Bank Power and Cash Holdings: Evidence from Japan

Similar documents
Bank Power and Cash Holdings: Evidence from Japan

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Corporate Liquidity. Amy Dittmar Indiana University. Jan Mahrt-Smith London Business School. Henri Servaes London Business School and CEPR

Cash Holdings in German Firms

International Journal of Asian Social Science OVERINVESTMENT, UNDERINVESTMENT, EFFICIENT INVESTMENT DECREASE, AND EFFICIENT INVESTMENT INCREASE

EURASIAN JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE

Determinant Factors of Cash Holdings: Evidence from Portuguese SMEs

Cash holdings and CEO risk incentive compensation: Effect of CEO risk aversion. Harry Feng a Ramesh P. Rao b

Does Debt Help Managers? Using Cash Holdings to Explain Acquisition Returns

Financial Conservatism: Evidence on Capital Structure from Low Leverage Firms. Bernadette A. Minton and Karen H. Wruck* Draft: July 9, 2001.

Do Persistent Large Cash Reserves Hinder Performance?

The Effect of Financial Constraints, Investment Policy and Product Market Competition on the Value of Cash Holdings

Managerial Incentives and Corporate Cash Holdings

CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT

Why do U.S. firms hold so much more cash than they used to?

Thriving on a Short Leash: Debt Maturity Structure and Acquirer Returns

A STUDY ON THE FACTORS INFLUENCING THE LEVERAGE OF INDIAN COMPANIES

Economic downturn, leverage and corporate performance

Over the last 20 years, the stock market has discounted diversified firms. 1 At the same time,

The Free Cash Flow Effects of Capital Expenditure Announcements. Catherine Shenoy and Nikos Vafeas* Abstract

THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE S DETERMINANT IN FIRM LOCATED IN INDONESIA

Do firms have leverage targets? Evidence from acquisitions

Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow and Bidders Long-run Takeover Performance

The benefits and costs of group affiliation: Evidence from East Asia

MANAGERIAL POWER IN THE DESIGN OF EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION: EVIDENCE FROM JAPAN

C C H F C: A P A R S B 1 J B R B F 2 1. I!"#$%"!

Lecture 1: Introduction, Optimal financing contracts, Debt

The effect of wealth and ownership on firm performance 1

CORPORATE CASH HOLDING AND FIRM VALUE

CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CASH HOLDINGS: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF CHINESE AND INDIAN FIRMS

Capital Structure, Compensation Contracts and Managerial Incentives. Alan V. S. Douglas

Corporate Governance and Cash Holdings: Empirical Evidence. from an Emerging Market

How Markets React to Different Types of Mergers

On Diversification Discount the Effect of Leverage

M&A Activity in Europe

Managerial compensation and the threat of takeover

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

If the market is perfect, hedging would have no value. Actually, in real world,

Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

Long Term Performance of Divesting Firms and the Effect of Managerial Ownership. Robert C. Hanson

How increased diversification affects the efficiency of internal capital market?

Cash Holdings of European Firms

Family Control and Leverage: Australian Evidence

CASH HOLDINGS, LEVERAGE, OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION AND BOARD INDEPENDENCE: EVIDENCE FROM MALAYSIA

An Initial Investigation of Firm Size and Debt Use by Small Restaurant Firms

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

Determinants of Target Capital Structure: The Case of Dual Debt and Equity Issues

The Effects of Capital Infusions after IPO on Diversification and Cash Holdings

TESTING TRADEOFF AND PECKING ORDER PREDICTIONS ABOUT DIVIDENDS AND DEBT. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French *

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

The Joint Determinants of Cash Holdings and Debt Maturity: The Case for Financial Constraints

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Comment on Determinants of Intercorporate Shareholdings

Can the Source of Cash Accumulation Alter the Agency Problem of Excess Cash Holdings? Evidence from Mergers and Acquisitions ABSTRACT

Firm Diversification and the Value of Corporate Cash Holdings

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND THE 2003 TAX CUTS Richard H. Fosberg

Investment opportunities, free cash flow, and stock valuation effects of secured debt offerings

The Determinants of Capital Structure of Stock Exchange-listed Non-financial Firms in Pakistan

Agency costs of free cash flow and the market for corporate control. Suzanne Ching-Fang Lin

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY DO U.S. FIRMS HOLD SO MUCH MORE CASH THAN THEY USED TO? Thomas W. Bates Kathleen M. Kahle Rene M.

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

Corporate Financial Policy and the Value of Cash

Overconfidence or Optimism? A Look at CEO Option-Exercise Behavior

International Review of Economics and Finance

A Comparison of Capital Structure. in Market-based and Bank-based Systems. Name: Zhao Liang. Field: Finance. Supervisor: S.R.G.

TESTING TRADEOFF AND PECKING ORDER PREDICTIONS ABOUT DIVIDENDS AND DEBT. Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French * Abstract

Debt and Taxes: Evidence from a Bank based system

Master Thesis. The Determinants of Cash Holdings: Evidence from Dutch Listed Firms

How Do Firms Finance Large Cash Flow Requirements? Zhangkai Huang Department of Finance Guanghua School of Management Peking University

The Choice Among Bank Debt, Non-Bank Private Debt and Public Debt: Evidence From New Corporate Borrowings *

Investment and Financing Policies of Nepalese Enterprises

Relationship Between Capital Structure and Firm Performance, Evidence From Growth Enterprise Market in China

Cash Flow Sensitivity of Investment: Firm-Level Analysis

The notion that income taxes play an important role in the

Cash Holdings of EU Firms

Capital Market Conditions and the Financial and Real Implications of Cash Holdings *

Firms' Cash Holdings and Performance: Evidence from Japanese corporate finance

Determinants of Capital Structure: A Long Term Perspective

Dividends, Investment, and Financial Flexibility *

Do Auditors Use The Information Reflected In Book-Tax Differences? Discussion

The Journal of Applied Business Research January/February 2009 Volume 25, Number 1

How Does Earnings Management Affect Innovation Strategies of Firms?

