Information environment, systematic volatility and stock return synchronicity

Similar documents
Stock price synchronicity and the role of analyst: Do analysts generate firm-specific vs. market-wide information?

Relationship Between Voluntary Disclosure, Stock Price Synchronicity and Financial Status: Evidence from Chinese Listed Companies

What Drives the Earnings Announcement Premium?

Further Test on Stock Liquidity Risk With a Relative Measure

Liquidity skewness premium

The Impact of Institutional Investors on the Monday Seasonal*

The Association between Earnings Quality and Firm-specific Return Volatility: Evidence from Japan

A Replication Study of Ball and Brown (1968): Comparative Analysis of China and the US *

Intraday return patterns and the extension of trading hours

Abnormal Audit Fees and Stock Price Synchronicity: Iranian Evidence

Is Stock Price Synchronicity a Measure of Noise or Stock Price Informativeness: Evidence from Audit Pricing Model

Does market liquidity explain the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle in the Chinese stock market?

Fama-French in China: Size and Value Factors in Chinese Stock Returns

An Online Appendix of Technical Trading: A Trend Factor

Are Firms in Boring Industries Worth Less?

Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers?

Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and

Does Greater Return Synchronicity Mean Less Firm-Specific Information? Evidence from Insider Trading

Does Greater Firm-specific Return Variation Mean More or Less Informed Stock Pricing?

Stock price synchronicity and dividend policy: Evidence from an emerging market

Bessembinder / Zhang (2013): Firm characteristics and long-run stock returns after corporate events. Discussion by Henrik Moser April 24, 2015

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Analyst forecasts, firm asymmetric information and audit quality

Earnings Announcement Idiosyncratic Volatility and the Crosssection

Post-Earnings-Announcement Drift: The Role of Revenue Surprises and Earnings Persistence

Volatility Appendix. B.1 Firm-Specific Uncertainty and Aggregate Volatility

Mutual Fund Ownership, Firm Specific Information, and Firm Performance: Evidence from China

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

ON THE INTERPRETATION AND ESTIMATION OF THE MARKET MODEL R-SQUARE

Does Transparency Increase Takeover Vulnerability?

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Online Appendix to. The Value of Crowdsourced Earnings Forecasts

April 13, Abstract

A Lottery Demand-Based Explanation of the Beta Anomaly. Online Appendix

Marketability, Control, and the Pricing of Block Shares

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Have we solved the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle?

Dividend Changes and Stock Price Informativeness

Firm specific uncertainty around earnings announcements and the cross section of stock returns

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

Darren T. Roulstone University of Chicago Graduate School of Business

Research Journal of Finance and Accounting ISSN (Paper) ISSN (Online) Vol.5, No.12, 2014

How Does Earnings Management Affect Innovation Strategies of Firms?

Short Sale Constraints and Price Informativeness *

A Synthesis of Accrual Quality and Abnormal Accrual Models: An Empirical Implementation

Corporate bond liquidity before and after the onset of the subprime crisis. Jens Dick-Nielsen Peter Feldhütter David Lando. Copenhagen Business School

THE PRECISION OF INFORMATION IN STOCK PRICES, AND ITS RELATION TO DISCLOSURE AND COST OF EQUITY. E. Amir* S. Levi**

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options

Mandatory Adoption of IFRS and Stock Price Informativeness

Turnover: Liquidity or Uncertainty?

Does R&D Influence Revisions in Earnings Forecasts as it does with Forecast Errors?: Evidence from the UK. Seraina C.

Daily Price Limits and Destructive Market Behavior

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

The Effects of Shared-opinion Audit Reports on Perceptions of Audit Quality

Statistical Understanding. of the Fama-French Factor model. Chua Yan Ru

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Corporate bond liquidity before and after the onset of the subprime crisis. Jens Dick-Nielsen Peter Feldhütter David Lando. Copenhagen Business School

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Market Timing Does Work: Evidence from the NYSE 1

Relation Between Stock Return Synchronicity and Information in Trades, and A Comparison of Stock Price Informativeness Measures

Margaret Kim of School of Accountancy

Whether Cash Dividend Policy of Chinese

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS

The Impact of Securities Analysts Prediction

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

Volatility Information Trading in the Option Market

Does IFRS adoption affect the use of comparable methods?

Positive Correlation between Systematic and Idiosyncratic Volatilities in Korean Stock Return *

Managerial Insider Trading and Opportunism

Macro Factors and Volatility of Treasury Bond Returns 1

Investor Sentiment and Stock Return Comovement: the Role. of Information and Innovation

Risk changes around convertible debt offerings

Can Hedge Funds Time the Market?

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

Size and Value in China. Jianan Liu, Robert F. Stambaugh, and Yu Yuan

Dong Weiming. Xi an Jiaotong University, Xi an, China. Huang Qian. Xi an Physical Education University, Xi an, China. Shi Jun

The Role of Credit Ratings in the. Dynamic Tradeoff Model. Viktoriya Staneva*

The Impact of Uncertainty on Investment: Empirical Evidence from Manufacturing Firms in Korea

Risk Taking and Performance of Bond Mutual Funds

Understanding the Closed-end Fund Puzzle from the Chinese Experience

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

The Role of Accounting Accruals in Chinese Firms *

Factors in the returns on stock : inspiration from Fama and French asset pricing model

Hedge Funds as International Liquidity Providers: Evidence from Convertible Bond Arbitrage in Canada

Benefits of International Cross-Listing and Effectiveness of Bonding

Variation in Liquidity and Costly Arbitrage

A SEEMINGLY UNRELATED REGRESSION ANALYSIS ON THE TRADING BEHAVIOR OF MUTUAL FUND INVESTORS

Journal of Banking & Finance

Earnings Announcements, Analyst Forecasts, and Trading Volume *

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Ownership Concentration, Adverse Selection. and Equity Offering Choice

