Department of Social Systems and Management. Discussion Paper Series

Similar documents
Application of the Collateralized Debt Obligation (CDO) Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in the Classical Newsboy Problem

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

A Newsvendor Model with Initial Inventory and Two Salvage Opportunities

The Stigler-Luckock model with market makers

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

e-companion ONLY AVAILABLE IN ELECTRONIC FORM

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

Forecast Horizons for Production Planning with Stochastic Demand

Handout 8: Introduction to Stochastic Dynamic Programming. 2 Examples of Stochastic Dynamic Programming Problems

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

TWO-STAGE NEWSBOY MODEL WITH BACKORDERS AND INITIAL INVENTORY

Revenue Management Under the Markov Chain Choice Model

Credit Risk Models with Filtered Market Information

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Characterization of the Optimum

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Casino gambling problem under probability weighting

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Advanced Risk Management

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

δ j 1 (S j S j 1 ) (2.3) j=1

Journal of Computational and Applied Mathematics. The mean-absolute deviation portfolio selection problem with interval-valued returns

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Technical Appendix to Long-Term Contracts under the Threat of Supplier Default

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

,,, be any other strategy for selling items. It yields no more revenue than, based on the

MODELLING 1-MONTH EURIBOR INTEREST RATE BY USING DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS WITH UNCERTAINTY

Singular Stochastic Control Models for Optimal Dynamic Withdrawal Policies in Variable Annuities

ECON Micro Foundations

GERMAN ECONOMIC ASSOCIATION OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION GEABA DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IN ECONOMICS AND MANAGEMENT

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

DISRUPTION MANAGEMENT FOR SUPPLY CHAIN COORDINATION WITH EXPONENTIAL DEMAND FUNCTION

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Switching Costs and Equilibrium Prices

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

Stock Repurchase with an Adaptive Reservation Price: A Study of the Greedy Policy

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

If U is linear, then U[E(Ỹ )] = E[U(Ỹ )], and one is indifferent between lottery and its expectation. One is called risk neutral.

ELEMENTS OF MONTE CARLO SIMULATION

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Pricing Dynamic Solvency Insurance and Investment Fund Protection

Working Paper October Book Review of

Simultaneous optimization for wind derivatives based on prediction errors

Elif Özge Özdamar T Reinforcement Learning - Theory and Applications February 14, 2006

Optimal retention for a stop-loss reinsurance with incomplete information

Strategies for Improving the Efficiency of Monte-Carlo Methods

An Approximation Algorithm for Capacity Allocation over a Single Flight Leg with Fare-Locking

Using Monte Carlo Integration and Control Variates to Estimate π

A Markov decision model for optimising economic production lot size under stochastic demand

Pricing & Risk Management of Synthetic CDOs

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

A Continuity Correction under Jump-Diffusion Models with Applications in Finance

October An Equilibrium of the First Price Sealed Bid Auction for an Arbitrary Distribution.

PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION AND EXPECTED SHORTFALL MINIMIZATION FROM HISTORICAL DATA

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

A Risk-Sensitive Inventory model with Random Demand and Capacity

Liquidity and Risk Management

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

The Value of Information in Central-Place Foraging. Research Report

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Valuation of Forward Starting CDOs

Approximate Revenue Maximization with Multiple Items

Self-organized criticality on the stock market

American Option Pricing Formula for Uncertain Financial Market

DRAFT. 1 exercise in state (S, t), π(s, t) = 0 do not exercise in state (S, t) Review of the Risk Neutral Stock Dynamics

GPD-POT and GEV block maxima

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Value of Flexibility in Managing R&D Projects Revisited

Optimal Policies of Newsvendor Model Under Inventory-Dependent Demand Ting GAO * and Tao-feng YE

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions

Price manipulation in models of the order book

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model

IE652 - Chapter 6. Stochastic Inventory Models

(v 50) > v 75 for all v 100. (d) A bid of 0 gets a payoff of 0; a bid of 25 gets a payoff of at least 1 4

