher inflation countries (such as Greece and Ireland). Turning to the exchange rate part of the model, we can observe some interesting facts. First, consistently with the theory (be it the purchasing power parity, the monetary model, or one of Svensson s three channels), we observe that, in general, a depreciation of the common currency translates into higher inflation. This is also consistent with what is empirically observed for the aggregate EMU inflation rate 8. 6 As it is explained in the next section, we also tried different lag structures to assess the robustness of our estimates. One alternative specification included the change in oil prices lagged one quarter. 7 The results shown here have proven to be fairly robust to specification changes: we estimated the model imposing different lag structures on the exchange rate part, by lagging the oil price change one period, by lagging the output gap two periods instead of one. We also estimated a similar SUR system using monthly data (excluding the output gap from the specification), thereby providing an informal check for robustness to sample size, which is admittedly quite small in the estimation presented here. Finally, we estimated VAR models for some of the countries individually (using monthly data on inflation rates, the exchange rate and oil price)), and observed a dynamic response consistent with what is intuitively discussed here. 8 This can be seen by estimating a single regression with the EMU inflation rate as the dependent variable, or by estimating a VAR model of the EMU inflation rate, the exchange rate change and the oil price inflation. In the latter case, some insights on the dynamics of adjustment can be obtained (see below). 4

Table 1 SUR estimation results. π at 1.9089 π be 2.1339 π de 1.7122 π es 3.2685 π fi 1.4702 π fr 1.8885 π gr 3.5813 π ie 3.3165 π it 2.3868 π nl 3.0562 α β 1i β 2i β 3i β 4i β 5i R 2 21.489 12.947 (0.045) 13.691 (0.010) 4.9032 (0.324) 13.926 (0.013) 8.7661 (0.013) 1.8485 (0.563) 14.604 (0.015) 2.5133 (0.334) 8.0817 (0.252).56672 (0.913) 4.3310 (0.517) 2.4455 (0.626) 6.8580 (0.136) 37.704 1.3609 (0.704) 10.416 (0.002) 26.8875.17708 (0.946) 29.388 5.6365 (0.143) 9.4244 (0.035) 3.0434 (0.374) 5.2415 (0.109) 4.0499 (0.240) 7.0122 (0.004) 5.7855 (0.012) 22.699 13.102 11.749 (0.004) 4.8317 (0.011) 3.8980 (0.107) 4.0205 (0.030) 9.4150 3.5156 (0.059) 3.9365 (0.003) 2.3264 (0.061) 3.8758 (0.097) 2.7289 (0.005) 2.1425 (0.331) π pt 3.3581 13.566 (0.114) 2.7664 (0.746) 17.530 (0.003) 1.2341 (0.703) P-values associated with the coefficient estimates are shown in parentheses..58878.15372 (0.106).02949 (0.756).42928 (0.039).27582.15952 (0.062).02382 (0.563).06894 (0.047).24615 (0.004).00713 (0.964).2484 (0.078) 0.4505 0.5486 0.6099 0.6958 0.8557 0.5425 0.7603 0.8479 0.6778 0.9217 0.5856 Second, our eleven countries can be subdivided roughly into three categories, with respect to their inflation rate s reaction to exchange rate changes: one group, for which the inflation rate reacts quickly (the β 2i coefficient is big and highly significant), containing Austria, Belgium and Germany; another group in which inflation rates do adjust, but with a longer lag (one or two years), consisting on Greece, Ireland, Netherlands, Portugal 9 ; finally, a third group includes those countries for which an adjustment does not seem to occur (the coefficients associated with the exchange rate change are not statistically significant or of the wrong sign), such as France and Spain 10. Third, we can notice that countries belonging to the fast adjustment group can also be classified as lower inflation countries (low values of the constant term), while those belonging to the slow adjustment group have significantly higher average inflation rates 11. Busetti et al. (2006) have studied the properties of inflation convergence / divergence whithin the EMU, independently of the exchange rate, identifying two convergence clubs, i.e. two clusters of countries showing statistically different behavior. They label 9 Finland may be thought of as belonging either to the first or second group. A more detailed dynamical analysis should be conducted to fully characterize the dynamics and speed of adjustment. 10 Again, there is an ambiguous case. Italy could be seen as belonging either to the second or third group: while the coefficient estimates would point toward the second group, visual inspection of the time series reveals a behavior that is more similar to that showed by France and Spain. 11 Given the very high significance of the constant term, confidence intervals around the point estimates are quite narrow, so that the discrimination between low inflation and high inflation countries is straightforward. 5