The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings

On the Capital Structure of Real Estate Investment Trusts (REITs)

Determinants of Corporate Cash Policy: A Comparison of Public and Private Firms *

Capital Structure. Capital Structure. Konan Chan. Corporate Finance, Leverage effect Capital structure stories. Capital structure patterns

Why Are Japanese Firms Still Increasing Cash Holdings?

Managerial Characteristics and Corporate Cash Policy

wang, liyan (2012) The increase cash holdings of UK public firms. [Dissertation (University of Nottingham only)] (Unpublished)

Organizational Structure and Risk Taking: Evidence from the Life Insurance Industry in Japan

Discussion Paper No. 2002/47 The Benefits and Costs of Group Affiliation. Stijn Claessens, 1 Joseph P.H. Fan 2 and Larry H.P.

What Do Cash Holdings Tell Us about Bank-Firm Relationship? The Case of Japanese Firms

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

U.S. Repatriation Taxes and Corporate Cash Holdings

Managerial Incentives and Corporate Leverage: Evidence from United Kingdom

Appendix: The Disciplinary Motive for Takeovers A Review of the Empirical Evidence

Capital Structure and Financial Performance: Analysis of Selected Business Companies in Bombay Stock Exchange

Advanced Risk Management

Transcription:

Bank Power and Cash Holdings: Evidence from Japan By Lee Pinkowitz and Rohan Williamson* Preliminary: Comments Welcome This Version: May 8, 1998 Abstract Using a sample of firm years from the United States, Germany and Japan, we examine the effect of bank power on the cash holdings of firms. We show that firms in Japan have higher cash holdings than those in the US or Germany, which indicates that there are possible agency problem associated with a bank centered system. Then, through an analysis of the Japanese firms we show that even though the high cash levels persist through time, the determinants of cash holdings changes. During periods of high bank power, firms cash holdings seemed to be consistent with banks extracting rents, yet when the banks became weaker, firms appear to hold cash for precautionary reasons. We conclude that there are costs associated with a bank centered monitoring system, especially if there are no other monitors, such as large non-bank blockholders. * Ph.D Candidate, The Ohio State University and Assistant Professor, Georgetown University, respectively. We would like to thank René Stulz for his invaluable comments and suggestions. We thank Jim Angel, Allan Eberhart, Jeff Harris, Jarrad Harford, Jan Jindra, Bernadette Minton, Sonya Williams-Stanton and Yishay Yafeh for helpful comments. We also thank seminar participants at The Ohio State University. Previous versions of this paper appeared under the title Governance Structures and Financing Behavior: An International Perspective. We alone are responsible for any errors.

1. Introduction In the corporate finance literature, one of the major issues is the reduction of the many forms of agency costs that exist between the various stakeholders of the firm. These agency costs are described in many studies, most notable of these are the seminal papers of Jensen and Meckling (1976), Myers and Majluf (1984) and Jensen (1986). In the US system, these agency problems arose from a corporate governance system in which there exists a separation of ownership and control resulting in conflicts between the various groups of stakeholders with differing objectives. One of the primary agency related issues, especially in recent history, is the amount of cash and marketable securities that should be held by a firm. The basic criticism of a US type system is that with non-active atomistic shareholders there may not be optimal monitoring of managers, thus creating less than optimal activities by these skilled managers of the firm. The basic implication is that a better system may be one in which there are larger more active stakeholders who are able to effectively monitor the actions of the managers. Banks and financial institutions are traditionally thought to be such monitors via their control over credit. This paper addresses the issue of whether a system in which banks wield significant influence can induce more optimal cash holdings by firms. More importantly, does simply allowing banks to act as the main source of monitoring result in higher cash holdings and how will bank power affect firms cash holdings? Agency problems can result in undesirable management activities such as holding too much cash, consuming excess perquisites, foregoing positive NPV projects, and overinvestment. There has 1 been an extensive amount of financial economics literature examining these potential problems. Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that the separation of ownership and control creates costs from both equity 1 Although there are many papers that discuss these issues, we choose to focus on the main papers. 2

and debt issues, while Myers and Majluf (1984) examine the case of information asymmetry between managers and shareholders. Since external financing can be costly, it seems only logical that firms would prefer to finance projects solely from internal funds and operating cash flow. This is the pecking order theory of Myers (1984), it implies that firms should maintain cash in order to take advantage of positive NPV projects and the level of cash changes with these investment opportunities. Jensen (1986) points out that excess cash could result in free cash flow, which he defines as cash remaining after all positive NPV projects have been taken by the firm. Thus, Jensen argues, free cash flow should not only be returned to the shareholders, but precautionary steps need to be taken in order to prevent firms from building up free cash in the first place. These arguments reflect agency costs associated with a US based system of corporate governance and financing in which the capital markets act as the primary corporate monitor. An examination of other governance systems can help shed light on the effect of banks as monitors on firms cash holdings. To address this issue empirically, we use a sample of firms from the US, Japan, and Germany. The governance system in Japan is characterized by a closely held ownership structure in which firms in an industrial group (keiretsu) hold shares of other keiretsu firms. Additionally, there is normally a large (main) bank at the center of this system. The German system is one where banks have significant ownership and even greater voting control in most of the large manufacturing firms. German firms frequently have one or more large blockholders via a system of pyramided holdings. The ultimate holder of the large blocks is most often a family group or another corporation (Franks and Mayer(1997)). In both systems, the large external stakeholder takes a more active role in the management of the firm than in the US. The existence of the large active stakeholder acting as monitor 3