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Auditing in the Presence of Outside Sources of Information

THE TRAVELING SALESMAN PROBLEM FOR MOVING POINTS ON A LINE

Haiyang Feng College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin , CHINA

MATH FOR CREDIT. Purdue University, Feb 6 th, SHIKHAR RANJAN Credit Products Group, Morgan Stanley

Price Setting with Interdependent Values

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

THE USE OF NUMERAIRES IN MULTI-DIMENSIONAL BLACK- SCHOLES PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS. Hyong-chol O *, Yong-hwa Ro **, Ning Wan*** 1.

4 Martingales in Discrete-Time

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

2.3 Mathematical Finance: Option pricing

STOCHASTIC REPUTATION DYNAMICS UNDER DUOPOLY COMPETITION

Single item inventory control under periodic review and a minimum order quantity Kiesmuller, G.P.; de Kok, A.G.; Dabia, S.

The Cleansing Effect of R&D Subsidies

A PRODUCTION MODEL FOR A FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION SYSTEM AND PRODUCTS WITH SHORT SELLING SEASON

Transcription:

Department of Social Systems and Management Discussion Paper Series No.1252 Application of Collateralized Debt Obligation Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in Classical Newsboy Problem by Rina Isogai, Satoshi Ohashi and Ushio Sumita February 2010 UNIVERSITY OF TSUKUBA Tsukuba, Ibaraki 305-8573 JAPAN

Application of Collateralized Debt Obligation Approach for Managing Inventory Risk in Classical Newsboy Problem Rina Isogai Morgan Stanley Japan Securities Co., Ltd Yebisu Garden Place Tower 4-20-3 Ebisu, Shibuya-ku, Tokyo, 150-6008, Japan rina.isogai@morganstanley.com Satoshi Ohashi and Ushio Sumita Graduate School of Systems and Information Engineering, University of Tsukuba, 1-1-1 Tennoudai, Tsukuba, Ibaraki, 305-8573, Japan sumita@sk.tsukuba.ac.jp ABSTRACT In the midst of the ongoing world financial crisis, the Collateralized Debt Obligation (CDO) became notorious. However, the fact that the misuse of the CDO resulted in collapse of the world economy does not necessarily imply that the CDO itself would be hazardous. The purpose of this paper is to explore the potential of the CDO approach for controlling general risks, by applying it to the classical Newsboy Problem (). The underlying opportunity loss of replaces the credit risk of CDO. For VaR (Value at Risk) problems formulated without or with CDO, extensive numerical experiments reveal that the overall effect of CDO is rather limited. It could be effective, however, if (i) the underlying risk is high in that the variability of the stochastic demand D is substantially large; (ii) the expected profit should be held above a high level; (iii) the probability of having a huge loss should be contained; and (iv) the detachment point K d should be held relatively low. Keyword: Collateralized Debt Obligation, Risk Control, Newsboy Problem, Value at Risk 1. Introduction It is widely believed that the Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs) played a major role in the ongoing worldwide financial crisis. Naturally, the CDO became notorious for its role in destructing the world economy. However, the fact that the misuse of the CDO resulted in collapse of the world economy does not necessarily imply that the CDO itself would be useless or even hazardous. It is still worth asking whether or not the CDO would be a genuine financial tool for managing risks. The purpose of this paper is to answer this question by exploring the potential of the CDO for controlling general risks. In order to examine the essential structure of the CDO in a neutral manner, we stay away from the problem of controlling financial risks and apply the CDO approach to the classical Newsboy Problem (), where the optimal solution for a VaR (Value at Risk) problem without CDO would be compared against that with CDO. 1