Quality Underlying Managerial Discretion

Errors in Estimating Unexpected Accruals in the Presence of. Large Changes in Net External Financing

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

AN ANALYSIS OF THE DEGREE OF DIVERSIFICATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Zheng-Feng Guo, Vanderbilt University Lingyan Cao, University of Maryland

Target Firm-Specific Information and Expected Synergies in M&A

Variation in Liquidity, Costly Arbitrage, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Core CFO and Future Performance. Abstract

Volatility Risk and January Effect: Evidence from Japan

Session 4: Corporate Transparency and Financial Reporting in China

Transcription:

Information environment systematic volatility and stock return synchronicity Jing Wang Steven X. Wei and Wayne Yu 1 June 2016 1 Jing Wang is from the School of Accounting and Finance Hong Kong Polytechnic University Hong Kong; email eileen.wang@connect.polyu.hk. Steven X. Wei is from the School of Accounting and Finance Hong Kong Polytechnic University Hong Kong; email afweix@polyu.edu.hk; tel. (852) 2766-7056; fax. (852) 2330-9845. Wayne Yu is from the Department of Economics and Finance City University of Hong Kong Hong Kong; email wayneyu@cityu.edu.hk; tel. (852) 34422866; fax. (852) 34420284. We would like to thank Huiwen Lai Nancy Su Shuo Yang Kevin Zhu and participants at ICAFEL 2016 for helpful comments. We acknowledge the financial support from The Hong Kong Polytechnic University Research Grant B-Q35Z.

Information environment systematic volatility and stock return synchronicity Abstract The stock return synchronicity decreases when the general information environment improves. We theoretically demonstrate that if investors can learn the firm s future performance based on all noisy signals in the market the systematic volatility would be largely reduced even when the incremental information content of each particular firm s signal is modest. Empirically we find that the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season when the information disclosure intensity is dramatically increased. This dynamic pattern is robust after control for the change of fundamentals the effect of corporate events the abnormal returns around the earnings announcements and the change of liquidity. The driving force of this dynamic pattern is the reduction of the systematic volatility rather than the increment of the idiosyncratic volatility and this pattern is more pronounced for older firms whose firm-specific uncertainty is relatively lower. Key words: Stock return synchronicity; information environment; cross-assets learning; earnings season. 2

1. Introduction The puzzle of whether R-square captures the information or else occasional frenzy unrelated to concrete information (Roll (1988)) is far from resolved. Although the information interpretation of R- square is widely supported in the literature since Morck Yeung and Yu (2000) substantial evidence is also provided for the contradicting view that the firm-specific variation resembles noise 2. From an econometric perspective the R 2 can be decomposed into (1) the systematic volatility which is the variation in returns that can be explained by the market factors and (2) the idiosyncratic volatility which is the variation of residuals from the market model regression. Therefore the higher R 2 can be caused by either elevated systematic volatility or depressed idiosyncratic volatility or both. However most of the previous work simply assumes that only the idiosyncratic volatility matters and overlooks the impact of systematic volatility. In this paper we highlight this limitation and reexamine the puzzle when the systematic volatility plays the key role for the dynamic pattern of R 2. We first demonstrate how the general information environment in the market would affect the stock return synchronicity in a dynamic setting around the earnings season. Consistent with the information interpretation of R 2 we provide further evidence that the dramatically increased intensity of information disclosures could significantly decreases the stock return synchronicity. More importantly we posit the driving force of this dynamic pattern is the reduction of the systematic volatility rather than the increment of the idiosyncratic volatility. When investors receive news for multiple firms whose cash flows are correlated they update their beliefs about the firm s future performance not only based on the news from that particular firm but also taken reference from other 2 Morck Yeung and Yu (2013) and Li Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2014) provide a review of the literatures exploring the puzzle. 3

firms news in the market. In a large economy this learning behavior across assets helps to reduce the systematic volatility but plays no role for the idiosyncratic volatility. As a result the stock return synchronicity should be negatively associated with the changing quality of the information environment. We develop a one-period rational model with multiple risky assets to demonstrate the information updating process and the underling mechanism of the dynamic R 2. The random end-of-period cash flows are determined by a linear combination of the market and firm-specific factors and the homogeneous prior beliefs about future cash flows would be updated based on the information set which contains noisy signals for the future cash flows. When investors receive new information from one particular firm they could update their prior beliefs about all firms future cash flows since their beliefs about the common component are updated. We show that in this dynamic learning process other firms information would be finally reflected in the systematic volatility but imposes no effect for the idiosyncratic volatility. As a result the stock return synchronicity would decrease when the general information environment is improved. Moreover the model indicates that the systematic volatility can effectively capture the accumulated change of information quality which cannot be detected by the idiosyncratic volatility. As long as the market factor is not perfectly revealed each individual news could provide additional information to depress the systematic volatility further. Therefore even though each firm s information quality in the market is only slightly improved if the number of the improved signals is large the systematic volatility would still be significantly reduced with the improved information environment. In contract since the idiosyncratic volatility could only reflect the information learned from that particular firm the idiosyncratic volatility would not change much if the incremental information content for that firm is modest. 4

