The impact of information sharing on the. use of collateral versus guarantees

Similar documents
Show Me Yours and I ll Show You Mine: Sharing Borrower Information in a Competitive Credit Market *

Does Collateral Reduce Overdues? A Regression Discontinuity Approach

The Changing Role of Small Banks. in Small Business Lending

06RT17. SME Collateral: risky borrowers or risky behaviour? James Carroll and Fergal McCann

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Bank Competition, Concentration, and Credit Reporting

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Book Review of The Theory of Corporate Finance

The usual disclaimer applies. The opinions are those of the discussant only and in no way involve the responsibility of the Bank of Italy.

THE IMPACT OF THE RECENT FINANCIAL CRISIS ON BANK LOAN INTEREST RATES AND GUARANTEES

Why Do Companies Choose to Go IPOs? New Results Using Data from Taiwan;

Collateralization of Loans: Testing the Prediction of Theories

ABSTRACT. Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): ISSN(p): DOI: /journal.aefr Vol. 9, No.

Information sharing, credit market competition and loan performance

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Financial Market Structure and SME s Financing Constraints in China

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

Investment and Financing Policies of Nepalese Enterprises

Discussion Paper No. 593

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov

Microfinance at the margin: Experimental evidence from Bosnia í Herzegovina

The effect of information asymmetries among lenders on syndicated loan prices

Financial Innovation and Borrowers: Evidence from Peer-to-Peer Lending

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

The Effect of New Mortgage-Underwriting Rule on Community (Smaller) Banks Mortgage Activity

Financial liberalization and the relationship-specificity of exports *

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

by Sankar De and Manpreet Singh

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Craft Lending: The Role of Small Banks in Small Business Finance

Internet Appendix to Broad-based Employee Stock Ownership: Motives and Outcomes *

Business Commitments, Personal Commitments and Credit Risk: Evidence from China

Bank Characteristics and Payout Policy

Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Permissible collateral, access to finance, and loan contracts: Evidence from a natural experiment Bing Xu Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

Rating Efficiency in the Indian Commercial Paper Market. Anand Srinivasan 1

An Empirical Investigation of the Lease-Debt Relation in the Restaurant and Retail Industry

Household Use of Financial Services

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DEBT MATURITY AND FIRMS INVESTMENT IN FIXED ASSETS

A Fistful of Dollars: Lobbying and the Financial Crisis

The Effect of Corporate Governance on Quality of Information Disclosure:Evidence from Treasury Stock Announcement in Taiwan

Hold-up versus Benefits in Relationship Banking: A Natural Experiment Using REIT Organizational Form

Capital Structure and the 2001 Recession

Bank lending technologies and credit availability in Europe. What can we learn from the crisis? Polytechnic University of Marche

Measuring banking sector outreach

Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans?

Development Economics 855 Lecture Notes 7

Lending to Small Businesses: The Role of Loan Maturity in Addressing Information Problems *

The Distributive Impact of Reforms in Credit Enforcement: Evidence from Indian Debt Recovery Tribunals

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

COLLATERAL S IMPORTANCE IN SMES FINANCING: WHAT IS THE BANKS RESPONSE? SOME EVIDENCE FOR ROMANIA

Why Do Banks Ask for Collateral and Which Ones? Régis BLAZY, Laurent WEILL

Competition and the pass-through of unconventional monetary policy: evidence from TLTROs

Online Appendix Results using Quarterly Earnings and Long-Term Growth Forecasts

The Role of APIs in the Economy

The Role of Soft Information in a Dynamic Contract Setting:

DIVIDENDS AND EXPROPRIATION IN HONG KONG

Maitreesh Ghatak and Timothy W. Guinnane. The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability: Theory and Practice

Does portfolio manager ownership affect fund performance? Finnish evidence

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

DIVIDEND POLICY AND THE LIFE CYCLE HYPOTHESIS: EVIDENCE FROM TAIWAN

Small Bank Comparative Advantages in Alleviating Financial Constraints and Providing Liquidity Insurance over Time

Does information sharing reduce the role of collateral as a screening device? Artashes Karapetyan Norges Bank

A Model of Simultaneous Borrowing and Saving. Under Catastrophic Risk

Discussion of Relationship and Transaction Lending in a Crisis

Italian Consumer Loan Market: Are Lenders Using Risk-Based Pricing?