2 in Germany and Japan should lead to a reduction in agency costs. In particular we are concerned with the agency costs associated with a firm s cash holdings. Based on previous work, with the reduction in agency costs brought about by bank ownership, one should expect to see German and Japanese firms holding lower levels of cash, ceteris paribus. Theoretically, this is due to the near equality in costs of internal and external financing. A deviation could result if we have a situation in which the main bank that is charged with monitoring has monopoly power. If this were the case we may observe higher cash holdings in order for these banks to extract rents or lower the costs of monitoring. Banks had this kind of monopoly power in Japan during the period after the second world war through the 1970's. The results of the paper are consistent with the bank power hypothesis. We find that Japanese firms hold significantly higher levels of cash to assets than do firms from the US or Germany. Also, Japanese firms show greater persistence in levels of cash than the United States. Firms from Germany exhibit lower levels of cash holdings which is consistent with the external block holder acting to counteract the power of the banks. We then explore this interesting result through a detailed evaluation of Japanese firms cash holdings. One reason Japanese firms might hold so much cash is that due to the bank centered keiretsu relation of the firms, they may be encouraged to deposit excess cash with the banks rather than paying it out as dividends. In contrast, the large block holder in the German system would prefer dividends in order to profit from their holdings. This in addition to a two-tiered board composition may lessen banks power and prevent them from being able to encourage a firm to hold excess cash. Also, 2 However, the German evidence in Franks and Mayer (1997) is not consistent with the idea that large shareholders are acting as diligent monitors, which may be due to the multiple layers of corporate holdings. They find that block shareholding is not significantly related to board turnover for firms with poor operating performance. 4

Germany has a 50 percent tax rate for funds that are not paid out to shareholders compared to a 36 percent rate for funds that are to be paid out, which may further result in the low level of cash. Another interesting result is that even though the Japanese firms have relatively high levels of cash they also have high levels of debt, which lends support to the idea that Japanese banks may prefer firms to hoard cash rather than use it to pay down their debt. The implication is that there appears to be agency costs of the bank centered system that are not present in a system in which the capital markets act as the chief monitor. We evaluate the cash holdings of the Japanese firms through time, since the power of the Japanese main banks decreased, especially during the late 1980's and into the 1990's. Consistent with the bank power arguments, Japanese firms held significantly higher levels of cash during the 1970's than during the late 80's and 90's, along with significantly higher levels of debt. The cash holding during the later years is still relatively high, but closer to US levels. More interesting, the debt levels were significantly lower in the later period. This is supportive of our arguments that during the 70's, Japanese firms held cash in order to generate rents for the banks. In the later period when the banking system weakened, since capital markets were not as developed as in the US, firms began to hold cash for precautionary reasons. These arguments parallel those in Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz and Williamson (1998) [hereafter OPSW]. This paper contributes to the financial economics literature in several areas. First, it expands the work on the cash level or optimal cash balances a firm should maintain which is examined in recent papers such as OPSW (1998) and Harford (1997). It also advances the work on the liquidity of firms with varying ownership structures (see for instance, Hoshi, Kashyap and Scharfstein (1991)). Additionally, it documents the effect of the strength of the banking system in Japan on non-bank firms, 5

this is complementary to the findings in Kang and Stulz (1997) and Weinstein and Yafeh (1998). Finally, it enhances the understanding and evaluation of the most popular corporate governance systems, which has policy implications for emerging market economies, especially in those countries that are undertaking a large privatization program. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present a theoretical discussion of the predictions of the various governance systems as it pertains to a firms cash balance. Section 3 uses the theoretical discussion to derive the empirical predictions. In Section 4 the data are described along with our methodology, while the determinants of cash holdings across the three countries are presented in Section 5. In section 6 we take a closer look at the Japanese system and the changes in determinants of cash holdings across time. Section 7 concludes along with some general implications for various systems of corporate governance. 2. Corporate Governance Systems and Cash Holdings Access to the capital markets is a major concern for firms in any country. However, in the US, this should be a more significant concern than in Germany or Japan. A US firm which requires external financing can rely on either debt or equity, but both have an information asymmetry problem which may prevent financing from being obtained. Myers and Majluf (1984) examine the case of information asymmetry between managers and shareholders. Their model shows that if managers act in the interests of existing shareholders, there are times at which they would prefer to forego a profitable project simply because the cost imposed by the information asymmetry outweighs the benefits of taking the project. As a result, they argue that firms prefer to issue safer securities before riskier ones and thus firms desire financial slack. 6

There are costs associated with informational asymmetries and lending (see for instance Leland and Pyle (1977) and Diamond (1984)). Lenders must first decide whether or not to grant credit to a firm. This decision requires that the lender be able to determine the true credit quality of the firm. Assuming that there are several types of borrowers, poorer credit risks will attempt to pool with better credit risks in order to obtain financing. Thus, the lender must incur a cost associated with discovering the firm s true credit quality. In some cases, identifying a firm s quality may be so difficult that the lender may simply ration credit (see Stiglitz and Weiss (1981)). In a competitive market, those lenders who are best able to determine the credit quality of the firm, (i.e. accurately and cheaply) will survive while others will fail. Clearly, the higher the level of informational asymmetry between the firm and the lender, the more difficult it will be for the lender to ascertain the firm s credit quality. Because of this asymmetry in lending and the possibility of credit rationing by banks, firms may decide to hold high levels of cash for precautionary reasons. This is consistent with the results in Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz and Williamson (1998). Firms may hold high levels of cash so they can survive times of tight credit and still be able to take advantage of positive NPV projects. Jensen (1986) cautions about the agency costs associated with firms holding too much cash. He refers to this as the costs associated with free cash flow. Compared to the US, in Japan and Germany, where banks are closely connected with the operations of the firms to which they lend, it is likely that the cost of determining credit quality will be lower. Since bank officials are often members of the firm s board and perhaps its management team, they are able to observe the firm s operations on a relatively frequent basis and are able to assess the firm s credit quality prior to a financing need. Additionally, firms within a group or keiretsu often share human capital and information. Banks 7