In the empirical analysis we use the general setting of earnings season to demonstrate how the general information environment would fluctuate the stock return synchronicity in a dynamic manner. When firms jointly announce their annual earnings reports in the earnings season the improved general information environment as well as the activated learning process across assets would lower the stock return synchronicity compared with other normal periods. Consistent with the predictions we find a clear and significant dynamic pattern of stock return synchronicity around the earnings season with the sample of 2037 Chinese firms from 2003 to 2015. The average R 2 estimated from the standard market model decreases about 18% in the earnings season and this pattern cannot be explained by the change of the fundamental values the effect of major corporate events the abnormal returns when earnings reports are released and the change of the price liquidity 3. Furthermore we decompose the R 2 into the systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities. We test how these two components of R 2 would change with different information environment around the earnings season. We find that the systematic volatility is significantly lower in the earnings season than that in the normal period with a decrease ratio of almost 36% for the standard market model and 32% for the industry-augmented model 4. However the idiosyncratic volatility does not change significantly in different periods indicating that the incremental information content revealed by the particular firm s earnings announcement is too modest to be reflected. We then conclude that the improved general 3 In the normal years the equal-weighted average of R 2 estimated from the standard market model decreases from 0.3927 in the non-earnings seasons to 0.3211 in the earnings season. 4 In the normal years the equal-weighted average of the systematic volatility decreases from 0.0154 in the nonearnings seasons to 0.0098 in the earnings season for the standard market model and from 0.0186 to 0.0126 for the industry-augmented market model. 5

information environment and the reduced systematic volatility are the primary causes for the dynamic pattern of the stock return synchronicity around the earnings season. Finally we find the dynamic pattern of R 2 around the earnings season is more pronounced for older firms whose uncertainty about the firm-specific factors is relatively lower. Since the information environment decreases the stock return synchronicity by resolving the uncertainty of the market factors the learning effect would be more important to the firms with relatively higher uncertainty of the systematic component. The empirical results confirm this prediction and document a positive association between the firm age and the change of R 2 around the earnings season. We conduct the analysis using Chinese data for the following reasons. First as a typical emerging market with inadequate informed arbitrage the higher market-wide uncertainty reflected in the elevated systematic volatility is more likely to be resolved when the information environment becomes better. Second the information environment presents very clear changing patterns in China. On one hand the earnings statements are important information sources for Chinese investors in addition to other kinds of disclosures; on the other hand the earnings announcements are highly clustered in China with almost 98% firms releasing their annual earnings reports within three months. In contract the information environment of other countries may not present clear changing patterns as China. For example in US only 66% of firms make their annual earnings announcements in the earnings season and this pattern can be easily disturbed by quarterly earnings announcements and other information sources. As a result the dynamic pattern of the R 2 is much weaker in US with only 9% decrease from the normal periods to the earnings season 5. 5 In the normal years the equal-weighted average of R 2 estimated from the standard model in US decreases from 0.1221 in the non-earnings seasons to 0.1105 in the earnings season. 6

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the previous literature on the stock return synchronicity and the learning behavior of investors. Section 3 describes the motivations and develops the propositions for the empirical tests. The sample description variables construction and the empirical results are presented in section 4 and section 5 concludes. The Appendix provides the detailed derivations and proofs for the theoretical model. 2. Related literature 2.1 Stock return synchronicity (R 2 ) and the informativeness of stock prices Roll (1988) draws our first attention to R 2 which measures to what extent the stock returns may move together. He argues that the large proportion of the firm-specific price movements in the stock return variations implies either private information or else occasional frenzy unrelated to concrete information. Following Roll (1988) substantial evidence is provided to explore the interpretation of the R 2. However what R 2 captures the information or noise is still under debate nowadays. The information interpretation of R 2 is first confirmed in Morck Yeung and Yu s paper in 2000. In a cross-country analysis they find the stock return synchronicity is lower in rich countries where the property rights are well protected. The stronger property rights promote the informed arbitrage and capitalize more firm-specific information. Following Morck et al. (2000) this line of literature documents that the stock return synchronicity is negatively associated with the disclosure quality (Jin and Myers (2006); Haggard Martin and Pereira (2008); Hutton Marcus and Tehranian (2009); Gul Kim and Qiu (2010)) the information about future earnings contained in the current stock prices (Durnev Morck Yeung and Zarowin (2003)) the corporate governance quality (Ferreira and Laux (2007); Ferreira Ferreira and Raposo (2011); Gul Ng and Srinidhi (2011); Armstrong Balakrishnan and Cohen (2012)) the activity of informed investors (Piotroski and Roulstone (2004); Crawford 7

Roulstone and So (2012)) and the efficiency of investment (Durnev Morck and Yeung (2004); Chen Goldstein and Jiang (2007)). Another line of literature documents an opposite view that the lower stock return synchronicity is associated with less informed stock prices. West (1988) shows that the excess price variance is higher when expectations are conditional on a smaller information set. Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2011) and Chen Huang and Jha (2012) state that the poor information quality is associated with higher idiosyncratic volatility. While Chan and Chan (2014) find a significant negative relation between stock return synchronicity and the information asymmetry measured by SEO discounts. All of the findings are consistent with the empirical evidences indicating that the lower R 2 is associated with greater impediments to informed trade less market efficiency and poorer information quality (Kelly (2014); Teoh Yang and Zhang (2009); Hou et al. (2013); Li Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2014)). Morck Yeung and Yu (2013) try to reconcile this puzzle by characterizing the firm-specific return volatility as the intensity of firm-specific information events. As a result the stock return synchronicity should vary over time with the information flows capitalized into the stock prices. Brockman Liebenberg and Schutte (2010) confirm this countercyclical return comovement pattern and find that the stock return synchronicity decreases (increases) during the periods of economic expansion (contraction) when the production of information increases (decreases). While Dasgupta et al. (2010) study the R 2 s pattern around a major corporate event and find the stock return synchronicity is higher in a more transparent information environment when the intensity of surprise events is low. Kim and Shi (2012) study the influences of IFRS adoptions and find the stock return synchronicity decreases from the pre-adoption period to the post-adoption period. Our paper also conducts analysis for the dynamic pattern of stock return synchronicity when the information environment is changing over time. 8