In the literature, the CDO has been studied largely from the perspective of how to deal with possible dependencies among defaults, see e.g. Li (2000), Duffie and Garlean (2001) and Schonbucher and Schubert (2001), Takada and Sumita (2009), and how to compute the risk-neutral unit premium, see e.g. Landor (2004), Kock, Kraft and Steffensen (2007) and Takada, Sumita and Takahashi (2008). In this paper, we focus on one-term CDO applied to the classical Newsboy Problem () in order to investigate the effectiveness of the CDO as a means for managing general risks. The classical is concerned with how to determine the optimal order quantity of a product, whose value drops substantially over one period, so as to maximize the expected profit, given the probability distribution of the demand of the product. Instead of maximizing the expected profit, one often deals with the loss function which can be expressed as the difference between the maximum possible profit and the actual profit. This loss function consists of the loss due to the reduced residual value when the order quantity is larger than the actual demand and the opportunity loss when the order quantity is less than the actual demand. Clearly maximizing the expected profit is equivalent to minimizing the expected loss function. The reader is referred to Khouja (1999) for further details. Recently the classical has been analyzed from the perspective of a conditional VaR problem by Gotoh and Takano (2007). In our analysis, the loss function of the classical replaces the credit risk in the original CDO context. The risk-neutral unit premium is formally introduced so as to assure no-arbitrage. A VaR problem, which is different from that of Gotoh and Takano (2007), is then formulated without or with CDO. Computational algorithms are developed for evaluating the optimal solutions for the two respective cases. By comparing the optimal solutions without CDO against those with CDO for a broad range of underlying parameter values, the effectiveness of the CDO for controlling general risks is examined. The structure of this paper is as follows. In Section 2, a general multi-term CDO model is formally described and the risk-neutral unit premium is introduced for assuring no-arbitrage. By incorporating the revenue and cost structure within the framework of the CDO, it is also shown that the CDO would not affect the expected profit. Section 3 is devoted to the classical, providing a succinct summary of the fundamental structure. In Section 4, the associated VaR problem is formulated. In order to solve the VaR problem, the distribution function of the profit is derived explicitly. In Section 5, the CDO approach for the classical is developed and the VaR problem is reformulated with CDO. The distribution function of the profit with CDO is then obtained in a closed form. Numerical examples with uniformly distributed demand are given in Section 6 for illustrating the merits of the CDO approach under certain conditions. Some concluding remarks are given in Section 7. 2. General CDO Model We consider a financial institution which provides loans to a reference portfolio, i.e. a group of corporations or consumers. Naturally, the financial institution faces the credit risk. The CDO is a structured financial product to control this credit risk by exchanging premium payments from the financial institution to the investors, and certain protections from the investors to the financial institution. More specifically, in 2

the CDO scheme, the credit risk is divided into tranches of increasing seniority, where a tranche is defined by a pair of an attachment point K a and a detachment point K d of the cumulative aggregate loss of the reference portfolio. Here, the attachment point K a means that the protection buyer, which is the financial institution issuing the CDO, is fully responsible for the portfolio loss up to K a. In principle, the protection seller, which is the tranche investor buying the CDO, compensates the portfolio loss beyond K a up to K d for the protection buyer during a contracted period. In exchange, predetermined premiums are paid to the protection seller by the protection buyer according to a predetermined schedule up to the maturity year in such a way that no-arbitrage condition of the credit derivative market is satisfied. These relationships are depicted in Figure 2.1. In what follows, we analyze a mathematical model for the CDO scheme, providing procedural details and certain basic properties. Figure 2.1 Relationship between the Protection Buyer and the Protection Seller Given a tranche [K a, K d ], the associated CDO contract consists of a predetermined premium per monetary unit, denoted by ξ, and a predetermined settlement schedule τ = [τ 0, τ 1,, τ K ] where τ 0 = 0 < τ 1 < < τ K. Let l t be the cumulative aggregate loss of the reference portfolio valued at time t. We note that, throughout the paper, financial values with mean that those values are evaluated at a point in time, and financial values without represent their discounted present values at time τ 0. The protection seller taking the credit exposure to the tranche with K a and K d would bear losses occurring in portfolio in excess of K a but up to K d. In order to capture such transactions, we introduce L t as K a, Kd (1) If we define [a] + = max{0, a}, L t K a, Kd in (1) can be rewritten as (2) In terms of L t K a, Kd in (2), the payment to the protection buyer from the protection seller at time τ k, denoted by P ( ), can be described, for k = 1, 2, 3,, K as AY sell buy k (3) 3

