SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT

Similar documents
ADVERSE SELECTION PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE. 1. Introduction

Econ 277A: Economic Development I. Final Exam (06 May 2012)

Dynamic Lending under Adverse Selection and Limited Borrower Commitment: Can it Outperform Group Lending?

The Micro in Microfinance. Dr. Kumar Aniket

Maitreesh Ghatak and Timothy W. Guinnane. The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability: Theory and Practice

A Theory of Interactions Between MFIs and

MORAL HAZARD PAPER 8: CREDIT AND MICROFINANCE

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Joint Liability Lending with Correlated Risks

A Theory of Interactions Between MFIs and Informal Lenders 1

Financially Interlinked Business Groups

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Rural Financial Intermediaries

A Theory of Interactions Between MFIs and Informal Lenders

Capital Allocation Between The Risky And The Risk- Free Asset

The role of asymmetric information

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

Problem Set: Contract Theory

This assignment is due on Tuesday, September 15, at the beginning of class (or sooner).

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

How do we cope with uncertainty?

UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION

1 Dynamic programming

9 D/S of/for Labor. 9.1 Demand for Labor. Microeconomics I - Lecture #9, April 14, 2009

F E M M Faculty of Economics and Management Magdeburg

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Group Size Matters in Microlending under Adverse Selection or Moral Hazard

Beyond Microcredit: Giving the Poor a Way to Save Their Way out of Poverty

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Peer Monitoring via Loss Mutualization

Group-lending with sequential financing, contingent renewal and social capital. Prabal Roy Chowdhury

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 8: Insurance Markets

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Where do securities come from

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

Basic Assumptions (1)

Money, Output, and the Nominal National Debt. Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman (AER 1990)

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

HARRIS-TODARO MODEL OF URBAN UNEMPLOYMENT

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

UNIVERSITY OF VICTORIA FINAL EXAM April 2012

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Answers to June 11, 2012 Microeconomics Prelim

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

BIROn - Birkbeck Institutional Research Online

Problem Set 5 - Solution Hints

General Equilibrium under Uncertainty

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Development Microeconomics Tutorial SS 2006 Johannes Metzler Credit Ray Ch.14

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

G604 Midterm, March 301, 2003 ANSWERS

LI Reunión Anual. Noviembre de Managing Strategic Buyers: Should a Seller Ban Resale? Beccuti, Juan Coleff, Joaquin

Leverage, Moral Hazard and Liquidity. Federal Reserve Bank of New York, February

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Macroeconomics and finance

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Information. September 1, A Comment on Meza and Webb: Too Much. Investment - A Problem of Asymmetric. Information. Manuela Hungerbuhler Lopes

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

ECONOMICS SERIES SWP 2006/23. The Value of Information in a Principal-Agent Model with Moral Hazard: The Ex Ante Contracting Case.

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

Adverse Selection and Costly External Finance

In real economies, people still want to hold fiat money eventhough alternative assets seem to offer greater rates of return. Why?

Mechanism Design: Single Agent, Discrete Types

Strategic Production Game 1

Competition and Moral Hazard

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Development Economics 455 Prof. Karaivanov

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Comprehensive Exam

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 12. Default Risk, Collateral and Credit Rationing

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Problems. 1. Given information: (a) To calculate wealth, we compute:

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

Financial markets in developing countries (rough notes, use only as guidance; more details provided in lecture) The role of the financial system

Development Economics

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

QED. Queen s Economics Department Working Paper No Junfeng Qiu Central University of Finance and Economics

Transcription:

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT Author: Maitreesh Ghatak Presented by: Kosha Modi February 16, 2017

Introduction In an economic environment where collateral does not exist or is low, this paper talks about solving the problem of adverse selection using the information that borrowers have about each other as a screening device. Joint liability contracts induces a positive assortative matching in group formation,i.e., safe borrowers will end up with safe borrowers as partners, and risky borrowers with risky partners. This local information can be used as a screening device. The success of the Grameen Bank also depends on this peer selection. According to Muhammad Yunus (1994), the founder of the Grameen Bank, Usually it takes quite a bit of time for the members to identify each other and consult each other before announcing they wish to form a group.

