The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Similar documents
The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

On the new Keynesian model

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Credit, externalities, and non-optimality of the Friedman rule

Interest-rate pegs and central bank asset purchases: Perfect foresight and the reversal puzzle

Discussion of: Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations by Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

Business Cycle Accounting

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

BUSINESS CYCLE ACCOUNTING

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Nominal Rigidities, News-Driven Business Cycles, and Monetary Policy

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Adjustment Costs, Agency Costs and Terms of Trade Disturbances in a Small Open Economy

A Model with Costly-State Verification

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Bank Capital, Agency Costs, and Monetary Policy. Césaire Meh Kevin Moran Department of Monetary and Financial Analysis Bank of Canada

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

International business cycle accounting: the case of Japan and the US

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

Sudden Stops and Output Drops

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a New Keynesian Model with Tobin s Q Investment Theory Features

Monetary Economics Final Exam

On the Merits of Conventional vs Unconventional Fiscal Policy

Risky Mortgages in a DSGE Model

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

1 Dynamic programming

Asset-price driven business cycle and monetary policy

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Incorporate Financial Frictions into a

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Utility Maximizing Entrepreneurs and the Financial Accelerator

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics

The Zero Lower Bound

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Government Policy Response to War-Expenditure Shocks

Money in an RBC framework

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Notes for a Model With Banks and Net Worth Constraints

Fiscal Multiplier in a Liquidity Constrained New Keynesian Economy

Collateral constraint and news-driven cycles

Introduction to DSGE Models

Business Cycle Accounting of Trade Barriers in a Small Open Economy

Growth Accounting and Endogenous Technical Change

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Is the Maastricht debt limit safe enough for Slovakia?

Credit Disruptions and the Spillover Effects between the Household and Business Sectors

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

Specification of DSGE Models: A Business Cycle Accounting Application for Colombia

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

A Neoclassical Analysis of the Asian Crisis: Business Cycle Accounting for a Small Open Economy

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Optimal Monetary Policy In a Model with Agency Costs

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

Monetary Policy and the Great Recession

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Goods Market Frictions and Real Exchange Rate Puzzles

A Note on the Solow Growth Model with a CES Production Function and Declining Population

Bernanke and Gertler [1989]

Asset Prices and Business Cycles with. Financial Frictions

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Financial Factors in Business Cycles

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting Masaru Inaba and Kengo Nutahara Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and Industry, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo 19. April 2008 Online at http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/8337/ MPRA Paper No. 8337, posted 19. April 2008 04:32 UTC

The role of investment wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy and business cycle accounting Masaru Inaba Kengo Nutahara Revised: April 19, 2008 Abstract Many researches that apply business cycle accounting (hereafter, BCA) to actual data conclude that models with investment frictions or investment wedges are not promising for modeling business cycle dynamics. In this paper, we apply BCA to artificial data generated by a variant model of Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997, American Economic Review), which is one of representative models with investment frictions. We find that BCA leads us to conclude that models of investment wedges are not promising according to the criteria of BCA, although the true model contains investment frictions. Keywords: Business cycle accounting; investment wedge; investment friction; wedge decompsition JEL Classification: C68, E13, E32 Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and Industry (RIETI). E-mail: inaba-masaru@rieti.go.jp Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo and research fellow of Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS). E-mail: ee67003@mail.ecc.u-tokyo.ac.jp 1

1 Introduction Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2002, 2007) (hereafter, CKM) propose a simple method, business cycle accounting (hereafter, BCA), to investigate a promising class of frictional models. In BCA, the economy is assumed as a standard neoclassical prototype model with time-varying productivity, labor tax, investment tax, and government consumption. These are called efficiency, labor, investment, and government wedges, respectively. This assumption is justified by equivalence results. This prototype model with wedges covers a large class of frictional business cycle models. Wedges are measured so that the prototype model perfectly accounts for the observed data. After the measurement of wedges, the importance of each wedge is evaluated through counterfactual simulations under an alternative sequence of wedges: wedge decompositions. The importance of wedges is judged by the similarity of output prediction to actual data. Many papers including CKM deny the importance of investment wedges. The models of Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999) and Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997) are often cited as representative models with investment frictions. In this paper, we apply BCA to artificial data generated by a variant model of Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997). We find that BCA leads us to conclude that models with investment wedges are not promising according to the criteria of BCA, although the true model contains investment frictions. This is because BCA focuses only on determining whether or not investment wedges are the driving force of business cycles. In the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy, the role of investment wedges is to delay the propagation of technology shocks, which is consistent with empirical facts. BCA cannot capture such a role of investment wedges. The remainder of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, we introduce our economy and the prototype model for BCA. Section 3 applies BCA to data generated by the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy. Section 4 draws some concluding remarks. 2