Unlike the static cross-sectional analysis in the previous literature our paper highlights the dynamic nature of R 2 in a general setting and provides direct evidences for the information interpretation of R 2. Several papers attribute the mixing empirical results to the disturbance of systematic volatility. Dasgupta et al. (2010) emphasizes the need to control for the β effect in firm-level studies of R 2. They argue that the positive associations of the stock return synchronicity with S&P additions (Barberis Shleifer and Wurgler (2005)) as well as the more analyst coverage (Piotroski and Roulstone (2004); Chan and Hameed (2006)) are due to the increased β which adds noise for the analysis of information and the firm-specific return variation. While Li et al. (2014) directly document a negative relationship between the information measures and the systematic volatility and conclude that the firm-specific return variation resembles noise. We cast doubt on this explanation and construct a model to highlight how the clustered firm-specific information would lower the R 2 by decreasing the systematic volatility. 2.2 Learning across assets and the excess comovement The effect of learning to the excess comovement of the stock returns has been studied by Veldkamp (2006). Her paper indicates that when the fixed costs for the information production is high investors price the assets using a common subset of information which elevates the comovement among the stock prices. Consistent with Veldkamp s model Hameed Morck Shen and Yeung (2015) provide empirical evidence for this spillover effect and find the bellwether firms whose prices are more accurate might exhibit more comovement. However none of these papers decompose the R 2 and analyze the systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities separately. Actually if the cross-assets learning in a multiple-firms setting is one explanation of excess return comovement the time varying information might move the variation of systematic factors which is nondiversifiable in a large economy. The effect of learning to the cost of capital and the systematic risk has 9

been explored in the previous literature. In the CAPM setting researchers find the higher disclosure quality (Lambert Leuz and Verrecchia (2007)) or the improved accounting standards (Zhang (2013)) would affect the firm s assessed covariance with other firms cash flows and lower the firm s systematic market risk in the learning process. Patton and Verardo (2012) directly investigate whether stock betas vary with the release of firm-specific news. They find the betas increase on earnings announcement days and explain the results in a learning model when investors use the announcing firms information to revise the expectations of the aggregate economy. Following these literatures we posit that if investors learn across assets when the firms fundaments are correlated the information would affect the systematic variations in addition to the firm-specific variations which would complicate the analysis of the information interpretation for the stock return synchronicity. 3. Model 3.1 R 2 expression and information structure We start by considering a single-period economy with N risky assets and one riskless asset. The returns for the risky assets can be expressed as = while the riskless asset has a known rate of return. The random end-of-period cash flow for firm j is presented by a single-factor index model as = + where is a market factor is a firm-specific factor and captures the importance of the market factor for firm j. We assume all investors possess homogeneous prior beliefs regarding the distributions of the factors as ~ ; ~ = 1 and the firmspecific factors are independently distributed across assets. The prior beliefs about the future cash flow would be updated when investors receive signals that are informative with respect to. We assume investors are identical and the signals are commonly observed by all investors. Consistent with the actual disclosure practices we model the information as 10

a noisy signal of the end-of-period cash flows 6. Specifically invertors use the information set I to update their beliefs where = and the signal for each firm can be expressed as = +! = + +! where! is the noise in the information. The error term! is i.i.d normally distributed with zero mean and variance ". 7 We regard the magnitude of the error term s variance as an inverse measure of the signal s information quality # where # =1/ ". In order to analyze how the information quality would affect the stock return synchronicity we use the standard asset pricing model of conditional CAPM to estimate the R 2. As stated in CAPM the expected return for firm j conditional on the information set is a function of the risk-free rate the conditional expected return for the market $ % ' and the beta coefficient ( ' where ( ' = )*+ + -. /++ -. that $ 0' = + 1( 2$ % 45 ' = + )*+ + -. /++ -. 2$ % ' 4. ⑴. Since the stock return equals to the ratio of the end-of-period cash flow to the stock price at the beginning of the period 6 where 8 9 1 the covariance of the stock return with the market return can be expressed as a function of the future cash flows covariance as :; % = :; < 8 9 8-9 - = = 9 9 - :; %. We define the systematic volatility as the variance of stock j s return related to the market-wide fluctuations and the idiosyncratic volatility as the remaining part of the total variance excluding the systematic volatility. Thus the systematic volatility SYSVOL and the idiosyncratic volatility IDIOVOL can be expressed as >?@A ' = B)*C % D'EF G /+ % 0' = 9 G B)*C % D'EF G /+ % 0' ⑵. 6 The similar information structure is possessed in literatures such as Lambert et al. (2007) Patton et al. (2012) and Zhang (2013). 7 For simplicity we assume the error term is not correlated with each other. 11

'H'@?@A0' = I 0' >?@A0' = 9 G JI 0' B)*C % D'EF G /+ % 0' K. ⑶. Consistent with Roll (1988) and Morck Yeung and Yu (2000) the stock return synchronicity or R 2 of the market model regression can be expressed as L ' = MNMOPQ. MNMOPQ.R.S.POPQ. = B)*C G % D'EF /+C D'E/+. ⑷. % 0' The expressions of R 2 and its two components imply that the information quality would influence the return synchronicity by affecting investors inference about the covariance structure of future cash flows. Based on these formulas the following sections analyze in details how the stock return synchronicity would change according to different information qualities. 3.2 Information updating process for stock returns In this section we illustrate how the information quality could affect the stock return synchronicity as well as its systematic and idiosyncratic volatility. The updating process is intuitive: based on an information set respect to the future cash flows investors update their beliefs about the variancecovariance structure of the market and firm-specific factors. When the updating beliefs about these underlying factors are reflected in the stock returns the stock return synchronicity would fluctuate with the information. According to the information structure the information set can be separated into two groups: one is the signal for that particular firm which can be used to update the beliefs about the whole cash flows for that firm; the other is a group of other firms signals in the market which can only be used to update the beliefs about the market factor. Using firm j as an example we illustrate how the covariance structure for firm j s cash flow with the market-wide cash flow % is updated based on the 12