Shirking and Employment Protection Legislation: Evidence from a Natural Experiment

How are social ties formed? : Interaction of neighborhood and individual immobility.

Preview PP542. International Capital Markets. Gains from Trade. International Capital Markets. The Three Types of International Transaction Trade

Repaying Microcredit Loans: A Natural Experiment on Liability Structure

Creditor protection, information sharing and credit for small and medium-sized enterprises: cross-country evidence

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

The Investment Behavior of Buyout Funds: Theory & Evidence

SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS

IPO Underpricing and Information Disclosure. Laura Bottazzi (Bologna and IGIER) Marco Da Rin (Tilburg, ECGI, and IGIER)

Adverse Selection in the Loan Market

Effectiveness of macroprudential and capital flow measures in Asia and the Pacific 1

Financing Constraints and Employment Evidence from Transition Countries. Dorothea Schäfer (DIW Berlin), Susan Steiner (LUH)

Banking market concentration and consumer credit constraints: Evidence from the 1983 Survey of Consumer Finances

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

Industry Volatility and Workers Demand for Collective Bargaining

ANNEX 3. Overview of Household Financial Assets

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

Financial Performance of Kotak Mahindra Bank

Individual and Neighborhood Effects on FHA Mortgage Activity: Evidence from HMDA Data

Public and Secret Reserve Prices in ebay Auctions

The Journal of Applied Business Research January/February 2013 Volume 29, Number 1

Multi-Dimensional Separating Equilibria and Moral Hazard: An Empirical Study of National Football League Contract Negotiations. March, 2002.

Asymmetric Information and the Role of Financial intermediaries

The Effects of Public Debt on Economic Growth and Gross Investment in India: An Empirical Evidence

Determinants of Credit Rating and Optimal Capital Structure among Pakistani Banks

Which Loans are Relationship Loans? Evidence from the 1998 Survey of Small Business Finances

Empirical Evidence. Economics of Information and Contracts. Testing Contract Theory. Testing Contract Theory

A Theory of Endogenous Liquidity Cycles

Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission. Konstantinos Drakos, MacroFinance, Monetary Policy Transmission 1

THE EURO AREA BANK LENDING SURVEY APRIL 2005

Wage Inequality and Establishment Heterogeneity

Transcription:

The impact of information sharing on the Abstract use of collateral versus guarantees Ralph De Haas and Matteo Millone We exploit contract-level data from Bosnia and Herzegovina to assess the impact of a new credit registry on the use of borrower collateral versus third-party guarantees. Among first-time borrowers, the introduction of mandatory information sharing leads to a shift from collateral to guarantees, in particular for riskier borrowers. Among repeat borrowers, both collateral and guarantee requirements decline in proportion to the length of the lending relationship. These results suggest that information sharing can reduce both adverse selection among new borrowers and hold-up problems among repeat borrowers. Keywords: Information sharing, collateral, guarantees JEL Classification Number: D04, D82, G21, G28 Contact details: Ralph De Haas, One Exchange Square, London EC2A 2JN, UK Phone: +44 20 7338 7213; Fax: +44 20 7338 6111; email: dehaasr@ebrd.com Matteo Millone, VU University Amsterdam, De Boelelaan 1105, 1081 HV, Amsterdam, The Netherlands. Phone: +31 20 59 88781; email: m.millone@vu.nl Ralph De Haas is the Director of Research at the EBRD and Matteo Millone is an Assistant Professor in Finance at VU University Amsterdam. The authors thank Borislav Petric and Igor Duspara for their kind help with accessing EKI data. Financial support from the Bocconi Centre for Applied Research in Finance (Baffi CAREFIN) is gratefully acknowledged. This short paper is forthcoming in the World Bank Economic Review. The working paper series has been produced to stimulate debate on economic transition and development. The views presented are those of the authors and not necessarily of the EBRD. Working Paper No. 197 Prepared in January 2017 9

