Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

Similar documents
ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Problem set 1 ECON 4330

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Problem set 2. Filip Rozsypal November 23, 2011

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

Macro Consumption Problems 12-24

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Consumption and Savings

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

III: Labor Supply in Two Periods

Solutions to Problem Set 1

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Topic 2: Consumption

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Macroeconomics: Fluctuations and Growth

Home Assignment 1 Financial Openness, the Current Account and Economic Welfare

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

14.05 Lecture Notes. Labor Supply

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

ECON 815. Uncertainty and Asset Prices

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Professor Dr. Holger Strulik Open Economy Macro 1 / 34

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY ECONOMICS NOTE 8b

Lecture 12 Ricardian Equivalence Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Lecture 4A The Decentralized Economy I

GMM Estimation. 1 Introduction. 2 Consumption-CAPM

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

1 Dynamic programming

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

1 The Solow Growth Model

Advanced (International) Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics I Chapter 3. Consumption

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

1 No capital mobility

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

INDIVIDUAL CONSUMPTION and SAVINGS DECISIONS

ECON Micro Foundations

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Final Exam Solutions

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Slides III - Complete Markets

Fakultät III Univ.-Prof. Dr. Jan Franke-Viebach

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Intermediate Macroeconomics, Sciences Po, Answer Key to Problem Set 9

Solving The Perfect Foresight CRRA Consumption Model

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Midterm Exam. Monday, March hour, 30 minutes. Name:

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency.

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

MID-TERM EXAM #2: Intermediate Macro Winter 2014

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

A simple wealth model

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

The Real Business Cycle Model

Feb. 20th, Recursive, Stochastic Growth Model

Equilibrium with Production and Labor Supply

Business Cycles II: Theories

One-Period Valuation Theory

An Entrepreneur s Problem Under Perfect Foresight

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Lecture 5: to Consumption & Asset Choice

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Analytical Problem Set

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Question 1: Productivity, Output and Employment (20 Marks)

Transcription:

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2 Universität Siegen Dynamic Macroeconomics 1 / 26

1 Two period model - Problem 1 2 Two period model with borrowing constraint - Problem 2 Dynamic Macroeconomics 2 / 26

1a) Maximization problem The maximization problem of the agent is max u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) c 1,c 2,a 1,a 2 such that : c 1 + a 1 = y 1 + a 0 (P1) c 2 + a 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 c 1 0, c 2 0 To solve this problem, we will first Get rid of the choice variable a2 (Question 1b)). Get rid of the non-negativity constraints on c1 and c 2 (Question 1c)). and then take the first-order conditions for the simplified optimization problem. Dynamic Macroeconomics 3 / 26

1b) Why a 2 > 0 can t be optimal Suppose you have solved the problem in (P1) and denote the solution by c 1, c 2, a 1, a 2 and suppose that a 2 > 0 Now suppose you reduce a 2 by ɛ to a 2 ɛ and increase c 2 to c 2 + ɛ. This will increase life-time utility, since u (c 2 ) > 0. Hence a2 can t be optimal. Intuitively: Saving for the time after your death does not yield utility. We will also assume that a2 < 0 is not allowed. (Banks won t lend to you, if they know you die tomorrow). Dynamic Macroeconomics 4 / 26

1c) Why c t = 0, t = 1, 2 can t be optimal Suppose you have solved the problem in (P1) and denote the solution by c 1, c 2, a 1, a 2 and suppose that c 1 = 0 Now suppose you reduce c 2 by ɛ to c 2 ɛ and increase c 1 to c 1 + ɛ. This reduces utility in the second period by u (c 2 )ɛ. It increases utility in the first period by u (c 1 )ɛ. The overall change in life-time utility is since we assumed that u (c 1 )ɛ βu (c 2 ) = u (0)ɛ βu (c 2 )ɛ > 0 lim c u (c t ) = t 0 Hence c 1 = 0 can t be optimal. Dynamic Macroeconomics 5 / 26

1d) Simplified maximization problem We have simplified our optimization problem (P1) to max u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) c 1,c 2,a 1 such that : c 1 + a 1 = y 1 + a 0 (P2) c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 We will solve this problem on two ways: Using the substitution method. Using the Lagrange function. Dynamic Macroeconomics 6 / 26