where Δ denotes the first difference of a sequence, i.e. given b k for k = 0, 1,, K, we define b k bk b, k = 1, 2, k 1, K. In return, the protection buyer pays the premium ξ per monetary unit applied to the remaining protected amount at time τ k-1. More specifically, one sees that, for k = 1, 2,, K, (4) By substituting (3) into (4) and working out the summation, it follows that (5) In order to satisfy the no-arbitrage condition of the credit derivative market, the risk-neutral premium should be determined in such a way that the present value of the expected total payment over the contract period from the protection seller to the protection buyer is equal to that from the protection buyer to the protection seller. For this purpose, let r f be the risk free rate to be employed for assessing the present value. Based on (3) and (5), the present values PAYsell buy and PAYbuy sell, describing the present value of the total payment over the contract period from the protection seller to the protection buyer and that from the protection buyer to the protection seller respectively, can be given by (6) As shown in (2.7) of Takada et al. (2008), the risk-neutral premium ξ RN can be obtained by setting, which we transcribe in the following theorem. Theorem 2.l Given a tranche [K a, K d ] and a contract period τ = [τ 0, τ 1,, τ K ], the risk-neutral premium ξ RN per monetary unit for the associated CDO is given by When the risk-neutral premium ξ RN is employed, the CDO would not affect the expected profit. In order to observe this point explicitly, let RV k be the cumulative revenue of the protection buyer evaluated at time τ k. Furthermore, let PR k and PR CDO k be the profit of the protection buyer over the k-th period evaluated at time τ k without and with CDO respectively. One then sees, for k=0, 1,, K, that 4

(7) and (8) As before, from (7) and (8), the present value of the profit of the protection buyer without or with CDO can be obtained as (9) We are now in a position to prove the following theorem. Theorem 2.2 Let PR and PR CDO (ξ) be as in (9) and define π = E[PR] and π CDO (ξ) = E[PR CDO(ξ)]. One then has π = π CDO (ξ RN ). Proof From the definition of π CDO (ξ RN ) together with (7), (8) and (9), it can be seen that where the last two terms on the right hand side of the above equation cancel each other from Theorem 2.1, completing the proof. Theorem 2.2 states that the CDO scheme has no impact on the expected profit. In order to explore the effectiveness of the CDO for risk management, it is therefore necessary to introduce an objective function which involves the probability distribution of the profit beyond its expectation. In this regard, we consider the following optimization problems: (10) The question concerning the effectiveness of CDO for risk management can be ** answered by comparing the optimal solution CDO for VaR-CDO against the optimal ** solution for VaR. 3. Classical Newsboy Problem: Expected Profit Maximization Approach We consider a product whose value drops substantially after a fixed point in time, say τ. The demand for the product over the period [0, τ] is given as a non-negative random variable D. Throughout the paper, it is assumed that the distribution function 5

def x of D is absolutely continuous with FD x P D x fd y dy having the mean 0 def The corresponding survival function is given by FD x P D x 1 FD x f D y x D E. Let c and p be the procurement cost and the sales price per one product respectively. Given that the order quantity is Q, if D < Q, each unsold product has the residual value r. It is natural to assume that If D > Q, each of the lost opportunities would cost s. Assuming that the payment would be made and the revenue would be received at time τ, the profit P R Q, D can then be described as dy D def. (11) (12) Let the expectation of PR Q, D be denoted by (13) * The classical is then to determine the optimal order quantity Q so as to maximize Q. For notational convenience, we write (14) From (12), the maximum profit that one can expect is p c D which occurs if Q happens to be D. The difference between this maximum profit and the actual profit may then be interpreted as the opportunity loss. More formally, we define (15) If we introduce c and O c as U (16) one sees from (12) and (15) that (17) Let the expectation of l Q, D be denoted by (18) 6