tend to be at the center of these groups and not only finance firms through debt, but hold equity as well. Therefore, the Japanese system of governance differs from the US in several ways which should impact the problems associated with informational asymmetries and free cash flow. This situation is analogous to the recent literature on small firms and bank relationships in the US. Smaller firms tend to have larger informational asymmetries, but Petersen and Rajan (1994) show that small firms which have a lending relationship with a bank are more likely to have access to credit than those without such relationships. However, credit quality is not the only concern for lenders. Lenders must be concerned about the risk of asset substitution when they provide debt to a firm. Typically in the US, restrictive debt covenants are used to preclude shareholders from undertaking a higher risk program. As Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue, one way to resolve this potential agency conflict is to have stakeholders own proportionate shares of debt and equity, essentially strip financing. However, since US banks are very limited in their ability to hold equity, this resolution is unavailable. This is not the case in Germany and 3 Japan, though, where the banks not only can, but do hold equity in the firms to which they lend. By holding equity, the German and Japanese banks are protected against this type of risk substitution because they are shareholders as well as lenders. 4 In sum, in the US, lenders not only face the problem of assessing credit quality, but they are also subject to asset substitution. In Germany, the ability of the banks to hold equity reduces the threat of asset substitution and their power to elect half of the supervisory board can also lessen informational 3 There are limits on the amount equity a bank can hold in a firm in Japan but this is not binding since there is such a complex web of cross holdings across firms and banks. Through these cross holdings, a bank can effectively have control over a higher percentage of share than is formally allowed by law. 4 However, Parrino and Weisbach (1998) show that the magnitudes of stockholder-bondholder conflicts appears to be small in the US. 8

asymmetries. In Japan, the keiretsu and main bank structure allows for the reduction of both informational asymmetries as well as a lower risk of asset substitution. The active participation of the main bank and the web of cross ownership should lead to much lower agency costs from asset substitution, asymmetric information and free cash flow. 3. Theoretical Predictions for Cash Holdings The focus of this study is what do the differences in governance structures imply about a firm s cash holdings. For the remainder of this analysis, let us assume that the pecking order holds so that if firms need external finance, they will use debt first (see Myers (1984)). Consider a US firm which has considerable growth opportunities but may not be able to finance them through operating cash flow. The firm can elect to build up a cash reserve in the event that cash flow is insufficient to cover investment or it can elect to pay out its cash and go to the capital markets if it needs additional financing. In the previous section, we argue that US banks have to overcome considerable asymmetries 5 in order to lend to firms, especially if they do not have a prior lending relationship. In addition to the informational asymmetry, there are other agency costs to contend with. Since the bank cannot hold equity, not only do they need to be concerned about risk substitution, but the fact that the firm s project may be foregone does not provide any further incentive for the bank to lend. Thus it seems as though US firms would be better off holding proportionately more cash for precautionary motives. 6 5 In this section, we discuss the problems that US banks face, but the discussion generalizes to other creditors. Bondholders have to assess the risk of default when deciding whether or not to purchase bonds and they are at risk of asset substitution, thus the fact that US firms do not have to rely solely on banks does not materially affect our argument. Although bondholders can hold equity, wealth constraints are likely to make strip financing difficult. 6 Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz, and Williamson (1998) provide evidence which is consistent with US firms holding cash for precautionary reasons. 9

On the other hand, since the German and Japanese banks have fewer information asymmetries to overcome, agency costs should be rather low. Thus we would expect that non-bank firms in those countries would need to hold very little cash. This is expected to be the case since not only are banks better able to determine the credit quality of the firm, but their equity share will protect them against asset substitution as well allow them to participate in any gain from a profitable project. Hence, foregone investment projects are costly to the foreign banks and provide even further incentive to lend. Cross-sectionally, we would expect US firms to hold a greater proportion of their assets in a liquid form relative to Japanese and German firms. On the surface, it is not apparent that there should be a significant difference in the cash holdings of the German versus the Japanese firms. Japanese banks own less stock than do their German counterparts and due to the voting rules, they have far less voting control than do German banks. The Japanese system provides the main bank with significant structural control and monitoring authority that is unequaled by the German system which may lead to banks exerting monopoly control as argued by Weinstein and Yafeh (1998). In the next section we will discuss the impact of the subtle differences between the two systems and their effect on the cash holdings of firms. 3.1. Cash holdings: Germany vs. Japan German banks have more direct voting control than do the Japanese banks, therefore we will first look the potential effect of voting on cash holdings. Stulz (1988) shows that managerial voting rights can impact the value of the firm through its impact on tender offers. However, in the German market, tender offers are all but nonexistent as shown in Lightfoot and Kester (1992). Can it be the case that German banks affect the cash holdings of the firm? To see this more clearly, consider the 10