information set ' = ( ). The conditional R 2 is expressed in Theorem1. See the detailed updating process in Appendix A. Theorem 1. When investors update their beliefs about the future cash flows based on all information in the market with the information set ' = ( ) the R 2 for firm j is given by L (' = ) = X G G T Y T G U V R X G T G Y RT G [ G \ ]Y G b U ( \c_ ] G U\ ^_/a\ \d. ⑸. R) As shown in theorem 1 the R 2 is affected by both the quality of the particular firm s information (# ) as well as the general information quality of all other firms signals in the market (# e f = 12.. & f ). The log R 2 can be decomposed into two parts as ln(l ') = ln < T U G V R = + ln m X G T Y G X G T G Y RT G [ G \ ]Y G b U ( \c_ ] G U\ ^_/a\ \d n. ⑹. R) The first part illustrates the effect of the firm s own information while the second part reflects the effects of the general information quality of other firms. Both parts would decrease when the information quality improved. Contrary to the common wisdom we highlight that R 2 would fluctuate with the general information quality of other firms even when the information quality for that particular firm remains the same. The relationship between R 2 and the general information environment is summarized in the following corollary. Corollary 1. R 2 is negatively associated with not only the information quality for that particular firm but also the general information quality of all other firms signals in the market. We then decompose the R 2 into systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities. The conditional systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities are expressed in Theorem 2. See the detailed updating process in Appendix A. 13

Theorem 2. When investors update their beliefs about the future cash flows based on all information in the market with the information set ' = ( ) the systematic volatility and the idiosyncratic volatility for firm j is given by >?@A (' = ) = 9 G < G X = T Y T G U V R [ G \ ]Y G b \c_] G R U\ ^_/a\ ⑺. And 'H'@?@A (' = ) = 9 G < T G U T G U V R =. ⑻. Theorem 2 establishes that both the systematic and the idiosyncratic volatility are associated with the quality of the information set. However they do not reflect the information in the same way: the systematic volatility is associated with both the information quality for that particular firm (# ) and the information quality for other firms (# e f = 12.. & f ); while the idiosyncratic volatility is only associated with the information quality for that particular firm (# ). We focus on how other firms information quality would affect the volatility structure of the studied firm j. Unlike the previous literature our information structure highlights that the news about the market and firm-specific factors in the cash flows are not separately reported. As a result references can be taken across assets since the common component contained in firm i s signals could also provide information for firm j s future cash flows. In theorem 2 firm i s information quality affects firm j s systematic volatility through the equation of X o G T Y G which reflects how much systematic news can be T G Uo R/V o learned from firm i s signal. If firm i s information quality improved investors could learn more about the common component which would be finally reflected into the systematic volatility of all stocks in the market. 14

Furthermore theorem 2 highlights that when investors learn the common component from all signals in the market the effects of learning can be accumulated as X G G \ T Y ep T G U\ R/V \. That means even when the information quality for each firm s signal only improves slightly if the number of signals are large the systematic volatility can still effectively capture the improved quality of the general information environment. On the contrary the change of the quality of the information environment would not be reflected into the idiosyncratic volatility due to the independence of the firm-specific cash flows. We summarize the effects of the information environment in corollary 2. Detailed proofs are in Appendix A. Corollary 2. Due to the special information structure and the investors learning behavior the systematic volatility is negatively associated with the general information quality of all other firms signals in the stock market. However the idiosyncratic volatility would not be affected by the general information environment. We then analyze what kinds of firms are more sensitive to the change of the general information environment. Intuitively the effect of the changing information environment would be more pronounced for the firms with relatively higher systematic uncertainty. In another word if the uncertainty about a firm s future cash flows is fully firm-specific the quality of the general information environment plays no role to the R 2. Corollary 3 documents this argument and detailed proofs are in Appendix A. Corollary 3. The effect of the general information environment to the R 2 would be strengthened when the uncertainty about the firm-specific factor is relatively low. 15

3.3 Earnings season and the stock return synchronicity The earnings season can be considered as a special period when the general information environment in the market is highly improved. On the one hand the individual firm s earnings announcement serves as an important and regular event to provide information which can be easily learned by all investors. Thus we suppose the information quality for the particular firm is improved when firm makes its earnings announcement. On the other hand the earnings announcements are clustered at calendar time. This reporting structure indicates that in the earnings season the information quality for all firms in the market would be improved simultaneously which highlights the importance of cross-sectional learning (Foster (1981) Han and Wild (1990) Ramnath (2002) and Thomas and Zhang (2008)) and provides a nature framework to test how the stock return synchronicity would fluctuate with the varying general information environment. Suppose that in the earnings season the information quality is higher than the one in the normal period for any firm in the market that # (qm) > # (sqm) ⑼. where # (qm) is the information quality of firm j s signal in the earnings season and # (sqm) is the information quality of firm j s signal in the non-earnings season. The dramatically increased information disclosure intensity in the earnings season would not only improve the information quality for that particular firm but also the general information quality of other firms signals in the market. According to corollary 1 we propose there is a dynamic pattern of R 2 around the earnings season. Proposition 1. As a special period with intense information disclosure R 2 is lower in the earnings season than it is in the normal period. 16