the two clubs high inflation and low inflation. Very interestingly, their clubs coincide roughly with our slow adjustment and fast adjustment groups 12. Parallely, Honohan and Lane (2003, 2005) believe that convergence/divergence of inflation rates within the EMU is closely related to exchange rate movements. The present paper could well serve as a connection between the latter two studies, in the same line of research, by suggesting one possible explanation for the different behavior of Busetti et al. s clusters: the differences in the dynamics of inflation rates within the European Monetary Union may be due, in part, to the different ways exchange rate shocks are transmitted to the inflation rate. 4. Concluding remarks and further directions of research In this paper we estimated a system of eleven equations relating national EMU inflation rates to changes in the Euro/Dollar exchange rate and found robust, albeit preliminary, empirical evidence of a significant effect of exchange rate changes upon national inflation rates of EMU member countries. Furthermore, we argued that this effect is different across countries, and that these countries can be classified in three groups with respect to their behavior: the fast adjustment group, the slow adjustment group and the no adjustment group. We also argued that our findings are consistent with other findings in the recent empirical literature, namely those by Honohan and Lane (2003, 2005) and Busetti et al. (2006). Further research is needed both on the theoretical and the empirical side. From the theoretical point of view, the influence of the exchange rate on price levels and inflation rates through the imported intermediate input needs to be modeled carefully. This could help explain the observed clustering of EMU members (with respect to their reaction to nominal shocks) with their different productive specialization, i.e., with their structural characteristics. From the empirical point of view, of the many ways in which this line of research could be carried further on, we suggest two. 1) A similar study should be conducted at a disaggregated level, seeking to exclude imported final goods from the price indexes considered, in order to isolate the imported intermediate input channel; and 2) the dynamics of adjustment still need to be fully characterized, in order for the empirical evidence on the relationship between exchange rates and inflation to be regarded as convincing. References Angeloni, I. and M. Ehrmann, 2004 Euro Area inflation differentials, ECB Working Paper no. 388 Aukrust, O., 1977, Inflation in the open economy: A Norwegian model, in L. B. Krause and W. S. Salant (eds), Worldwide Inflation Theory and Recent Experience, The Brookings Institution 12 Of course, we have a third group: in the classification of Busetti et al., Spain belongs to the first club, France to the second. In their analysis, as in ours, Italy shows an ambiguous behavior. As for Finland, it clearly belongs to the low inflation club. 6

Busetti, F., L. Forni, A. Harvey and F. Venditti, 2006, Inflation convergence and divergence within the European Monetary Union, ECB Working Paper no. 574 Favero, C. and R. Rovelli, 2003, Macroeconomic stability and the preferences of the Fed: A Formal Analysis, 1961 98, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 35 (4), 545 556 Honohan, P. and P. R. Lane, 2003, Divergent inflation rates in the EMU, Economic Policy 18 (37), 357 394 Honohan, P. and P. R. Lane, 2005, Exchange rates and inflation under the EMU: An update, Institute for International Integration Studies Discussion Paper no. 31 Kara, A. and E. Nelson, 2003, The exchange rate and inflation in the UK, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 50 (5), 585 607 McCallum, B. T. and E. Nelson, 1999, Nominal income targeting in an open-economy optimizing model, Journal of Monetary Economics 43, 553 578 Svensson, Lars E. O., 2000, Open-economy inflation targeting, Journal of International Economics 50, 155 183 7