1. Introduction Most small-business lenders require borrowers to pledge real estate, movable assets or some other form of collateral. Economic theory suggests two reasons for doing so. First, when borrower quality is unobservable, safe borrowers may pledge collateral to signal their quality (Besanko and Thakor, 1987). Second, when quality is observable, collateral boosts borrower effort and discourages strategic default (Boot, Thakor and Udell, 1991). If the first mechanism dominates, riskier borrowers put up less collateral. If the second effect dominates, they pledge more. Not all potential borrowers have assets to pledge and even low-risk borrowers can therefore be credit constrained. For this reason, many lenders not only accept borrower collateral but also third-party guarantees, where a guarantor or co-signer underwrites the loan. While such social collateral fulfils a similar role as borrower collateral mitigating adverse selection and moral hazard there are also differences. 1 Unlike passive assets, guarantors actively monitor borrowers to ensure repayment (Banerjee, Besley and Guinnane, 1994) and such monitoring is often leveraged by the threat of social sanctions (Bond and Rai, 2008). This makes guarantees particularly effective in alleviating moral hazard (Pozzolo, 2004). Moreover, guarantees entail a claim on the entire wealth of the guarantor. Compared with borrower collateral, which only gives a (priority) claim on specific assets, their value is therefore less correlated with the underlying business. Notwithstanding the widespread use of guarantees, empirical evidence on their role relative to borrower collateral remains scarce. This short paper investigates this role by exploiting the introduction of a credit registry in Bosnia and Herzegovina. 2 The registry required lenders to start sharing borrower information and led to a sudden increase in public information on loan applicants. This provides a good setting to contrast the role of guarantees and borrower collateral as the registry partially shifted the focus of lenders from concerns about adverse selection towards moral hazard. 3 We test two hypotheses. For first-time borrowers, we expect a shift from collateral to guarantees as the latter may be particularly effective at containing moral hazard. This shift may be more pronounced for riskier borrower categories because the newly available public 1 Besanko and Thakor (1987) show theoretically that co-signers reduce credit rationing for borrowers without sufficient collateral. 2 See Bos, De Haas and Millone (2015) for additional background. 3 Pagano and Jappelli (1993) provide a theoretical framework in which information sharing reduces adverse selection. 10

information reveals most about them. Second, for repeat borrowers, about whom the lender has built up proprietary information, the impact of the registry depends on the extent to which lenders adjust their views about these existing clients. For instance, the registry may reveal outstanding debt or repayment problems at another bank, in which case a lender may tighten its collateral requirements. 4 Conditional on this base effect, however, we expect that borrowers with a longer lending relationship see a gradual decline in collateral requirements. Their good track record now becomes public information and this reduces the market power of the incumbent lender (Padilla and Pagano, 1997). When the bargaining power of the bank declines, it can require less collateral to extract rents (Chen, 2006). 4 Theoretical work by Karapetyan and Stacescu (2014) suggests that information sharing and collateral may be complements as borrowers with a bad credit history face tougher collateral requirements. Doblas-Madrid and Minetti (2013) provide evidence from the United States of America on a positive relationship between information sharing and the presence of collateral for low-quality borrowers. 11

2. Data The Bosnian credit registry (Centralni Registrar Kredita) became fully operational in July 2009 and requires lenders to submit a report for each loan to a firm or private individual that is disbursed, repaid, late or written off. It contains negative information on past loan defaults, positive information on outstanding loans, and data on whether applicants are or have a guarantor. Our data consist of all 98,012 loans granted during July 2007 to June 2011 by EKI, a Bosnian small-business lender. This period encompasses the two years before and after the registry was introduced. Table 1 shows that almost 40 per cent of all loans are secured by some collateral such as movable or immovable assets. 5 Moreover, almost all loans are guaranteed by at least one guarantor and the average number of co-signers is 2.4. Clients have typically been borrowing from EKI for 1.4 years. 5 As we analyse small-business loans to sole proprietorships where the business owner is personally liable for repayment without a distinction between the assets of the firm and those of the owner our collateral definition encompasses both ( inside ) business assets and ( outside ) personal assets. 12