It can be readily seen from (13) through (18) that maximizing to minimizing Q. It then follows that l : Q is equivalent (19) From (17), it can be shown that (20) Since Q H Q x dx, it then follows that, l : 0 l : (21) By differentiating Q with respect to Q twice, one finds that l : (22) and (23) Hence, Q l : is strictly convex in Q and has the unique minimum point * Q at which the first order derivative in (22) vanishes. Accordingly, it follows that (24) For incorporating the one-term CDO approach in the context of the, it is necessary to convert the monetary values evaluated at time τ, where such values are highlighted by in the above discussions, into the corresponding present values. This can be accomplished by discounting the monetary values evaluated at time τ by e r f where r f is the risk free rate as introduced in Section 2. The present value of a monetary value evaluated at time τ is denoted by dropping in the notation. One can confirm the following conversions. (25) From (25), it can be readily seen that and one has Q achieves the maximum also at * Q 7

(26) It should be noted from (13), (15) and (25) that (27) where l: Q can be obtained from (21) and (25) as (28) The next theorem provides a necessary and sufficient condition for the maximum * to be positive. expected profit Theorem 3.1 * 0 Q Q if and only if * s 1 Q sdf D x c 0 O cu D Proof From (21), (25) and (26), after a little algebra, one finds that. (29) * Since p c = c U s from (16) and (25), substituting (29) into in (27) yields Q and the theorem follows. Throughout the paper, we assume that the condition of Theorem 3.1 is satisfied and *. 0 Q 4. Classical Newsboy Problem: Value at Risk Approach We now consider the VaR problem for the classical as specified below. 8

In order to solve this problem numerically, it is necessary to evaluate the distribution PR Q, D. function of Theorem 4.1 Let W Q, x P PR Q, D x and W Q x P PR Q D, the followings., x. One then has Proof We first define (30) so that one sees from (12) that (31) From the law of total probability, it can be seen that (32) From the definition of Q D be rewritten as in (30), the right hand side of Equation (32) can, It then follows that (33) From (31), this then leads to 9

and part (a) follows from (33). Part (b) is immediate from (25) since completing the proof. Under the condition of Theorem 3.1, the range of Q satisfying Q v1 can be found as a connected interval since Q is strictly concave from (23) and (27). * Given v 0 and v 1, the optimal solution can then be computed from Theorem 4.1 (b) by applying the bi-section method with respect to Q in this interval. 5. Application of CDO Approach to Classical Newsboy Problem The risk structure of the classical is contained in the opportunity loss l Q, D given in (15) where the discrepancy between the actual order quantity Q and the actual occurrence of the stochastic demand D dictates its magnitude. In order to see the potential of the CDO approach for risk management in general by applying it to the classical, it is then natural to replace the cumulative aggregate loss l t of the reference portfolio in the original CDO model by l Q, D. Let L Q D, be defined as in (1) where l t K a K, d is replaced by l Q D, given in (17). Then, the mean of L K Q D a, K, and the risk-neutral premium for the with d CDO can be obtained from Theorem 2.1 with K=1, (17) and (18), as stated in the next theorem. Theorem 5.1 With this risk-neutral premium ** RN: Q, the total payment form the protection buyer to the protection seller paid at time 0 is deterministic for the with CDO and is given by Accordingly, the net profit Q D PR CDO, can be described as (34) (35) Of particular importance for further study is the distribution function of PR CDO Q, D defined as 10

(36) In the next theorem, we derive W CDO Q, x in terms of demand probabilities under various conditions. Theorem 5.2 Let W CDO Q, x be as defined in (36). One then has where Proof From (35), one sees that For notational convenience, we denote the condition inside this probability by (37) With this notation, the law of total probability implies that 11

