Introduction. Laura D Amato

Similar documents
Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

Are Intrinsic Inflation Persistence Models Structural in the Sense of Lucas (1976)?

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

A Cross Country Empirical Analysis of Inflation Persistence. Fernando N. de Oliveira 1 (Central Bank of Brazil and IBMEC/RJ)

Shocks, frictions and monetary policy Frank Smets

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN ROMANIA OVER THE PERIOD 2001 TO 2012: A BVAR ANALYSIS

Gali Chapter 6 Sticky wages and prices

On the new Keynesian model

Notes on the monetary transmission mechanism in the Czech economy

The link between labor costs and price inflation in the euro area

On Neutral Interest Rates in Latin America By Nicolas E. Magud and Evridiki Tsounta

The investigation of inflation persistence in Croatia in the period of

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

1 sur :30

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 17. Stabilization in an Integrated World Economy

Monetary Economics Semester 2, 2003

Textbook Media Press. CH 28 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE

Microfoundation of Inflation Persistence of a New Keynesian Phillips Curve

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

Departamento de Economía Serie documentos de trabajo 2015

22/03/2012. Inflation Cycles. The 1920s were years of unprecedented prosperity.

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Is the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Flat?

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Using A Forward-Looking Phillips Curve to Estimate the Output Gap in Peru

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Estimating Output Gap in the Czech Republic: DSGE Approach

Inflation Stabilization and Default Risk in a Currency Union. OKANO, Eiji Nagoya City University at Otaru University of Commerce on Aug.

Expectations Theory and the Economy CHAPTER

Real Business Cycle Model

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

New Ideas about the Long-Lasting Collapse of Employment after the Financial Crisis

Review of the literature on the comparison

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

EXTENSIVE ABSTRACT. Can Phillips curve explain the recent behavior of inflation? Evidence from G7 countries

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

Lecture Policy Ineffectiveness

economic fluctuations. Part 1.

ECON 3020: ACCELERATED MACROECONOMICS

Inflation Persistence

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

Principles of Macroeconomics. Twelfth Edition. Chapter 13. The Labor Market in the Macroeconomy. Copyright 2017 Pearson Education, Inc.

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AGGREGATE DEMAND, AND INFLATION: PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

The Importance of Being Predictable. John B. Taylor Stanford University. Remarks Prepared for the Policy Panel on Monetary Policy Under Uncertainty

Asian Economic and Financial Review, 2016, 6(4): Asian Economic and Financial Review. ISSN(e): /ISSN(p):

Monetary Policy in Pakistan: Confronting Fiscal Dominance and Imperfect Credibility

Monetary Policy rule in the presence of persistent excess liquidity: the case of Trinidad and Tobago

Principles of Macroeconomics December 15th, 2005 name: Final Exam (100 points)

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

The purpose of this paper is to examine the determinants of U.S. foreign

1 Figure 1 (A) shows what the IS LM model looks like for the case in which the Fed holds the

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Inflation. persistence SUMMARY DOES IT CHANGE?

UNIVERSITY OF TOKYO 1 st Finance Junior Workshop Program. Monetary Policy and Welfare Issues in the Economy with Shifting Trend Inflation

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

PROBLEM SET 6 New Keynesian Economics

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle. Copyright 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

Chapter 8: Business Cycles

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

ECON 3150: Exam 2 study guide

Learning, Sticky Inflation, and the Sacrifice Ratio

PART ONE INTRODUCTION

Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence

Homework #6 Uses of Macro Policy Due April 20

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS. Professor Frederic S. Mishkin Fall 1999 Uris Hall 619 Extension:

Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy. Remarks by. Richard H. Clarida. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Monetary Theory and Policy

ECO403 - Macroeconomics Faqs For Midterm Exam Preparation Spring 2013

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

A New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Japan

Financial cycle in Iceland

WORKING PAPER NO. 290 INFLATION PERSISTENCE AND ROBUST MONETARY POLICY DESIGN BY GÜNTER COENEN

In ation persistence, Price Indexation and Optimal Simple Interest Rate Rules

Expected Inflation Regime in Japan

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Exploring the Formation of Inflation Expectations in Jamaica: A Pragmatic Approach

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 11. Classical and Keynesian Macro Analyses

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

Do Sticky Prices Need to Be Replaced with Sticky Information?

ECON : Topics in Monetary Economics

Alamanr Project Funded by Canadian Government

Deepak Mohanty: Perspectives on inflation in India

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

MACROECONOMICS FOR ECONOMIC POLICY

Transcription:

Laura D Amato This book brings together a number of studies which are part of a joint research agenda carried out by several central banks in the region within the framework of the CEMLA s Central Banks Researchers Network. The research aims at enhancing our knowledge about inflation persistence of inflation and price formation in our countries. These issues have been central to the research agenda of both macroeconomists and central banks in the last few years on two grounds. On the one hand, the downward trend in inflation recorded in developed and emerging economies in the last decade of the 20th century and the first decade of the 21st century might have caused sustantial changes in inflation dynamics, which lead to a revision of the notion of inflation as a highly persistent process. 1 On the other hand, the widespread use of macroeconomic models based on assumptions of nominal rigidity raised the need to corroborate the support of these assumptions on an empirical basis. Part I comprises six studies which focus on the analysis and measurement of inflation persistence following different methods. From an intuitive perspective, persistence stands for the speed at which a variable returns to its trend or long-run value after a shock. During many decades, inflation was considered a highly persistent process. From a policy perspective the immediate consequence of this feature of inflation is a high sacrifice ratio in terms of percentage points of unemployment required to curtail inflation, if inflation returns slowly to its trend value. This was reflected in the first versions of the Phillips curve 1 See in this respect Cogley and Sargent (2005), Cogley, Primicieri and Sargent (2009), Stock and Watson (2007), Cogley and Sbordone (2008), Angeloni et al. (2006) and Levin and Pigier (2004), among others. 3

which included an inertial component as a proxy for adaptative expectations based on a nominal rigidity pattern. The modeling of inflation as an inertial process was challenged by rational expectations (RE) models. During the 1980s, Taylor (1982), Rotemberg (1982 and 1983), and Calvo (1983), among others, developed price formation RE models with price-level stickiness, in an attempt to reconciliate the theory with the observed behavior of the time series. During the 1990s, Furher and Moore (1995) showed that these models implied a degree of persistence much lower than that present in the data, making clear that further research was required to get a better understanding of inflation dynamics and different sources of persistence and in particular, it was relevant to disentangle intrinsic inflation persistence, which may derive from a price formation process from that derived from the dynamics of the GDP and from monetary policy itself. As noted by Furher (2011), it is worth striking the difference between reduced-form persistence, which stands for an empirical property of the inflation time series, and the structural persistence of inflation which arises from identifiable macroeconomic sources, such as the behavior of GDP or monetary policy. Recently, the empirical research has focused on the relation between macroeconomic sources of inflation persistence, and the time series properties of inflation. Such evidence shows, to a significant extent, that reduced-form persistence has fallen in recent years in line with the adoption of regimes that focused on inflation anchoring managed to shrink persistence on a substantial and permanent basis. 2 Such evidence implicitly suggests that the long-run or trend inflation is not necessarily constant and that its value may be related to changes in the central bank policy function. Based on this evidence, Cogley and Sbordone (2008) study inflation persistence assuming that long-run inflation is not constant but rather has a trend. Furthermore, Cogley and Sargent (2005), and Cogley, Primicieri and Sargent (2010) study inflation dynamics using models with variable coefficients that assume learning rather than rational expectations, in which the value of long-run inflation is subject to change. Cogley and Sargent (2005) find a high positive correlation between inflation persistence and trend inflation for the United States. They further corroborate that the persistence of inflation fell once the Federal Reserve adopted a more active policy to maintain inflation under control by the mid 1980s. 2 See in this regard Levin and Pigier (2004) and Benati (2008). 4

L. D Amato Part I comprises six studies that focus on the analysis and measurement of inflation persistence, providing a rich empirical evidence on the dynamics of inflation in the region. Some papers use different methodologies to assess the presence of changes in trend inflation and measure inflation persistence. In others, regime switching models are developed to identify regime changes and measure inflation persistence. Finally, one of them studies the transmission of common shocks to aggregate inflation through the dynamics of sectorial inflation rates. A common finding across almost all the studies is the presence of breaks in trend inflation and the reduction of persistence that came along with the lowering of inflation in the region in the 1990s and 2000s. Table 1 sums up the findings of the six studies concerned with inflation dynamics in the region. Castagnino and D Amato analyze inflation dynamics in Argentina and the United States over the period ranging from 1960 to 2006. Using a dynamic factor model and frequency domain analysis they study the transmission of aggregate shocks to inflation based on sectorial inflation dynamics. They find that the impact of aggregate shocks translates into an increase of the comovement of sectorial inflation rates, but their incidence depends on the inflationary environment. When inflation is high shocks lead to strong comovements among sectorial inflation which tend to perpetuate; where inflation is low, the adjustment of relative prices prevails over the comovements, shocks rapidly dissipating. In the case of Costa Rica, Carlos Chaverri Morales and Carlos Torres Gutiérrez study the presence of structural breaks in inflation and its relation with persistence. They find that, in the case of Costa Rica, inflation persistence is sharply reduced when evaluated in terms of the deviations from a changing mean. They attribute their findings to the high weight of a long-lasting period of low inflation exhibited in their sample. Indeed, the assessment of inflation persistence over the latest period (1997-2009) reveals that the estimated persistence is higher. They further evaluate the level of inflation persistence in terms of the mean duration of shocks. D Amato and Garegnani study inflation persistence in Argentina over a long period of time: 1961-2006. They analyze the relation between changes in the mean of inflation and its autoregressive component and changes in the monetary regime. By using tests for multiple structural breaks and recursive estimation they identify changes in trend inflation that coincide with regime changes. They find that in Argentina inflation was a highly persistent process during the 1970s and 1980s, close to a random walk. On the contrary, persistence fell dramatically when inflation 5