The Model Consider a one-period model of a credit market under adverse selection. Technology and Preferences: All agents live in a village with a large population normalised to unity and are endowed with one unit of labour and a risky investment project. The project requires one unit of capital and one unit of labour. Agents do not have personal wealth and need to borrow to launch their projects. The outcomes of the project are Success (S) and Failure (F). There are two types of borrowers, risky (r) and safe (s), characterized by the probability of success of their projects, p r and p s respectively where 0 < p r < p s < 1: Risky and safe borrowers exist in proportions θ and 1 θ the population. The outcomes of the projects are independently distributed for the same type as well as across different types.

The return of a project of a borrower of type i is R i > 0 if successful and 0 if it fails. Assume that risky and safe projects have the same mean return, that is, p r R r = p s R s = R, but risky projects have a greater spread around the mean. Borrowers are risk-neutral and maximize expected returns (second order stochastic dominance). Borrowers of both types have an reservation payoff ū: The lending side is represented by risk-neutral banks whose opportunity cost of capital is ρ 1 per unit. We assume that the village is small relative to the credit market, and so the supply of loans is perfectly elastic at the rate ρ

Information and Contracting: The type of a borrower is unknown to the lenders. However, borrowers know each other s types. There is no moral hazard and agents supply labour to the project inelastically. The outcome of a project (whether it is a success or a failure) is observable by the bank; so the credit contracts are contingent on the outcomes. There is a limited liability constraint: in case their projects fail, borrowers are liable up to the amount of collateralisable wealth they posses, w. For simplicity we take w = 0. Let us assume that the project is socially productive in terms of expected returns and oppurtunity costs of labour and capital i.e. R > ρ + ū

Individual Liability Framework If a bank has full information about a borrower s type, then by the zero profit constraint of the banks, a borrower of type i, i r, s, will be charged the interest rate r i = ρ/p i Thus, the safe borrowers will be charged a lower interest rate. The average repayment rate will be given by p = θp r + (1 θ)p s Since the lender cannot identify the borrower s type, the risky borrowers have an incentive to mimic being the safe borrowers so as to be charged a lower interest rate. In this case, the banks thus have to charge a single interest rate to all borrowers. If both types of borrowers borrow in equilibrium, then the optimal pooling contract satisfying zero profit constraint, r = ρ/ p..

Clearly, under asymmetric information, it is less profitable now for the safe borrowers because they are being charged a higher interest rate. Suppose it becomes so unprofitable for the safe borrowers that they are driven out of the credit market i.e., the expected returns from the project are lesser than the expected costs R < p s r + ū or R < p s ρ/ p + ū In such a case, only the risky borrowers will stay in the credit market. This is a problem of underinvestment (or the lemons problem) due to adverse selection. The interest rate charged will be r = ρ/p r and the average repayment rate will be given by p r

Joint Liability Lending In a joint liability contracts, credit is given in groups. There is an individual liability component r,and a joint liability component c. As in standard debt contracts, if the project of a borrower fails then owing to the limited-liability constraint, she pays nothing to the bank. But if a borrower s project is successful then apart from repaying her own debt r to the bank she has to pay an additional joint liability payment c per member of her group whose projects have failed. Here, for simplicity we take groups of two. PROPOSITION 1. Joint liability contracts lead to positive assortative matching in the formation of groups. In our setup, this means that a safe borrower will partner with a safe one, and a risky borrower with a risky one.

PROOF: The expected payoff of a borrower of type i when her partner is type j from a joint liability contract (r, c) is: U ij (r, c) = R [p i r + p i (1 p j )c] Note here that the higher the probability of success of your partner, p j, the higher is your expected payoff, for c > 0. Thus, both type of borrowers would want to team up with the safe type. The net expected gain of a risky borrower from having a safe partner is U rs U rr = p r (p s p r )c. Similarly, the net expected loss of a safe borrower from having a risky partner is U ss U sr = p s (p s p r )c. Thus, U ss U sr > U rs U rr or U ss + U rr > U sr + U rs. The latter implies assortative matching maximises aggregate expected payoff of all borrowers over different possible matches.