(38) We now apply the law of total probability again with the conditions 0 D Q and Q < D to each term on the right hand side of the above equation. For the first term, under the condition l Q, D 0, K a, one has L K, Q 0 a K from (1) so that COND(Q, d D, x) is simplified to Combined with the condition 0 D Q, COND 1 (Q, D, x) can be further reduced from (15), (17) and (25) to (39) (40) Under 0 D Q, the condition l Q, D 0, becomes equivalent to K a (41) The probability of satisfying both (40) and (41) is then equal to G 1 (Q, x). Similarly, when Q < D is satisfied, COND 1 (Q, D, x) can be reduced from (15), (17) and (25) to (42) We also note that, under the condition Q < D, one has (43) Hence the probability of satisfying both (42) and (43) is given by G 2 (Q, x). Consequently, we have shown that the first term on the right hand side of (38) is equal to G 1 (Q, x) + G 2 (Q, x). It can be shown in a similar manner that the second term becomes G 3 (Q, x) + G 4 (Q, x), and the third term is equal to G 5 (Q, x) + G 6 (Q, x), completing the proof. 12

The expressions for G i (Q, x) (i = 1,, 6) in Theorem 5.2 are somewhat awkward and may not be suitable for computing W CDO Q, x repeatedly for different values of Q and x. In order to facilitate repeated computations of W CDO Q, x better, alternative expressions for G i (Q, x) (i = 1,, 6) are given in Appendix where proofs are omitted. Based on Theorem 5.2 together with those theorems in Appendix, W CDO Q, x can be computed repeatedly for different values of Q and x with speed and accuracy. Accordingly, we are now in a position to numerically explore the VaR for the classical with CDO. More specifically, of our main concern is the following problem. 6. Numerical Examples with Uniformly Distributed Demand For exploring the potential of the CDO approach in general risk management, in this section, VaR- defined in Section 4 would be compared with VaR--CDO introduced in Section 5 through numerical examples. In order to conduct such numerical experiments systematically, we assume that the demand D is uniformly distributed, i.e. the p.d.f. f D (x) of D is defined by (44) The distribution function and the survival function of D can be written as (45) The basic set of the parameter values to be employed in this section is provided in Table 6.1, which we assume unless specified otherwise. Table 6.1 Basic Set of Parameter Values p the unit sales price 3 c the unit procurement cost 1 r the unit residual value 0.1 s the unit opportunity cost 0.5 μ D the mean of the demand 5000 r f the risk free rate 0.0001 K a the attachment point 500 K d the detachment point 1000, 2000, 3000 We note that two parameters a and b for the distribution of the demand D are related to each other, when μ D is fixed, as a = μ D b/2. 13

From (26), one finds that the optimal order quantity Q* maximizing the expected profit is given by. (46) The corresponding maximum expected profit is then obtained from (27) as (47) From (27) together with (46) and (47), it follows that. (48) The expected loss can then be given from (27) as. (49) Figures 6.1 and 6.2 depict π(q) and for b=2000, 2500 and 3000. Figure 6.1 Expected Profit π(q) Figure 6.2 Expected Loss We next turn our attention to VaR- introduced in Section 4. The feasible region is denoted by. (50) From (48), we see that can be rewritten as (51) where 14

(52) In order to evaluate, we recall from Theorem 4.1 (b) that (53) where (54) From (45), it can be seen that (55) and, (56) where,,,. The next lemma then immediately follows. Lemma 6.1 Let (57) and assume that 15