1d) Substitution method Solving c 1 + a 1 = y 1 + a 0 for c 1 and using c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 we can write the optimization problem as max a 1 u(y 1 + a 0 a 1 ) + βu(y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 ) The first order condition is (using the chain rule) u (y 1 + a 0 a 1 )) + βu (y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 )(1 + r) = 0 u (y 1 + a 0 a 1 )) = βu (y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 )(1 + r) u (c 1 ) = β(1 + r)u (c 2 ) Def. of c i (Euler) Equation (Euler) is one of the fundamental building blocks of dynamic macro models. Dynamic Macroeconomics 7 / 26

1d) Lagrange function I The Lagrange function for the problem in (P2) is L(c 1, c 2, a 1, λ 1, λ 2 ) = u(c 1 ) + βu(c 2 ) + λ 1 [y 1 + a 0 c 1 a 1 ] The first order conditions are + λ 2 [y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 c 2 ] L = u (c 1 ) λ 1 c 1 = 0 (FOC 1) L = βu (c 2 ) λ 2 c 2 = 0 (FOC 2) L = λ 1 + (1 + r)λ 2 a 1 = 0 (FOC 3) L = y 1 + a 0 c 1 a 1 λ 1 = 0 L = y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 c 2 λ 2 = 0 Dynamic Macroeconomics 8 / 26

1d) Lagrange function II, Euler Equation From FOC 1, FOC 2 and FOC 3 we get u (c 1 ) = β(1 + r)u (c 2 ) (Euler) which is again the Euler equation. The Euler equation describes the optimal consumption time path. Think of it in terms of costs and benefits of saving. LHS: Costs of saving. RHS: Benefits of saving. In the optimum the consumer cannot improve her utility by shifting consumption inter-temporally. We can rewrite the equation to u (c 1 ) βu (c 2 ) = 1 + r Marginal rate of substitution (LHS) has to be equal to relative price. Dynamic Macroeconomics 9 / 26

1e) u(c) = c1 σ 1 1 σ For the period utility function We have and The Euler equation reads then as u(c) = c1 σ 1 1 σ u (c) = c σ = 1 c σ > 0 u (c) = σc σ 1 < 0 c σ 1 = β(1 + r)c σ 2 (Euler) Dynamic Macroeconomics 10 / 26

1e) Plot of u(c) = c1 σ 1 1 σ Dynamic Macroeconomics 11 / 26

1f) Consumption growth Rewrite the Euler equation as ( ) σ c2 = β(1 + r) β = 1 c 1 1 + ρ ( ) σ c2 = 1 + r ln c 1 1 + ρ ( ) c2 σln = ln (1 + r) ln (1 + ρ) ln (1 + x) x c 1 ( ) c2 ln 1 (r ρ) σ c 1 ρ can be interpreted as a personal discount rate (a personal interest rate). Consumption grows, if the market interest rate is higher than the private interest rate. Movements in r have a higher effect if σ is small. Dynamic Macroeconomics 12 / 26

1g) Solving for c 1 Optimal allocation is implicitly given by c 1 + a 1 = y 1 + a 0 (1) c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 (2) ( ) σ c2 = β(1 + r) (Euler) Combining (1) and (2) gives c 1 c 1 + c 2 1 + r }{{} i) = a 0 + y 1 + y 2 1 + r }{{} ii) (LB) i): Present value of lifetime expenditure on consumption goods. ii): Present value of lifetime income. Dynamic Macroeconomics 13 / 26

1g) Solving for c 1 From Euler equation have Combine it with (LB) to get c 2 = (β(1 + r)) 1 σ c1 1 c 1 = 1 + (β) 1/σ [(1 + r)] 1/σ 1 [ a 0 + y 1 + y ] 2 1 + r Consumption in period 1 depends upon lifetime income. If β(1 + r) = 1, then split consumption equally between periods 1 and 2. Perfect consumption smoothing. σ determines how much differences in subjective and market interest rate affect the allocation of consumption. Dynamic Macroeconomics 14 / 26

1g) Income, substitution and wealth effects See additional file Dynamic Macroeconomics 15 / 26

1h) Optimal consumption in three cases Note that for all three case, lifetime income is given by 100 = 100 + 0 50 = 50 + 1 + 0 1 + 0 = 0 + 100 1 + 0 Additionally, since β(1 + r) = 1(1 + 0) = 1, it is optimal to have c 1 = c 2 = 50. This implies the following saving choices i) a 1 = y 1 c 1 = 100 50 = 50 ii) a 1 = y 1 c 1 = 50 50 = 0 iii) a 1 = y 1 c 1 = 0 50 = 50 Does this make sense? (Who lends to somebody with 0 income?). Dynamic Macroeconomics 16 / 26