case where a German bank has a large stake in a firm, for example, Deutsche Bank s 28 percent holding in Daimler Benz. It is likely that they control voting rights for many more shares. Assume for the sake of argument that the bank maintains voting control over 40 percent of the outstanding shares. Although they do not have total control over the firm, it is easy to argue that they exert significant effective control. We have already argued that in such a case there is little need for precautionary cash reserves since the bank is very likely to lend if the firm needed financing for a profitable project. Thus, we would expect the firm to have very little in the way of cash reserves. Any cash that the firm generates should be returned to shareholders via dividends or share repurchases. However, there is a potential agency problem that arises which is not common under the US system. Consider the incentives of the German bank. If they push for a dividend payment, then they will receive 28 percent of the cash which they can invest in other projects. Since a bank s projects are essentially making loans, this means that they can lend a portion (depending on reserve requirements) of the 28 percent at a market rate of interest. However, if instead, the bank persuades the firm to maintain a large cash reserve and hold that reserve in accounts on deposit at the bank, then they have access to 100 percent of the potential dividends which they can lend. If the bank is required to pay taxes on its dividend distribution, then this would give further incentive to the bank to pursue such action. One way that this agency cost can be avoided is if there are other large active shareholders who would prefer the dividend payment. Jenkinson and Ljungqvist (1997) argue that hostile stakes in shares are more active than previously believed. They argue that even though there is not an active tender offer market there is takeover activity between the groups of large blockholders. The banks are not active in these actions and take a more passive role than previously believed. There exists another reason that banks may encourage firms to which they lend to hold large 11

amounts of cash. Although equity ownership decreases the risks of asset substitution, banks typically hold more of a firm s debt than its equity. This is more like the situation prevalent in the Japanese system. By keeping a large reserve of cash on hand, the firm reduces its risk of default and thus increases the value of the debt. In the main bank system of Japan, the bank is expected to support the 7 firm if encounters financial difficulty. Hoshi, Kashyap and Sharfstein (1990) show that firms with strong main bank ties tend to invest more and sell more than firms without these strong ties when they face financial distress. They conclude that a main bank relationship either overcomes the free-rider problem and allows efficient renegotiation or that the main bank simply refuses to allow one of its group to fail due to a reputation issue. At times, main banks have fulfilled the liabilities of its borrowers to outside entities which implies that a firm s default may be more costly for a Japanese bank than a US or German bank since the Japanese bank stands to lose not only the loans it made to the firm, but may also face costs associated with loss of reputation or explicit costs associated with honoring the firm s liabilities. With default being a more costly state, we would expect to see Japanese banks take precautions to avoid it, which may include requiring large cash holdings from the firm. There is an additional consideration in this idea, which is especially valid for Japanese banks. If a bank persuades a firm to hold a large level of cash, it is reasonable to assume that the firm will not need to obtain debt financing from the bank as often as they would if the firm paid out its cash. Thus, the bank incurs a cost by encouraging cash holdings, namely the loss of potential loans to those firms. Thus, Japanese banks which are large shareholders or which have considerable control seem to face a tradeoff between encouraging the firm to hold cash and paying the cash out as dividends. The 7 Aoki, Patrick and Sheard (1994) discuss the Japanese main bank system and the responsibilities of the main bank. 12

tradeoff is that with large cash holdings, banks have more funds to lend to the general market than if it relied only on dividend income; however, the cash rich firm will not need to borrow as much. The ideal situation for the bank is if the cash rich firm decides to hoard the cash and use bank financing for its positive NPV projects. This situation can only occur if the banks have monopoly power and thus can extract rents from the firms. The ability of banks to extract rents when it has monopoly power is similar to the argument presented in Petersen and Rajan (1995). Petersen and Rajan (1995) show that the rents banks can extract tend to be directly related to how competitive the market for financing is in the city where a firm is located. This argument is similar to the idea of bank centered groups. Weinstein and Yafeh (1998) discuss evidence of this result in the Japanese main bank system. The main bank can extract rents through many mechanisms such as compensating balances, investment banking services and cash management services to the firm. Therefore, if the Japanese system provides the main bank with monopoly power, the banks may persuade the firms to hold higher levels of cash than would be expected based on a US agency cost consideration. Finally, taxes may affect the level of cash that is held by these firms. The German tax rate (36%) is higher than the US (34% for all profits) or Japanese (35%) tax rates, however, profits that are not set aside for distribution to stockholders are taxed at a 50 percent rate in Germany, while it is 40 percent in Japan for profits not distributed to shareholders. The tax differential seems to give Germany and Japan greater incentive to pay out its earnings to shareholders rather than holding it internally. 3.2. Summary of Predictions Based on the classical agency cost arguments presented previously, we expect that US firms 13

should have larger cash holdings than Japanese or German firms. This may not be the case if, as argued in the previous sub-section, the German or Japanese banks can exert monopoly power and extract rents by persuading the firms to have a higher than optimal cash balance. The large nonbank shareholder in Germany may act to mitigate the power of the large banks, thus leading to more optimal cash holdings. In the Japanese system, there is no clear force counteracting the possible monopoly power of the main bank. This may outweigh any possible benefits of the main bank system over a market based system of monitoring firm cash holdings. The level of this monopoly power and thus rent extraction activity will be important in determining the cash holdings of firms in these governance systems. The rest of this study will shed some light on this issue. 4. Data and Methodology We use the PACAP files of all Japanese firms from 1974-1995 for our analysis. For German data, we use COMPUSTAT s Global Vantage database from 1984-1994. All raw variables are winsorized at the 1 percent tails. In this paper, for the US and Germany, cash refers to cash and marketable securities. In Japan, since there are significant cross holdings of shares of other firms, cash refers only to cash as reported in the PACAP database. This should bias our results toward finding that Japanese firms have lower cash holdings than firms in the US or Germany. Since we are trying to examine the effect of cash, we deflate all variables by assets minus cash which we refer to as net assets following OPSW (1998). The US firm data is the same data set used in OPSW containing COMPUSTAT firm years from 1971-1994. 8 8 We have also examined our results using only the 1984-1994 period in order to keep the time periods similar across countries. Additionally, changes in Japan s laws made external debt financing easier for firms in the early 80's (see Weinstein and Yafeh (1998) for details). Our results are not materially different using the more restrictive sub-period. 14