2 The model 2.1 Carlstrom-Fuerst economy First, we provide a brief description about our Carlstrom-Fuerst economy. 1 There are two types of consumers: households and entrepreneurs. Households own capital stock and supply labor input and capital for the production of output to competitive firms. Entrepreneurs own capital stocks and supply capital to firms. Entrepreneurs also have investment technology, and they produce investment goods. Moreover, they have to borrow working capital to produce investment goods, however, the amount of borrowing are limited by their net worth because of the agency problem. There are two modifications in our Carlstrom-Fuerst economy: utility function and the introduction of government consumption. We employ the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function u(c t, l t ) = log(c t ) + ν log(1 l t ), since the utility function of the prototype model is CRRA. We also introduce constant government consumption g. 2 The equilibrium system of our Carlstrom-Fuerst economy is summarized as follows: c t ν = (1 α) yt, (1) 1 l t l [ { t }] q t 1 y t+1 = βe t q t+1 (1 δ) + α, (2) c t c t+1 k t+1 + z t+1 } ] y t+1 qt+1 f( ω t+1 ) q t = βγe t [{q t+1 (1 δ) + α, (3) k t+1 + z t+1 1 q t+1 g( ω t+1 ) [ q t = 1 Φ( ω t )µ + φ( ω t )µ f( ω ] 1 t) f, (4) ( ω t ) i n t t = 1 q t g( ω t ), (5) [ n t = z t q t (1 δ) + r t ], (6) [ ] α y t = A t k t + z t l 1 α t, (7) 1 See Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997, 1998) for details. 2 We introduce government consumption to make the volatility of the government wedge in the associated prototype model small. 3

] ] [ ] [k t+1 + z t+1 = (1 δ) [k t + z t + i t 1 Φ( ω t )µ, (8) e t + q t z t+1 = q t i t f( ω t ), (9) c t + e t + i t + g = y t, (10) log(a t+1 ) = ρ log(a t ) + ε t+1. (11) (1) is the intratemporal optimization condition; (2) is the Euler equation for households; (3) is the Euler equation for entrepreneurs; (4) and (5) are conditions for the optimal contract; (6) is the definition of net worth; (7) is the aggregate production function; (8) is the evolution of aggregate capital; (9) is the budget constraint of entrepreneurs; (10) is the resource constraint; and (11) is the evolution of aggregate productivity. 2.2 Prototype economy with wedges The equilibrium system of the associated prototype economy is as follows: c t ν 1 l = (1 α) ỹt, (12) t l [ t { }] 1 + τ x,t 1 = βe t (1 + τ x,t+1 )(1 δ) + α ỹt+1, (13) c t c t+1 k t+1 ỹ t = Ãt k α t l 1 α t, (14) c t + g t + ĩ t = ỹ t, (15) k t+1 = (1 δ) k t + ĩ t, (16) where Ãt is the efficiency wedge; 1/(1 + τ x,t ) is the investment wedge; and g t is the government wedge. 3 The evolution of s t [Ãt, τ x,t, g t ] is s t+1 = P 0 + P s t + ε t+1. (17) 3 We eliminate the labor wedge following Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2002). 4

2.3 Equivalence result If we interpret i t [ 1 Φ( ωt )µ ] as investment i t of the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy and k t + z t as the total capital stock K t, the following equivalence result holds. 4 Proposition 1 (Equivalence result) The equilibrium allocation of the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy {c t, l t, i t, K t+1, y t } t=0 coincides with that of the prototype model { c t, l t, ĩ t, k t+1, ỹ t } t=0 if A t = Ãt, (18) q t = 1 + τ x,t, (19) e t + i t Φ( ω t )µ + g = g t. (20) The proof is simple. It is easily obtained in a straightforward manner by comparing two equilibrium systems (1) - (11) and (12) - (16). The remaining problem is the existence of the VAR(1) representation of wedges, as discussed in Nutahara and Inaba (2008). In this case, the VAR(1) representation of wedges exists under realistic parameter values since the number of wedges is three and the number of endogenous and exogenous variables in the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy is three. Moreover, Theorems 1 and 2 in Nutahara and Inaba (2008) are satisfied. This proposition states that the equilibrium allocation of the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy is consistent with that of the prototype model if the investment and government wedges fluctuate positively. 3 BCA in the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy First, we generate artificial data from our Carlstrom-Fuerst economy. The parameter values of the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy are as follows. Most variables are taken from Carlstrom and Fuerst (1997, 1998). The discount rate β is.99; the depreciation rate of capital δ,.02; and the persistence of technology ρ,.95. The production share of capital 4 This equivalence result is different from that in Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2002). They construct a prototype economy with a type of adjustment costs of investment. 5