The intuition is simple. The benefit of having a safe rather than a risky partner is realised only when a borrower herself has succeeded. Hence a safe borrower is much more concerned about the type of her partner than a risky borrower, although both would prefer a safe partner. Hence, a risky borrower cannot afford a high enough side payment that will convince the safe type to team with him. Now given that same type of borrowers will team up, the expected payoff function for the borrower of type i is given by U ii = R [p i r p i (1 p i )c] The indifference curve of a borrower of type i in the (r, c) plane is represented by the line rp i + c(1 p i )p i = k (where k is some constant) which also represents an iso-profit curve of the bank when lending to a borrower of type i. The only difference of course is that the higher is k the lower is the expected payoff of a borrower and higher is the expected profit of the bank.

The slope of the indifference curve is given by dc dr U ii =const= 1 1 p i Which type of borrower s indifference curve is steeper? The intuition is that to receive a small reduction in the interest rate, safe borrowers would be willing to pay a higher amount of joint liability than risky borrowers because having safe partners they do not have to pay joint liability payments very often. Thus indifference curves have single crossing property.

Optimal Joint Liability Contracts The contracting problem is the following sequential game: first, the bank offers a finite set of joint liability contracts (r 1, c 1 ), (r 2, c 2 ),...; second, borrowers who wish to accept any one of these contracts select a partner and do so; finally, projects are carried out and outcome-contingent transfers as specified in the contract are met. Borrowers who choose not to borrow enjoy their reservation payoff of ū. Let us look at contracts C JL = [(r, c) r, c 0]. Suppose the bank offers two contracts [(r r, c r ), r s, c s ] designed for risky and safe borrower groups respectively. We are essentially looking at a separating equilibrium.

The bank s objective is to choose (r r, c r ), (r s, c s ) such that the utility of a representative consumer is maximised i.e., θu rr + (1 θ)u ss subject to the following constraints (1) The zero profit constraint of the bank requires that the expected repayment from each loan is at least as large as the opportunity cost of capital, r r p r + c r p r (1 p r ) ρ r s p s + c s p s (1 p s ) ρ (2) The participation constraint given by U ii 0fori = r, s

(3) The limited liability constraint requires that a borrower cannot make any transfers to the lender when her project fails, and that the sum of individual and joint liability payments, r + c, cannot exceed the realised revenue from the project when it succeeds: r i + c i R i fori = r, s (4)The incentive-compatibility constraint for each type of borrower requires that it is in the self-interest of a borrower to choose a contract that is designed for her type since that is private information: U rr (r r, c r ) U rr (r s, c s ) U ss (r s, c s ) U ss (r r, c r ) LEMMA 1. If (r r, C r ) and (r s, c s ) satisfy the incentive-compatibilityc onstraints then they will induce assortative matching in the group formation stage.

Since the objective is to maximise the borrower s utility, the zero profit constraint will hold with equality. Now if we simultaneously solve the two zero profit equality constraints, we get ˆr = ρ(p r + p s 1) and ĉ = ρ/p r p s. We assume ˆr is greater than 0. In the diagram, The line DA and Ac are the zero profit lines. Can you guess the region where incentive compatibility holds? Let us assume that limited liability constraint is fulfilled for ˆr, ĉ, i.e., R ρ(1 + p s p r ) Note that the limited liability constraint has a slope=-1, i.e., it is flatter than the indifference curves. Thus, if the limited liability constraint is fulfilled for (ˆr, ĉ), it automatically is fulfilled for the (r r, c r ). Thus we only consider the LLC to be binding for the safe borrowers. This is shown in the diagram.

Note that since the zero profit constraint is fulfilled, U ii = R ρ > ū (by assumption of social productiveness of the project). Thus the participation constraint is fulfilled for both the types. Since both the types continue to exist in the credit market, the problem of underinvestment is solved. The average repayment rate is again p which is the average probability of success of the project in the economy, and welfare levels are R ρ of the two types of borrowers as was in the full information case.

For the pooling equilibrium, the same (r,c) is offered to both the types. Check: The zero profit, limited liability and participation constraint stay the same, and the incentive compatibility constraint is vacuously true. Here ˆr, ĉ would be a pooling equilibrium. Does it satisfy the zero profit, limited liability and participation constraint? Again, both the types continue to exist in the credit market, the problem of underinvestment is solved. The average repayment rate is again p which is the average probability of success of the project in the economy, and welfare levels are R ρ of the two types of borrowers as was in the full information case.