We use the year end Japanese consumer price index (including imputed rent) to deflate total assets to 1994 Yen. To calculate total assets in 1994 dollars, we use the average monthly exchange rate for the dollar to the yen during 1994. Size is the natural logarithm of total assets, thus real size is the value of the logarithm of total assets based on 1994 US dollars. The German data is manipulated similarly using the CPI from West Germany, obtained from CITIBASE. Since we are concerned with free cash flow as well as potential underinvestment, we need to examine a firm s investment policy. For the US data, OPSW rely on the flow of funds statements, however, we do not have access to this data for Japanese and German firms. In order to proxy for capital expenditures, we use the annual change in net fixed assets to which we add back depreciation charges. Roughly 4 percent of the Japanese firm years we examine have negative capital expenditures using this proxy. For Germany, roughly 18 percent of the firm years have negative capital expenditures. We use the market to book ratio to proxy for a firm s growth opportunities, since the value of growth options are not included in a firm s book value, but should be reflected in its market value (see for instance Smith and Watts (1992), Jung, Kim and Stulz (1996), and Barclay and Smith (1995)). Market to book is defined as book value of assets - book value of equity + market value of equity / total assets. We define a firm s cash flow as income from operations + depreciation charges - interest and discount charges - income taxes - cash dividends, while total leverage is defined as long-term debt + short-term debt divided by total assets. Since we need to control for alternative sources of liquidity, we also examine net working capital, which we define as current assets - current liabilities - cash. Thus, net working capital is examined without the impact of cash included in it. For Japan, bank holdings are calculated using shares owned by financial institutions divided by 15

total shares outstanding. In this paper, we will refer to all financial institutions as banks. COMPUSTAT Global Vantage does not have financial institution holdings for Germany, hence we do not have bank ownership data in German firms. We also use measures to proxy for the structure of interest rates in Japan. We define the average level of the 3 month Gensaki rate each year to proxy for the risk free rate for that year. We also proxy for a default premium using the difference between the average long term prime lending rate and the average rate on long term government bonds. Additionally, we calculate the term spread using the average long term prime rate less the average short term prime rate. All these variables are obtained from the key monthly economic statistics file from the PACAP tapes. 5.0 Cash Holdings: A Cross Country Analysis Table 1 shows summary statistics for the three countries. Panel A shows Japanese firm years from 1974-1995, Panel B includes German firm years from 1984-1994, and Panel C contains US firm years from 1971-1994. The first thing to notice is that Japanese firms hold a greater percentage of their assets in cash. On average, they hold 18.5 percent of net assets in cash, which is slightly greater than the US, but remember that for the US the cash includes marketable securities while in Japan it only includes liquid cash. Japan is also 50 percent greater than the mean for Germany s cash and marketable securities. The results are more striking when we compare the medians. The median Japanese firm holds roughly two and one half times the amount of cash that the median German or US firm does. This is an interesting result since the Japanese firms have significant cross holdings and are monitored by banks as well as other firms that own its debt and equity. However, this is consistent with the idea that the monopoly power of the Japanese main bank system may allow the banks to extract rents from 16

their borrowers by persuading them to hold high levels of cash. We also notice that when we examine the quartiles of cash, Germany and the US seem relatively similar. We also see that the foreign firms in our sample are larger than the US firm years. Real size in 1994 dollars for Japan and Germany is about 50 percent larger than the US firm years. This makes the higher cash holdings of Japanese firms even more surprising since smaller firms are more likely to hold higher levels of cash. Therefore, any bias our sample creates would tend to be towards the US cash holdings being overstated. Market to book ratios appear to be similar across countries, while net working capital to net assets is dramatically different. German firms tend to have high levels of net working capital to assets while Japanese firms have very low levels, with more than half of the firm years characterized by negative net working capital. This may simply reflect the fact that Japanese firms are well known for not holding large stocks of inventory. We also notice that US firms are the most highly levered which is not surprising given the development of the US capital markets for debt. Japanese firms are not very different from US firms although they are slightly less levered, while German firms seem to carry relatively little debt. Another interesting observation is that although Japanese firms seem best able to pay cash dividends, they pay the least, with the average German firm paying out 80 times the level of the average Japanese firm. This is consistent with the idea that the large non-bank blockholders in Germany push for higher dividends since, unlike banks, they do not benefit from large cash holdings. US firms tend to fall in the middle. One of the reasons for holding cash as given by OPSW (1998) is to smooth out the fluctuations of internally generated cash flow. Industry sigma is the mean of the standard deviation of cash flow to assets for 20 (10) years for Japanese and US (German) firms for each year in each industry. Industry 17

is defined as 2 digit SIC code for Germany and the US and 2 digit industry code (INDID) from PACAP for Japan. This variable proxies for the volatility of cash flows and shows that there are dramatic differences among the countries. Although Japan and Germany have similar levels of cash flow volatility, US firms experience a much higher degree of volatility. On average, US firms face a cash flow volatility about 4 times as large as its foreign competitors. Clearly, for precautionary reasons, it seems as though the US firms have the incentive to hold larger amounts of liquid assets. Additionally, the larger volatility in the US should create incentive for banks to require larger cash balances since the risk of default is higher. Strangely, we do not see this, however, debt covenants may be taking the place of large cash balances. Since the role of the keiretsu in Japan may play a significant role in the cash holdings of firms, 9 we have a sample of firms that are a part of a keiretsu. In our sample 48% of Japanese firms are part of a keiretsu. To this point, our discussion of the differences among countries has not included any statistical analysis; however, when we conduct tests for the difference in means and medians, we find that almost all of the variables are statistically different from each other at the 1% level. 10 OPSW argue that US firms target levels of cash. They show that cash balances are mean reverting with the median coefficient of an autoregression on lagged change in cash to assets of -0.242. In Figure 1, we provide similar analyses for German and Japanese firms. For 1,574 Japanese firms, the average beta coefficient is -0.2111 while for 239 German firms the average beta coefficient is -0.267. Thus, it seems that in all three countries, cash balances mean revert at approximately the same rate. 9 We would like to thank Jun-Koo Kang and René Stulz for providing us with the sample of Japanese keiretsu firms. 10 Median cash and market to book are insignificantly different between Germany and the US. Results are available upon request. 18