Table 1: Summary statistics and variable definitions Mean St. Dev. Min Max Definition Credit registry 0.37 0.48 0 1 Dummy = '0' for all months during July 2007-June 2009; '1' for all months during July 2009-June 2011 Borrower collateral 0.38 0.49 0 1 Dummy = '1' if loan is secured by an administrative ban on salary, mortgage, movable collateral, and/or a bill of exchange; '0' otherwise Guarantees 2.35 1.1 0 10 No. of guarantees (co-signed promissory note, contract with solidarity guarantor, and/ or movable guarantor collateral) pledged to the loan Loan amount (log) 8.00 0.78 5.70 10.31 Loan amount in BAM (log) Borrower age 40.81 12.00 18 82 Borrower age in years Male borrower 0.60 0.49 0 1 Dummy = '1' if borrower is male; '0' if female Household size 3.37 1.36 0 19 No. of members in the borrower's household Poverty level -6.99 0.47-10.51-3.91 Minus one * Borrower income in BAM (log) Rural borrower 0.65 0.48 0 1 Dummy = '1' if borrower lives in a rural area; '0' if in an urban area Income risk 0.15 0.36 0 1 Dummy = '1' if borrower has no stable employment; '0' otherwise Low-education borrower 0.11 0.31 0 1 Dummy = '1' if borrower has primary education or less; '0' otherwise Number of 2.04 1.36 1 7 No. of consecutive EKI loans per borrower consecutive loans Relationship length 1.35 1.82 0 9 No. of years since the disbursement of the first EKI loan to the borrower No. of observations 98,012 Note: BAM is Bosnian Convertible Mark. Exchange rate at time of introduction of credit registry: 0.73 USD/BAM. 9

3. Results 3.1 First-time borrowers Table 2 presents OLS regressions to explain for a sample of first-time borrowers the probability that collateral is pledged (columns 1 to 5) and the number of guarantees (columns 6 to 10). The dummy Credit registry distinguishes between loans granted during the two years before the registry ( 0 ) and during the two years after its introduction ( 1 ). All specifications include branch fixed effects, covariates (Borrower age, Business registered, Male borrower, Household size and Loan amount) and borrower-risk proxies. These are Income risk (a dummy that is 1 if the borrower has no stable employment); Poverty level (the inverse of log borrower income); Rural borrower ( 1 if the borrower lives in a rural area) and Low-education borrower ( 1 if the borrower has at most primary education). We first present a parsimonious regression to look at the base effect of the registry introduction (columns 1 and 6) and then consecutively interact Credit registry with each risk proxy. Columns 1 and 6 show that the credit registry entailed a shift from borrower collateral to guarantees.6 The registry introduction was accompanied by a (substantial) 6.7 percentage points lower probability of borrower collateral being pledged and a simultaneous (but limited) increase in the number of guarantees by 0.1 (a Poisson model yields very similar results). Unreported regressions indicate no significant impact on the total number of items pledged (collateral plus guarantees). The interaction regressions in the subsequent columns consistently indicate that the shift from borrower to social collateral is stronger for riskier borrower types. For instance, while the registry reduces the probability of borrower collateral by 5.8 percentage points for borrowers with at least secondary education, the collateralisation rate for less-educated borrowers declines even by 14.9 percentage points. Likewise, the shift towards guarantees is concentrated among rural borrowers for whom the credit registry leads to an additional increase in the expected number of guarantees by 0.1. The effect on the overall number of pledges is again neutral or in the case of low-income borrowers slightly negative (unreported). 6 The covariates show that collateralisation tends to be more common for larger loans and for riskier borrowers, in line with theories that stress the role of collateral in mitigating moral hazard. 9