TABLE 1. INFLATION PERSISTENCE Study Country Sample Methodology Persistence Comments D Amato Garegnani Argentina 1960-2006 Evaluate changes in mean and estimate persistence with constant and changing mean Constant mean: = 0.78 Non-constant mean = 0.31 Persistence decreases along with the lowering of inflation Castagnino D Amato Argentina and the USA 1960-2006 Study the transmission of aggregate shocks to inflation focusing on the dynamics of sectoral inflation rates: Frequency domain analyisis and factor model High inflation induces a generalized comovement among sectoral inflation rates that persists over time Echavarría - López - Misas Colombia 1990-2010 Regime switching model Inflation: between 0.336 and 0.226 Inflation gap: = 0.88 Do not find changes in persistence across regimes Echavarría - Rodíguez Rojas Colombia 1979-2010 Unobserved components model Evaluated using impulse response functions:persistence increases between 1979-1989 and 1989-1999 and decreases between 1999 and 2010 Chaverri Morales - Torres Gutiérrez Costa Rica 1953-2009 Evaluate changes in mean and estimate persistence with constant and changing mean. Also estimate persistence through the mean life of shocks Constant mean: = 0.78 Non-constant mean = 0.31 Results biased toward low inflation due to the high weigth of a low inflation period within the sample: Increases to 0.31 (for the period 1997-2009 and with a changing mean) Oliveira Petrassi 23 developed and 17 From 1995 Estimate reduced form inflation models: AR(p) underdeveloped countries onwards models, New Keynesian hybrid Phillips curve, and an inflation reducedform model with wage rigidity Reduced and stable persistence in general and lower for developed economies Persistence is lower in those economies that experienced hyperinflation in the recent past 6

L. D Amato sharply decreased in the early 1990s. With the introduction of the managed floating exchange rate scheme in 2002, inflation persistence slightly increased. Their findings corroborate the relevance of assessing structural breaks for modeling inflation dynamics and, particularly, for estimating its persistence. Their results also indicate that persistence, in the case of Argentina, is not inherent to inflation but dependent on the monetary regime. Juan Echavarría, Norberto Rodríguez and Eduardo Rojas study inflation persistence in Colombia over a long period: 1979-2010. They estimate an unobserved component model for inflation that allows for regime changes and use it to estimate the persistence of the inflation-gap. They identify statistically significant changes in the persistence of inflation which, defined in terms of impulse-response functions increased between 1979 and 1989 and between 1989 and 1999, to then decrease to its lowest level during the 1999-2010 period with the adoption of inflation targeting in 1999. Juan Echavarría, Enrique López and Martha Misas also study inflation persistence in Colombia over the period ranging from 1990 to 2010 by using a regime change model for both inflation and the inflation gap, bearing in mind, as suggested by Cogley, Primicieri and Sargent (2010), that the persistence of inflation could be caused by the persistence of the monetary authority s inflation target. Even though, they find evidence that inflation went down and became less volatile as from the adoption of an inflation targeting regime in 1999, they cannot account for a statistically significant reduction in the persistence of inflation. Finally, Fernando Olivera and Myrian Petrassi estimate inflation persistence in several industrial and emerging countries since 1995 onwards using different reduced-form models of inflation: autoregressive models, a New Keynesian Phillips curve and a reduced-form inflation model with wage rigidity. Their findings reveal that the persistence of inflation has been reduced and remains stable in both groups of countries in the recent past, being lower in industrial economies. References Angeloni, I., L. Aucremanne, M. Ehrmann, J. Galí, A. Levin, and F. Smets (2006), New Evidence on Inflation Persistence and Price Stickiness in the Euro Area: Implications for Macro Modeling, Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 4, No. 2-3, April-May, pp. 562-574. 7

Benati, L. (2008), Investigating Inflation Persistence Across Monetary Regimes, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 123, No. 3, pp. 1005-1060. Calvo, G. (1983), Staggered Contracts in a Utility Maximizing Framework, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 383-398. Cogley, T., G. E. Primicieri and T. J. Sargent (2010), Inflation-gap Persistence in the US, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 2, No. 1, pp. 43-69. Cogley, T., and T. J. Sargent (2005a), Dirft and Volatilites: Monetary Policies and Outcomes in the Post WWII US, Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 262-302. Cogley, T., and A. Sbordone (2008), Trend Inflation, Indexation and Inflation Persistence in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve, American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 5, pp. 2102-2126. Furher, J. (2011), Inflation Persistence, en B. Friedman and M. Woodford (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, Vol. 3A, Chapter 9, North- Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 423-486. Furher, J., and G. Moore (1995), Inflation Persistence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 1, pp. 127-159. Levin A., and J. Piger (2004), Is Inflation Persistence Intrinsec in Industrial Countries, European Central Bank (Working Paper, No. 334). Rotemberg, J. (1983), Aggregate Consequences of Fixed Costs in Price Adjustment, American Economic Review, Vol. 73, No. 3, pp. 433-436. Stock, J., and M. Watson (2007), Has Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?, Journal of Money Credit and Banking, Vol. 39, pp. 3-34. Taylor, J. (1980), Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, No. 1, pp. 1-23. 8