α is.36. The weight of leisure in utility ν is calibrated such that the steady-state labor supply equals.3. The discount rate of entrepreneurs γβ is.973β; the standard deviation of idiosyncratic technology shock σ,.37; and the monitoring cost µ,.15. The steadystate ratio of government purchase to output, g/y, is.1. We approximate the equilibrium system by the log-linearization and employ the method of Uhlig (1999) to calculate the policy functions. We generate 1000 long-period artificial data. Following the standard method of BCA, we measure efficiency, labor, investment, and government wedges so that the prototype model can perfectly account for data of consumption, investment, labor, and output. Then, we obtain wedge decompositions by providing only one wedge. 5 Figure 1 shows the actual output and output prediction with only one wedge. [Insert Figure 1] The contribution of investment wedge to output is rather small and negative. Hence, by the criteria of BCA, the investment wedge is not promising. However, our datagenerating model is the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy, which is one of the representative models with investment frictions. Why does BCA lead us to such a conclusion? One might consider that we mismeasured the investment wedge. Figure 2 shows the model and the measured investment wedges for the first 100 periods. 6 As shown in Figure 2, the investment wedge is measured almost correctly. 7 [Insert Figure 2] This is due to the role of investment wedges. Figure 3 shows the impulse responses to the one percent technology shock in the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy. [Insert Figure 3] 5 The procedure that we employ here will be available from authors upon request. 6 The model investment wedge is obtained by solving the extended equilibrium system (1) - (11) and (13). 7 Other wedges are also measured correctly since they are measured directly under intratemporal conditions. 6

When technology shocks hit the economy, output increases and the investment wedge 1/(1+τ x,t ) decreases, or the distortion in the investment process increases. The important feature of the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy is the hump-shaped impulse response of output to technology shock, which is consistent with the finding of Cogley and Nason (1995). The role of investment wedges is to delay the propagation of shocks. Then, the main driving force of output is the efficiency wedge, and the investment wedge explains deviations from the simple real business cycle model in the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy. BCA cannot capture such a role of investment wedges. 4 Concluding remarks In this paper, we apply BCA to artificial data generated by the model with investment frictions and find that it leads us to conclude that models of investment wedges are not promising according to the criteria of BCA, although the true model contains investment frictions. This is because BCA only focuses on determining whether or not investment wedges are the driving force of business cycles. In the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy, the role of investment wedges is to delay the propagation of technology shocks, which is consistent with empirical facts. BCA cannot capture such a role of investment wedges. Therefore, we have to be careful while interpreting the results of wedge decomposition in BCA. References Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist, 1999, The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework, in: J. Taylor and M. Woodford, eds., Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1C (North-Holland, Amsterdam) 1341-1393. Carlstrom, C. T. and T. S. Fuerst, 1997, Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations: A computable general equilibrium analysis, American Economic Review 87, 893-910. 7

Carlstrom, C. T. and T. S. Fuerst, 1998, Agency costs and business cycles, Economic Theory 12, 583-597. Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan, 2002, Business cycle accounting, Research Department Working Paper 625, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan, 2007, Business cycle accounting, Econometrica 75, 781-836. Cogley, T. and J. M. Nason, 1995, Output dynamics in real-business-cycle models, American Economic Review 85, 492-511. Nutahara, K. and M. Inaba, 2008, On equivalence results in business cycle accounting, Discussion Paper 08-E-020, Research Institute of Economy, Trade, and Industry (RIETI). Uhlig, H., 1999, A toolkit for analyzing nonlinear dynamic stochastic models easily, in: R. Marimon and A. Scott, eds., Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies, (Oxford University Press, Oxford) 8

Figure 1: Output decomposition with one wedge 9

Figure 2: Model and measured investment wedges 10

Figure 3: Impulse responses to one percent technology shock of the Carlstrom-Fuerst economy 11