Table 2: Information sharing and the use of collateral and guarantees by first-time borrowers Borrower collateral Guarantees [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [9] [9] [10] Credit registry -0.067*** -0.121*** -0.564*** -0.003-0.058*** 0.055* 0.119*** 0.663*** 0.003 0.060** (0.015) (0.022) (0.095) (0.017) (0.015) (0.028) (0.040) (0.201) (0.029) (0.028) Credit registry*income risk -0.065*** 0.076** (0.017) (0.034) Credit registry*poverty level -0.071*** 0.087*** (0.014) (0.028) Credit registry*rural borrower -0.093*** 0.076*** (0.016) (0.028) Credit registry*low-education borrower -0.091*** -0.055 (0.017) (0.034) Borrower covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Branch fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 46,826 R-squared 0.192 0.193 0.193 0.194 0.193 0.361 0.362 0.362 0.362 0.362 Note: This table shows ordinary least squares regressions to explain the use of borrower collateral and guarantees in a sample of the first-time loans. Robust standard errors are clustered by loan officer and shown in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Before credit registry: July 2007-June 2009. During credit registry: July 2009-June 2011. All specifications include branch fixed effects and as additional covariates: Borrower age, Business registered, Male borrower, Household size, Income risk, Poverty level, Rural borrower, Low-education borrower and Loan amount. Constant not shown. 9

This shift from borrower collateral to social collateral is in line with the lender focusing more on moral hazard as the new public information on loan applicants reduces concerns about adverse selection. This affects riskier borrowers in particular and is in line with the findings of Pozzolo (2004), who shows that Italian borrowers with a higher ex ante default probability are more likely to have to post third-party guarantees (but not borrower collateral). 3.2 Repeat borrowers Table 3 shows regressions for all repeat borrowers that during the sample period received at least two loans from EKI. Borrower fixed effects wipe out time-invariant observable and unobservable borrower characteristics. 7 In addition to Credit registry, we include either Number of consecutive loans or Relationship length, both proxies for the duration of the lending relationship. We interact these variables with Credit registry to test whether the impact of information sharing differs for lending relationships of different length. When measuring relationship length as the Number of consecutive loans (columns 1 and 3), we observe an overall increase in the probability of borrower collateral by 6.5 percentage points and a rise in the number of guarantees of 0.1 after the introduction of the registry. However, this increase is balanced by a rapid decrease in collateral requirements over the length of the relationship. In fact, even before the registry, for every additional loan the probability that a borrower had to pledge collateral decreased by 3.1 percentage points and the expected number of guarantees by 0.04. This is in line with Boot and Thakor (1994) who argue that repeat interactions help to build trust and reduce moral hazard. The negative effect of relationship length on collateralisation becomes even stronger during the credit registry (an additional reduction of 2.4 percentage points in the probability that borrower collateral is present and an additional decline of 0.02 expected guarantees). 8 Using years to measure the duration of the relationship (columns 2 and 4), gives qualitatively equivalent results for both borrower collateral and guarantees. The strengthening of the negative effect of relationship length on collateralisation rates once the credit registry is in place, suggests a decline in switching costs. Without information sharing, repeat borrowers that try to switch to a competing lender get pooled with low-quality 7 Borrower fixed effects ensure that all one-time borrowers drop out of these regressions so that we compare first-time and repeat loans among a set of repeat borrowers. 8 Taking all three coefficients in column 1 into account, we see that the combined effect on first-time loans after the credit registry is not significantly different from zero for personal collateral while it is positive and significant for guarantees. 9