This lends support to the idea that in each country firms have a target level of liquid assets which they migrate toward at roughly the same rate. This seems a bit surprising in light of the significant differences among countries observed in Table 1. The question which remains is whether or not there are differences in the determinants of the target level of cash among the three countries. 5.1 Determinants of cash holdings Among the three countries, there are considerable differences in the governance systems and thus we might expect firms in each country to have distinctive determinants of cash holdings. Panel regressions of the cash holdings across the full sample and on a country specific level are shown in Table 2. Since OPSW find persistence in cash holdings which likely indicates a violation of the independently and identically distributed errors assumption, we use the Fama-MacBeth (1973) methodology. Each year, we run cross-sectional regressions and then use the time series of the regression coefficients to make our inferences. The independent variables are as described in the previous section. There are some interesting findings in the results which are not consistent with what one may predict based on the assumptions developed in previous studies. For the full sample of all countries, we find that market to book, cash flow/net assets and R&D/sales all increase with an increase in the cash level of the firms and are consistent with the results from OPSW for the US. Net working capital/assets, firm size, and the dividend dummy are all negative which is again consistent with the US findings. The regression in column 1 shows that there is a significant country specific component to the cash holdings of these firms. Consistent with the univariate results, the Japan dummy variable is highly significant indicating that Japanese firms hold more cash even after controlling for fundamental factors. What is a bit interesting is that the German 19

dummy also is significantly positive. In order to use all available information we run a pooled timeseries cross-section regression for all countries (column 2). To control for any macroeconomic events we include yearly dummies which are unreported. The inferences do not change greatly with this specification, except that Industry Sigma and Capex/Assets are no longer significant. Since there are significant differences in the determinants of cash holdings across countries, we run individual regressions for the sample of firms from each of the three countries. These results are shown in columns 3-6 of the same table. Some interesting findings result from evaluating the country specific samples. First, in Germany the evidence shows that larger firms hold more cash, while the opposite is true for Japan and the US. Another interesting finding for the German firms is that net working capital is insignificant, whereas in the other countries it is significantly negative. However, due to the limited sample size, we have lower power to reject in the German regressions. Even though cash flow is significant for both the US and Japan they are of opposite signs, with the US increasing and Japan decreasing in cash. A possible explanation for this is that due to the keiretsu relationships, high cash flow firms may be funded by the high cash but low cash flow firms within the keiretsu. This is also supported by the results on capital expenditures, in which the US and German firms both show a significant increase in capital expenditures as cash increases but the Japanese firms have a significantly negative relation. This argument is analogous to the recent evidence by Shin and Stulz (1997) regarding the behavior of the internal capital market. Although this seems inconsistent with the market to book results which indicate that firms with good investment opportunities hold more cash in order to take advantage of them, it is not necessarily inconsistent if the high growth firms are being funded by the banks within the keiretsu. To test the impact of keiretsu membership on the cash holdings of the firms, we include a 20

dummy variable for keiretsu membership. Firms that are members of a keiretsu hold less cash than non-member firms. This result is consistent with Hoshi, Kashyap and Sharfstein (1991) who show that keiretsu firms are less liquidity constrained than non-group firms. Contrary to the results from the US, Japanese and German firms that pay dividends tend to have higher levels of cash. This might signify that dividends, in the US, are a mechanism firms use to avoid building up free cash flow, as Jensen (1986) argues, while dividends in Japan and Germany are used to return cash to shareholders in the event of unusually profitable years. This is consistent with the findings of Dewenter and Warther (1997) who show that dividends are less sticky in Japan than they are in the US. Clearly, for all three countries, firms with higher leverage hold less cash which is again consistent with Jensen s argument. In column 4, we run a Fama-MacBeth specification for Japan in order to address the econometric issues mentioned previously. Again, we find that the inferences are materially unchanged. Clearly, Japanese firms hold more cash than firms in the US or Germany. Also, the determinants of their cash holdings lead to some interesting questions. The somewhat surprising cash holdings of these firms could be a result of the ability of the Japanese banks to extract rents from firms by persuading them to hold high levels of cash. Alternatively, the main bank in Japan may encourage firms to hold high levels of cash in order to lower the probability of financial distress for these firms. This could be driven by the high cost of the firm s financial distress to the main bank. Further tests are needed to determine why Japanese firms hold high levels of cash. 6.0 Japanese Firms and Cash We have established that firms in Japan have cash holdings that are inconsistent with previous 21