We then argue that the improvement of the general information environment is the dominant effect for this dynamic pattern. Actually if there is no information spillover effect the incremental information provided by the public news such as the earnings announcement is too modest to affect the R 2 (Roll (1988) Ball et al. (2008)). However if investors could learn across assets the R 2 should be lower when the earnings announcements are simultaneously released in the earnings season. Remember that the quality of the general information environment would affect the systematic volatility and stock return synchronicity in a sum function of X G G \ T Y ep T G U\ R/V \. When # e slightly increases for all firms in the earnings season the insignificant increase for each component would be accumulated into a large change of the sum value if n is large. That means in a large economy the effect of the improved general information environment would still be significant even when the information quality for a particular firm is only slightly improved. The intuition is straight-forward. In the earnings season investors could update their beliefs about the market-wide factor from all firms earnings announcements. The large number of signals could compensate for the limitation of inaccurate signal from each firm and lower the systematic volatility through the learning process. In contrast the idiosyncratic volatility can only be learned from the signal for that particular firm so the idiosyncratic volatility would not reduce significantly if the earnings announcement only provide modest incremental information. Proposition 2. The dominant effect for the pattern of R 2 around the earnings season is coming from the systematic volatility rather than the idiosyncratic volatility. Finally we explore what kind of firms are more vulnerable to the varying information environment around the earnings season. We first posit that the investors would possess more uncertainty for the younger firms future cash flows. As stated by Pastor and Veronesi (2003) investors attempting to value 17

the newly listed firms are confronted with substantial uncertainty about their future profitability and this uncertainty can be resolved over time through learning. Similarly Dasgupta et al. (2010) also argue that when a firm becomes older the market could learn more about its time-invariant characteristics thus the uncertainty about the fundamentals will be reduced over time. According to corollary 3 R 2 would be more sensitive to the change of the general information environment with relatively lower firm-specific uncertainty thus we argue that the older firms R 2 s would change more around the earnings seasons. Proposition 3. The change of R 2 around the earnings season would be more pronounced for older firms. 4. Empirical results 4.1 Data and sample We obtain stock return trading volume and accounting data from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database and the bid-ask price from DataStream. The initial sample contains all A shares listed in Shanghai and Shenzhen stock exchange 8. Since the quarterly accounting data is only available from 2002 in China our sample periods cover 13 years from 2003 to 2015. We require our sample firms to have at least 30 available trading days for each season which covers three months and exclude the daily returns when the prices are hitting the daily price limit 9 or when the stocks are under special treatment 10. We also exclude firm-years that are within 2 years after the IPO 8 We exclude the stocks listed on the Growth Enterprises Market (GEM) Board as well as B shares and H shares from our sample. 9 The Exchange imposes the daily price limit on trading of stocks and mutual funds with a daily price up/down limit of 10%. 10 According to the stock listing rules the stock exchanges would give special treatment to the stocks of the listed companies with abnormal financial conditions which called ST shares. 18

year and limit the sample to non-financial and non-utility firms according to the Industry Classifying Index Code of Listed Companies released by the China s Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) 11. The final sample contains 16799 firm-year observations for 2037 firms. Table 1 presents the sample distribution across industries and years. As shown in Panel A the number of firms within each industry ranges from 10 for Other Manufacturing which posits less than 1% to 402 for Machinery Equipment and Instrument which posits 19.73%. While the number of firms increases monotonically over the sample years as shown in Panel B. 4.2 The earnings season We define the earnings season as the period when the majority of firms jointly make their annual earnings announcements. We consider the effect of annual earnings announcements rather than the quarterly reports because the annual earnings statements provide relatively more information content in China. Quarterly earnings announcements play a minor role as they are of low quality and get less attention from the market. In addition CSRC requires Chinese listed firms to complete and disclose the annual reports within 4 months from their fiscal year ends which is coincident with the calendar year end for all Chinese listed firms. So we define the earnings season as the period from February to April when majority of firms release their earnings reports. The non-earnings seasons are also defined to cover three months from November of the last year to January this year May to July and August to October respectively. Thus the analysis year in this paper is defined from last year s November to this year s October with one earnings season and three non-earnings seasons. 11 http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/csrc_en/ 19

Table 2 shows the time distribution of the annual earnings announcements which clearly presents a clustered pattern. 97.89% of the annual earnings statements are announced during the earnings season with 8.73% in February 42.13% in March and 47.25% in April. In addition this clustered pattern of earnings announcements is consistent over years. This table confirms the rationality of our definition of the earnings season from February to April. 4.3 Main variables and descriptive statistics In order to measure the dynamic pattern of the stock return synchronicity we estimate both the standard market model and the industry-augmented market model using daily returns for each season L$v wx = y + (z{l $v x +! wx ⑽. L$v wx = y + ( z{l $v x + ( 'H $v x +! wx. ⑾. where L$v wx is the daily return for firm i on day t z{l $v x is the value weighted A-share market return for day t and 'H $v x is value weighted industry return. We require at least 30 available trading days for each season and extract R 2 (1) and R 2 (2) from the regressions respectively. Stock return synchronicity is a logarithmic transformation of R 2 as >}~ = ( L /(1 L )) and the systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities are the sum of squares due to regression and the sum of squared errors respectively. We consider several control variables to exclude other potential effects on the dynamic pattern of stock return synchronicity. Four variables are controlled for the fundamental changes which are widely used in the previous literature including firm total assets (SIZE) market to book value (MTBV) leverage (LEV) and the profitability (ROA). We use quarterly accounting data to measure all variables 20