firms and may therefore only receive unattractive outside offers. With information sharing, outside lenders can now observe good borrower performance. This reduces the market power of the incumbent lender while boosting the bargaining power of reputable borrowers. 9 As a result, lengthening lending relationships lead to an even faster reduction of both borrower collateral and guarantees. Table 3: Information sharing and the use of collateral and guarantees by repeat borrowers Borrower collateral Guarantees [1] [2] [3] [4] Credit registry 0.065*** 0.383*** 0.096*** 0.388*** (0.013) (0.011) (0.021) (0.018) Number of consecutive loans -0.031*** -0.040*** (0.005) (0.010) Credit registry*number of consecutive loans -0.024*** -0.020*** (0.004) (0.007) Relationship length -0.261*** -0.261*** (0.007) (0.011) Credit registry*relationship length -0.022*** -0.011** (0.003) (0.005) Borrower covariates No No No No Borrower fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 68,811 68,811 68,811 68,811 R-squared 0.232 0.290 0.196 0.212 Note: This table shows OLS regressions to explain the use of borrower collateral and guarantees in a sample of repeat borrowers. All specifications include borrower fixed effects. Robust standard errors are clustered by borrower and shown in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively. Before credit registry: July 2007-June 2009. During credit registry: July 2009-June 2011. Constant not shown. 9 The loss of market power also reduces the incentives to offer favourable conditions to first-time borrowers. 10

4. Conclusion An increasing number of emerging markets regard public credit registries that collect, consolidate and distribute reliable borrower information as a potentially effective tool to counterbalance weak creditor protection and inadequate bankruptcy laws. We find that the introduction of a credit registry in Bosnia and Herzegovina entailed a shift from borrower collateral to third-party guarantees among first-time borrowers. This holds in particular for riskier borrower types, such as low-income clients, for whom mandatory information sharing substantially reduced the likelihood that they needed to pledge hard collateral. This reduction is only partially offset by a limited increase in the number of required co-signers. We also document a gradual decline in both types of collateral for repeat borrowers and this decline is proportional to the duration of the lending relationship. These results suggest that mandatory information sharing, and the resulting decline in adverse-selection problems, can reduce banks focus on traditional collateral. This can broaden the set of borrowers that banks can service provided that the (limited) increase in required guarantees does not lead to the exclusion of borrowers without social capital. At the same time, the increased transparency introduced by a credit registry can force incumbent banks to reduce collateralisation rates even faster than normal, as good borrowers can now more easily shop around and look for better deals elsewhere. This is a second channel through which information sharing can benefit borrowers. 11

References A.V. Banerjee, T. Besley and T.W. Guinnane (1994), Thy Neighbour's Keeper: The Design of a Credit Cooperative with Theory and a Test, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, no. 2: 491 515. D. Besanko and A.V. Thakor (1987), Collateral and Rationing, Sorting Equilibria in Monopolistic and Competitive Credit Markets, International Economic Review 28, no. 3: 671 89. P. Bond and A.S. Rai (2008), Cosigned or Group Loans, Journal of Development Economics 85: 58 80. A.W. Boot and A.V. Thakor (1994), Moral Hazard and Secured Lending in an Infinitely Repeated Credit Game, International Economic Review 35: 899 920. A.W. Boot, A.V. Thakor and G.F. Udell (1991), Secured Lending and Default Risk: Equilibrium Analysis, Policy Implications and Empirical Results, Economic Journal 101: 458 472. J. Bos, R. De Haas and M. Millone (2015), Sharing Borrower Information in a Competitive Credit Market, EBRD Working Paper No. 180, London. Y. Chen (2006), Collateral, Loan Guarantees, and the Lenders Incentives to Resolve Financial Distress, Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46: 1 15. A. Doblas-Madrid and R. Minetti (2013), Sharing Information in the Credit Market: Contract-Level Evidence from U.S. Firms, Journal of Financial Economics 109, no.1: 198 223. A. Karapetyan and B. Stacescu (2014), Does Information Sharing Reduce the Role of Collateral as a Screening Device?, Journal of Banking & Finance 43: 48 57. J. Padilla and M. Pagano (1997), Endogenous Communication Among Lenders and Entrepreneurial Incentives, Review of Financial Studies 10, no. 1: 205 236. M. Pagano and T. Jappelli (1993), Information Sharing in Credit Markets, Journal of Finance 48, no. 5: 1693 1718. A.F. Pozzolo (2004), The Role of Guarantees in Bank Lending, mimeo. 12