1 Two period model - Problem 1 2 Two period model with borrowing constraint - Problem 2 Dynamic Macroeconomics 17 / 26

2a) Budget constraints Start with the budget constraints for period 1 and 2 given by and combine them to yield c 1 + a 1 = y 1 c 2 = y 2 + (1 + r)a 1 c 1 + c 2 1 + r = y 1 + y 2 1 + r. This is the life-time budget constraint. It states that the present value of life-time consumption expenditure (the stuff on the left-hand side) cannot exceed the present value of life-time income (the stuff on the right hand side. For the given income levels, the life-time budget constraint becomes c 1 + c 2 1 + r = 4 + 10 1 + r. Dynamic Macroeconomics 18 / 26

2b) Optimal consumption The optimal consumption in the first period can be obtained by combining the Euler equation, 1 c 1 = β(1 + r) 1 c 2, and the life-time budget constraint. One obtains c 1 = 1 [ 4 + 10 ] 1 + β 1 + r Savings in the first period are given by s = y 1 c 1 = y 1 1 [ y 1 + y ] 2 1 + β 1 + r 1 = (1 + β)(1 + r) (y 1β(1 + r) y 2 ). Dynamic Macroeconomics 19 / 26

2b) Optimal consumption The consumer will be a borrower if the following condition holds s < 0 1 (1 + β)(1 + r) (y 1β(1 + r) y 2 ) < 0 β(1 + r) < y 2 y 1 β(1 + r) < 10 4. Dynamic Macroeconomics 20 / 26

2c) Comparison with Keynesian consumption function Above we found c 1 = 1 [ 4 + 10 ] 1 + β 1 + r A typical Keynesian consumption function from undergraduate course looks like c 1 = 0.9y 1 Differences: Where does the 0.9 come form? Different response to changes in first period income. Dynamic Macroeconomics 21 / 26

2c) Comparison with Keynesian consumption function At low incomes, people will spend a high proportion of their income. When you have low income, you do not have the luxury of being able to save. You need to spend everything you have on essentials. Consumption depends only on y 1. However, it depends also on life-cycle circles, behavioural factors. When you get more income, it is possible to save. In Keynesian function: a consumer always spends the income s fraction of 0.9 on consumption. Dynamic Macroeconomics 22 / 26

2d) Marginal propensity to consume Suppose that the income in the first period increases by ɛ (while the income in the second period remains constant). The marginal propensity to consume in the first-period is given by c 0 / y 0 If first-period income increases by one unit, then first-period consumption increases by 1 1 + β units in the optimization case. Most likely β [0.9, 1] so that 1 1+β 0.5. For the Keynesian consumption function a one unit increase in income leads to a 0.9 unit increase in consumption. Dynamic Macroeconomics 23 / 26

2d) Marginal propensity to consume At low incomes, people will spend a high proportion of their income. When you have low income, you do not have the luxury of being able to save. You need to spend everything you have on essentials. Consumption depends only on y 1. However, it depends also on life-cycle circles, behavioural factors. When you get more income, it is possible to save. In Keynesian function: a consumer always spends the income s fraction of 0.9 on consumption. Dynamic Macroeconomics 24 / 26

2d) Borrowing constraints Suppose that the consumer faces a liquidity constraint, which means that he can save but is unable to borrow in the first-period. For r = 0 and β = 1 we see from question b) that the consumer would like to consume c 1 = 1 [ 4 + 10 ] = 7 1 + 1 1 which would entail a borrowing of s 1 = y 1 c 1 = 4 7 = 3. In the presence of borrowing constraints this is not attainable. The consumer tries to come as close to the optimal level of consumption without borrowing constraints and hence consumes his entire first period income, i.e c 1 = 4, s 1 = 4 4 = 0 Dynamic Macroeconomics 25 / 26

2f) Marginal propensity to consume with borrowing constraints Continue to assume that the consumer is liquidity constrained in the first-period. Suppose that the income in the first period increases by ɛ (while the income in the second period remains constant). The marginal prospensity to consume for consumer faced by borrowing constraint is 1. Why? Without constraint he would like to consume at least 7 units in period 1. But actually he can only consume 4 units. If he now has one more unit available, he wants to get closer to the 7 units and consumes all additional income in the first period. Behaves more like a Keynesian consumer. Importance for policy? Dynamic Macroeconomics 26 / 26