and match the latest accounting numbers available to each season. All variables are trimmed at top and bottom 1%. Some major corporate events would also fluctuate the return synchronicity. We control for their effects by adding dummies if there were important corporate events happened during that particular season. Following Dasgupta et al. (2010) we first control extreme changes in total assets (EVENT) since the significant corporate events are typically associated with major changes in asset size. Second we control for the effect of merger and acquisitions (M&A) as well as the seasonal equity offerings 12 (SEO) which would change the normal speed of information release and affect the pattern of the stock return synchronicity. Finally in order to exclude the potential effects of liquidity to the dynamic pattern of stock return synchronicity we control for the seasonal liquidity measures namely Turnover (TURN) Amihud Illiquidity (AMIL) and Bid-Ask Spread (SPREAD). The Appendix provides more detailed definitions for all variables. Panel A of Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics of our sample firms. The mean and median value of the seasonal R 2 estimated from the standard market model (R 2 (1)) are 0.3907 and 0.3869 respectively which are significantly lower than the ones estimated from industry-augmented market model (R 2 (2)) with the values of 0.4669 and 0.4726. Both R 2 s display considerable variations as reflected in the high standard deviations and inter quartile ranges. Panel B of Table 3 presents the Pearson correlation matrix of the variables. Consistent with the previous literature the stock return synchronicity is positively associated with SIZE and LEV while negatively associated with MTBV 12 We do not include right issues and seasoned new issues to specific target into our SEO control variables because their disclosures of information would not be as intense as a public offering. 21

which means the firms with higher R 2 are larger firms with higher leverage and lower market to book ratios. 4.4 Dynamic pattern of stock return synchronicity Our empirical analysis starts from a carefully examination of the dynamic pattern of the stock return synchronicity around the earnings season. Proposition 1 predicts that the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season than it is in the normal period when the information environment is substantially improved due to the clustered earnings announcements. We first test this pattern by univariate analysis and then present the regression results with proper controls. Table 4 reports the results of the univariate analysis for R 2 in the earnings season and in the normal period. The descriptive statistics in Panel A clearly display a changing pattern of firm-level R 2 around the earnings season. For the R 2 estimated from the standard market model (R 2 (1)) the equal-weighted mean is 0.3561 in the earning season and 0.4024 in the non-earnings seasons. The difference is 0.0464 and significant at 1% level. While for the value-weighted means of R 2 the difference between the earnings season and the non-earnings seasons (0.0407) is slightly lower than the difference of the equalweighted means. It means that the larger firms not only have higher R 2 s than the smaller firms but also present weaker patterns than the smaller firms. The pattern is also robust for the medians of R 2 and the R 2 estimated from the industry-augmented market model (R 2 (2)). Furthermore we argue that the dynamic pattern of R 2 around the earnings season is mainly due to the cross-sectional learning effects rather than the impact of individual firm s earnings announcement. To support this argument we first exclude the observations within the three days around the individual firm s earnings announcement and then estimate the R2 with the standard market model (R 2 (3)) and industry-augmented market model (R 2 (4)) respectively. The pattern is robust with the equal-weighted 22

mean value of the difference as 0.0410 and 0.0388 for R 2 (3) and R 2 (4) which confirms that the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season than it is in the normal period even after excluding the effects of the individual earnings announcements. The dynamic pattern of R 2 can be easily disturbed by large macro news and abnormal market conditions. We take this concern into consideration and present the seasonal pattern of R 2 in the normal years in Panel B of Table 4. There are two special periods in China stock market over the sample years. One is 2005 when the stock market is undergoing share structure reform. The other is 2008 to 2009 when the whole market is under financial crisis. After excluding the observations during the special periods the difference of R 2 between the earnings season and the non-earnings seasons becomes larger: the equal-weighted means for R 2 (1) and R 2 (2) are 0.0715 and 0.0674 respectively. We then test whether the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season than it is in the non-earnings season by estimating the following regression model >}~ wx = α + ( $ wx + ( e }; ; wx e e + > I + 'ƒ +! wx. ⑿. where >}~ wx is the stock return synchronicity for stock i and season t $ wx is a dummy variable taking the value of one if the stock i at time t is in the earnings season and value zero otherwise Control denotes a set of control variables; Year and Industry are the year and industry dummies control for year and industry fixed effects. As predicted by Proposition 1 we expect the coefficient of $ wx to be significantly negative which means the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season than the one in the non-earnings seasons. Panel A of Table 5 presents the results of the regression analysis in our sample years from 2003 to 2015. The dependent variable for column (1) and (2) is the stock return synchronicity estimated from the standard market model. In column (2) we add an interaction term of dummies for the abnormal 23

years and the earnings season (RCD) to control for the noises caused by the special market condition. The coefficients for ES are -0.2290 and -0.3525 respectively which are significantly negative as our expectation. Column (3) and (4) show the results using the stock return synchronicity estimated from the industry-augmented market model as the dependent variable. The pattern remains unchanged which confirms that the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season than it is in the normal periods. One potential explanation for the dynamic pattern of R 2 is that since there are abnormal stock returns surrounding the earnings announcement date (Beaver (1968)) the decreased R 2 in the earnings season may be caused by the short-run response to the information content released by the individual firms earnings announcements. We test this argument by using SYNCH (3) and SYNCH (4) as the dependent variables. The results are presented in the last four columns in Panel A of Table 5. The dynamic pattern is still robust and the coefficients for ES are -0.3330 and -0.2873 respectively which means the effects of the particular firms earnings announcements are very limited to explain our results. The other concern is whether the lowered R 2 in the earnings season is just a reflection of the changing liquidity. Since the firm s R 2 and liquidity are negatively correlated if the liquidity is changing in different seasons the stock return synchronicity would change as well. Therefore we add three liquidity measures in the regressions. As shown in Panel B of Table 5 our results are robust with significant negative coefficient for ES. In addition all three liquidity variables are significantly negatively associated with the stock return synchronicity. The results confirm that the pattern of the stock return synchronicity is not driven by the effects of liquidity. 24