work regarding the motives that account for cash holdings in the US. The Japanese main bank system provides for powers that are beyond those in other industrialized countries. Additionally, the keiretsu relations may provide for unusual behavior by these firms. This main bank system was in its heyday of power beginning after the second world war and continued until the mid 1970's when regulatory changes in Japan resulted in the opening of the Japanese markets that made it easier for firms to raise financing. This regulatory change took effect around 1980 and led to a gradual change in the make-up of the financial structure. In the late 1980's the Japanese financial system started going through turmoil. Combined with the strong growth and profitability of Japanese manufacturing firms in the mid to late 1980's, this may have resulted in a relative weakening of the Japanese main bank system. One would expect that these changes would have a significant effect on the cash holdings of Japanese firms. With a strong monopolistic banking system and rent extraction, we might expect firms to have not only high cash holdings, but also relatively high levels of debt. When the banking system weakened and its monopoly power decreased, firms may have found themselves able to change their cash holding behavior. With weak banks that may not have been able to guarantee financing, firms may have decided to reduce their debt while maintaining high levels of cash in order to take advantage of future investment opportunities. This is consistent with the precautionary motive for holding cash as shown in OPSW. In the rest of the paper we investigate how cash holdings in Japan changed across time. To evaluate this more clearly and account for any time series effects we will focus on two subsamples. The early period, 1974-1981, was characterized by significant bank power, while 1988-1995 was the period in which the financial system weakened. The middle years are assumed to be a transition period and are eliminated from our tests. Regressions of the sub-periods are shown in Panel B of Table 2. The regressions show that 22

there are differences in the determinants of cash across the periods. Specifically, cash flow/ assets and leverage are not significant during the first subperiod, but are significantly negative in the latter. We also find that the coefficient on capital expenditures is significantly negative during the early sub-period but insignificant during the later period. The leverage coefficients are particularly interesting. With powerful banks, the firms cash holdings and leverage may have been dictated by the banks and thus we may not expect to see any relation between them. This is the evidence in the early period. However, if firms were allowed to select their leverage and cash holdings, as with the US, we would expect to find an inverse relationship. This is precisely what we observe in the later period. Additionally, we find that R&D / sales is not significant during the first period but is positive and significant during the later years. This is consistent with firms moving towards holding cash for precautionary reasons. Firms with more investment projects would hold higher levels of cash in order to take advantage of them without having to rely on outside financing. The market to book coefficients also support this since in the later period, the coefficient is nearly three times as large as in the early period. These differences lend support to the idea that bank power weakened across the sub-periods and that the reason that Japanese firms held cash changed across time. 6.1 Bank ownership and cash To examine the idea that bank power can affect cash holdings, we examine the level of stock ownership in a firm by financial institutions. It is reasonable to assume that the higher the level of bank ownership, the more power the bank wields over the firm. However, when bank ownership is very high, then the banks begin to bear the brunt of the agency costs and thus we might expect to see a nonlinear relationship between bank ownership and agency costs. 23

To test whether firms with very high bank ownership act differently from firms with lower bank ownership, we run univariate tests on the Japanese firms. Table 3 shows these results for the early subperiod when bank power was high (Panel A) and the latter period when bank power decreased (Panel B). Panel C shows the p-values for difference of mean and medians tests between the two sub-periods. We find that in the early period, firms in the lowest quartile of bank ownership have a higher cash level than firms in the highest quartile. The level of cash declines as the level of bank ownership increases. In the later period, there is not a clear relation between bank ownership and cash. We argued that with higher bank power, we might observe firms holding not only more cash, but have higher leverage as well. We see that in the early period, firms hold considerably higher levels of cash, while at the same time being more highly levered. This seems consistent with the idea that banks not only had more power in the early period, but exerted its influence. However, since we are interested in whether banks persuade firms to hold too much cash, we use the residual of the first pass regression from Table 2 which we refer to as excess cash. Interestingly there is evidence of a switching point in the excess cash level of the firms as we go from the second to the third quartile of bank ownership in the early period. The firms that hold the most excess cash are in the second quartile of bank ownership which could be consistent with the findings of Stulz (1988) and Shleifer and Vishny (1986) on the optimal insider ownership of a firm. The U- shaped results do not seem to hold when we examine the latter period when bank power decreased. However, we do see that firms held higher levels of excess cash in the latter period which could be consistent with the idea that the impetus behind firms holding cash changed over time. These results do not appear to be driven by internal cash flows since cash flow to assets is similar at the highest and lowest levels of bank ownership for both sub-periods. Additionally, there is 24

no difference in cash flow to assets across time, so that doesn t explain the increase in excess cash through time. Also consistent with these firms hoarding cash is the fact that market to book first decreases then increases with bank ownership, with the minimum occurring in the third quartile. However, this relationship is observed in both periods. We can interpret this as evidence that high bank ownership provides effective monitoring, but the benefit may not be monotonic. Cash dividends are decreasing in bank ownership which seems to be contrary to our argument that banks with low ownership might encourage cash holdings rather than cash dividends. However, there are two caveats to this result. First, Table 3 only presents a univariate analysis and thus there may be interactions that are not accounted for. Second, it may simply be that for Japanese firms with low bank ownership, the control is not in the hands of the banks, but rather in either the open market or more likely the other firms in the keiretsu. This would be the case in a vertical keiretsu in which the controlling firm is not a bank, but a large manufacturing firm. In either case, the emphasis would be on the payment of dividends rather than on cash holdings. We argued that banks might prefer firms to hold cash in order to lessen the riskiness of the firm, especially since in Japan, the costs to the banks of a firm s financial distress are substantial. One way to examine this is to look at the volatility of operating cash flows in each period. Cash flow sigma is the standard deviation of operating cash flows for a 20 year period. Although the measure crosses the two subperiods, it should give us an idea of the firm s risk. We see that cash flow sigma is decreasing in bank ownership in both periods which is consistent with banks persuading firms to take on less risky projects. However, we also see that in the later period, cash flow sigma is higher which is indicative of the firm taking on greater risk after the bank power decreased. We see similar evidence with capital expenditures. Although mainly decreasing in bank ownership, they are higher in the later years. 25