. (58) Lemma 6.1 then yields the next lemma. Lemma 6.2 Under the assumption of (58), the following statements hold true. (a) (b) We are now in a position to prove the next theorem. Theorem 6.3 Under the condition of (58), the optimal solution of VaR- can be obtained as. Proof From (53) through (56) combined with Lemma 6.2, one finds that. (59) It can be seen that, as a function of Q, is linearly decreasing given by for and linearly increasing as for. The theorem then follows from (50) and (51). Unfortunately, the counterpart of Theorem 6.3 for VaR--CDO is not available and cannot be evaluated explicitly. One has to resort to numerical solutions based on the bi-section method using Theorems A.1 through A.6 given in Appendix. In Figure 6.3, W (Q,7500) and W CDO (Q,7500) are plotted along with π(q), where v 1 is varied for 8000, 8500 and 9000, while K d =1000 and b=2500 are fixed. One sees that the feasible region becomes narrower as the threshold, v 1, of the expected profit increases. Accordingly, both η ** and η ** CDO, the optimal solutions for VaR- and VaR--CDO respectively, become worse and increase as v 1 increases. It is worth noting that the CDO approach is effective only when v 1 becomes sufficiently large. 16

v 1 =8000 v 1 =8500 v 1 =9000 Figure 6.3 π(q) and W (Q,7500) v.s. W CDO (Q,7500) [ K d =1000, b=2500 ] Similarly to Figure 6.3, W (Q,7500), W CDO (Q,7500) and π(q) are depicted in Figure 6.4 where b is varied for 2000, 2500 and 3000, while v 1 is fixed at 9000 with K d =1000. It should be noted that π(q) decreases while both W (Q,7500) and W CDO (Q,7500) increase as b increases. This means that it becomes more difficult to control the profit as the variability of the stochastic demand becomes larger. While η ** < η ** CDO for b = 2000, this inequality is reversed and the CDO approach becomes effective for b = 2500 or 3000. b=2000 b=2500 b=3000 Figure 6.4 π(q) and W (Q,7500) v.s. W CDO (Q,7500) [K d =1000, v 1 =9000] 17

In order to observe the impact of the variability of the stochastic demand on the optimal solutions more closely, Figure 6.5 depicts η ** and η ** CDO as functions of b, where v 0 is varied for 7000, 7500 and 8000, while v 1 = 9000 and K d =1000 are fixed. One sees that the CDO approach dominates the performance without CDO for v 0 = 7000. For v 0 = 7500 and 8000, the CDO approach becomes effective when b becomes sufficiently large, and this breaking point becomes larger as v 0 becomes larger. v 0 = 7000 v 0 = 7500 v 0 = 8000 Figure 6.5 η ** v.s. η ** CDO [K d =1000, v 1 =9000] Finally, Figure 6.6 illustrates how η ** and η ** CDO are impacted when (v 0, v 1 ) and (b, K d ) are changed, where the white areas represent the regions in which the CDO approach is effective. It can be observed that the CDO approach can be effective only when v 1 is sufficiently large. The area in which the CDO approach performs better shifts toward the lower side of v 0 and becomes larger as b increases or K d decreases. In summary, assuming that the stochastic demand D is uniformly distributed, the CDO approach could become effective if (i) the underlying risk is high in that the variability of the stochastic demand D is substantially large; (ii) the expected profit should be held above a high level; (iii) the probability of having a huge loss should be contained; and (iv) the detachment point K d should be held relatively low. 18

b=2000, K d =1000 b=2000, K d =2000 b=2000, K d =3000 b=2500, K d =1000 b=2500, K d =2000 b=2500, K d =3000 b=3000, K d =1000 b=3000, K d =2000 b=3000, K d =3000 Figure 6.6 η ** v.s. η ** CDO as (v 0, v 1 ) and (b, K d ) Change 7. Concluding Remarks It is widely believed that the Collateralized Debt Obligations (CDOs) played a major role in the ongoing worldwide financial crisis. Naturally, the CDO became notorious for its role in destructing the world economy. However, the fact that the misuse of the CDO resulted in collapse of the world economy does not necessarily imply that the CDO itself would be useless or even hazardous. It is still worth asking whether or not the CDO would be a genuine financial tool for managing risks. The purpose of this paper is to answer this question by exploring the potential of the CDO for controlling general risks. In order to examine the essential structure of the CDO in a neutral manner, we stay away from the problem of controlling financial risks and apply the CDO approach to the classical, where the optimal probability, the optimal order 19