4.5 Systematic volatility or idiosyncratic volatility? We now confirm that the stock return synchronicity is lower in the earnings season than it is in the normal period. However which component the systematic volatility or the idiosyncratic volatility is the dominant force for this pattern remains to be an empirical question. Proposition 2 predicts that the systematic volatility would be significantly lower in the earnings season if investors learn the common component across assets even though the earnings announcements only provide modest incremental information. We test this prediction by analyzing the patterns of the systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities separately. Table 6 presents the results of the univariate analysis for the systematic and idiosyncratic volatilities. The systematic volatility is lower in the earnings season than it is in the non-earnings seasons in both Panel A and Panel B. In the normal years the equal-weighted mean for the systematic volatility estimated from the standard market model is 0.0098 in the earnings season and 0.0154 in the normal period decreased about 36% in the earnings season. While the difference of the value-weighted mean is even higher with the value of 0.0074. This pattern is also robust for the systematic volatility estimated from the industry-augmented market model. However the difference between the earnings season and the non-earnings season for the idiosyncratic volatility is vague. In the normal years the equal-weighted mean value for the idiosyncratic volatility estimated from the standard market model is 0.0230 in the earnings season which is almost the same as 0.0233 in the normal periods. While the difference for the median value is 0.0001 and insignificant. However the difference of the value-weighted mean is significant positive with the value of 0.0026 which means the larger firms earnings announcements may provide more 25

information and have lower idiosyncratic volatility in the earnings season. The idiosyncratic volatility estimated from the industry-augmented model exhibit the similar results. The results of the regression analysis are presented in Table 7. The first two columns show the regression results using the log of the systematic volatility as the dependent variables. The coefficients for ES are both significantly negative no matter which market model is used in the estimation process indicating that the systematic volatility is lower in the earnings season. However for columns (3) and (4) which use the log of idiosyncratic volatility as the dependent variable the coefficients for ES are both insignificant which means there is no significant change for the idiosyncratic volatility around the earnings season. The last four columns present the results with the control of liquidity and the results remain to be robust 13. 4.6 Age effect on the change of R 2 In this section we test whether the R 2 dynamic pattern around the earnings season is more pronounced for older firms. As the uncertainty about the firm-specific factor can be resolved over time older firms would have relatively higher market-level uncertainty then younger firms. When the information environment improved in the earnings season the cross assets learning helps to reduce the market-level uncertainty which would decrease R 2 more for older firms. In table 8 we calculate the change of R 2 and the ratio of systematic to idiosyncratic risk (SYS_VOL/IDIO_VOL) using the average value in the non-earnings seasons minus the value in the earnings season. We then classify the sample firms into three groups according to the firm age for each 13 Since volatilities are highly associated with the number of observations we also test the pattern of the standard deviations. The results remain to be robust. 26

fiscal year. Consistent with Proposition 3 the change of R 2 is larger for older firms than the younger firms and this result is robust for the systematic to idiosyncratic ratios. Table 8 also presents the change of fundamentals around the earnings season (denoted as Δ ) as well as the annual values (SIZE MTBV LEV and ROA). We use these variables as controls in the following regression analysis. In table 9 we test the effect of age to the change of R 2 and the systematic to idiosyncratic ratio in the following regression models L wx = α + ( {ˆ$ wx + ( e }; ; wx e e + ( }; ; wx + > I + 'ƒ +! wx ⒀. ( MNM_OPQ ) e.s.p_opq wx = α + ( {ˆ$ wx + e ( e }; ; wx + ( }; ; wx + > I + 'ƒ +! wx ⒁. where L wx is the change of average R 2 in the non-earnings seasons minus the R 2 in the earnings season for firm i at year t; ( MNM_OPQ.S.P_OPQ ) wx is the change of systematic to idiosyncratic volatility ratios around the earnings season; AGE is the firm age; }; ; and }; ; are the changes and annual values for fundamental variables and liquidity; Year and Industry are the year and industry dummies control for year and industry fixed effects. As shown in table 9 the change of R 2 or the change of systematic to idiosyncratic volatility ratio is positively related to the firm age indicating that the older firms R 2 s change more around the earnings season. The results are robust for different estimation models and after control for the change of liquidities. 4.7 Does US presents similar R 2 pattern? In this section we examine whether the dynamic pattern of R 2 around the earnings season can be generalized into other markets such as US. The major challenges come from the indistinct change of the information environment in US: the earnings reports become less important when investors have 27

multiple information sources and the disperse fiscal year ends for US firms make the situation even worse. As a result we predict the dynamic pattern of R 2 in US is much weaker than it is in China. We obtain the daily stock return and trading volume data from CRSP and accounting data from COMPUSTAT from 1975 to 2015. We only include the stocks listed on the NYSE AMEX or NASDAQ that have a CRSP share code of 10 or 11 and exclude firms in finance and banking (SIC 6000-6999) and regulated utilities (SIC 4900-4999). We require at least 30 available trading days to calculate the seasonal R 2 from a standard market model and our sample contains 13952 firms with 454283 firm-season observations. As shown in Panel A of table 10 around 66% of the sample firms make their annual earnings announcements from January 15 th to April 15 th which we defined as the earnings season in US. We then estimate the R 2 from a standard market model from January 15 th to April 15 th as the earnings season and April 15 th to July 15 th July 15 th to October 15 th and October 15 th to Jan 15 th the next year as the non-earnings seasons. The dynamic pattern of R 2 is shown in Panel B of Table 10. Consistent with the previous literature the equal-weighted mean value for the R 2 is only 0.1259 in US which is much lower than the value of China as 0.3907. The average R 2 is higher in the non-earnings season as 0.1286 than in the earnings season as 0.1181 and the systematic volatility also presents similar pattern as the R 2. We then control for the effect of the financial crisis in 1987 the crash of internet bubble from 2000 to 2001 and the subprime crisis from 2008 to 2009 and the results remains to be robust. All in all we find the R 2 in US also presents similar dynamic pattern around the earnings season but the pattern is much weaker than the one in China. 28