quantity and the resulting expected profit for a value at risk problem without CDO would be compared against those with CDO. A general multi-term CDO model is formally described first and the risk-neutral unit premium is derived for assuring no-arbitrage. By incorporating the revenue and cost structure within the framework of the CDO, it is also shown that the CDO would not affect the expected profit. The CDO idea is then applied to the classical. The fundamental structure of the classical is first described and the associated value at risk problem is formulated. In order to solve the value at risk problem numerically, the distribution function of the profit is derived explicitly. The CDO approach for the classical is developed and the value at risk problem is rewritten with CDO. The distribution function of the profit with CDO is then obtained in a closed form. Numerical examples are given for illustrating the merits of the CDO approach under certain conditions. Extensive numerical experiments reveal that the overall effect of CDO is rather limited. It could be effective, however, if (i) the underlying risk is high in that the variability of the stochastic demand D is substantially large; (ii) the expected profit should be held above a high level; (iii) the probability of having a huge loss should be contained; and (iv) the detachment point K d should be held relatively low. While the positive effect of the CDO approach could be demonstrated through numerical examples, it is difficult to establish a necessary and sufficient condition under which the CDO approach would be worth doing for the protection buyer. Furthermore, the CDO model discussed in this paper may be expanded so as to accommodate multiple terms and multiple markets, and also to incorporate the motivation analysis of the protection seller which is totally ignored in the current model. These theoretical challenges would be pursued further in the future. Theorem A.1. APPENDIX Let G 1 (Q,x) be as in Theorem 5.2 and define Let x 1:Q and x 1:a be defined by respectively. Then the following statements hold. 20

Theorem A.2 Let G 2 (Q,x) be as in Theorem 5.2 and define Let x 2:Q and x 2:a be defined by respectively. Then the following statements hold. Theorem A.3. Let G 3 (Q,x) be as in Theorem 5.2 and define Let x 3:d and x 3:a be defined by respectively. Then the following statements hold. 21

Theorem A.4. Let G 4 (Q,x) be as in Theorem 5.2 and define Let x 4:a and x 4:d be defined by respectively. Then the following statements hold. Theorem A.5. Let G 5 (Q,x) be as in Theorem 5.2 and define Let x 5:d be defined by Then the following statements hold. 22

Theorem A.6. Let G 6 (Q,x) be as in Theorem 5.2 and define Let x 6:d be defined by Then the following statements hold. REFERENCES Duffie, D., & Garleanu, N. 2001. Risk and Valuation of Collateralized Debt Obligations. Financial Analyst Journal, 57(1). Gotoh, J., & Takano, Y. 2007. Newsvendor solutions via conditional value-at-risk minimization. European Journal of Operational Research, 179(1): 80-96. Khouja, M. 1999. The single-period (news-vendor problem: Literature review and suggestions for future research. Omega, 27: 537-553. Kock, J., Kraft, H., & Steffensen, M. May 2007. CDOs in Chains. Willmot Magazine. Lando, D. 2004. Credit risk modeling: Theory and applications. Princeton University Press. Li, D.X. 2000. On Default Correlation: A Copula Function Approach. Journal of Fixed Income, No.9: 43-54. 23

Schonbucher, P., & Schubert, D. 2001. Copula-dependent default risk in intensity models. Working Paper, Bonn University. STANDARD & POOR'S, Home Price Values (July 2008), Accessed January 20 th, http://www2.standardandpoors.com/portal/site/sp/en/us/page.topic/indices _csmahp/0,0,0,0,0,0,0,0,0,1,1,0,0,0,0,0.html Takada, H. & Sumita, U. 2009. Dynamic analysis of a credit risk model with contagious default dependencies for pricing collateralized debt obligations and related European options. Working Paper, Department of Social Systems and Management, University of Tsukuba. Takada, H., Sumita, U., & Takahashi, K. 2008. Development of computational algorithms for pricing collateralized debt obligations with dependence on macro economic factor: Markov modulated poisson process approach. To appear in Quantitative Finance. 24