There are 7 questions on this exam. These 7 questions are independent of each other.

Similar documents
Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency.

There are 9 questions on this exam. These 9 questions are independent of each other.

There are 10 questions on this exam. These 10 questions are independent of each other.

Each question is self-contained, and assumptions made in one question do not carry over to other questions, unless explicitly specified.

Microeconomics, IB and IBP. Regular EXAM, December 2011 Open book, 4 hours

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

1a. Define and comment upon Slutsky s substitution effect.

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

Midterm 1 (A) U(x 1, x 2 ) = (x 1 ) 4 (x 2 ) 2

Solutions to Midterm Exam. ECON Financial Economics Boston College, Department of Economics Spring Tuesday, March 19, 10:30-11:45am

Homework 1 Solutions

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

1. Madison has $10 to spend on beer and pizza. Beer costs $1 per bottle and pizza costs $2 a slice.

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

x 1 = m 2p p 2 2p 1 x 2 = m + 2p 1 10p 2 2p 2

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Consumption and Saving

Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Principles of Microeconomics Final Exam Wednesday, October 10th, 2007

Introduction. The Theory of Consumer Choice. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Microeconomics. The Theory of Consumer Choice. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich update C H A P T E R

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work- Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization. Copyright 2014 Pearson Education, Inc.

SOLUTIONS. ECO 100Y L0201 INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Midterm Test # 1 LAST NAME FIRST NAME STUDENT NUMBER. University of Toronto June 22, 2006

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 15 Problem 3 / 15 Problem 4 / 20 Problem 5 / 25 TOTAL / 100

DO NOT BEGIN WORKING UNTIL YOU ARE TOLD TO DO SO. READ THESE INSTRUCTIONS FIRST.

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Econ 101A Midterm 1 Th 28 February 2008.

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

NAME: ID # : Intermediate Macroeconomics ECON 302 Spring 2009 Midterm 1

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

MID-TERM EXAM #2: Intermediate Macro Winter 2014

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Econ 633/733: Advanced Microeconomics Final Exam, Autumn 2004 Professor Kosteas

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

ECON Micro Foundations

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis July 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm - Solutions

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Midterm 2 (Group A) U (x 1 ;x 2 )=3lnx 1 +3 ln x 2

Assignment 5 Advanced Microeconomics

1. Consider the figure with the following two budget constraints, BC1 and BC2.

Rose-Hulman Institute of Technology / Department of Humanities & Social Sciences / K. Christ SL354, Intermediate Microeconomics / Sample Exam #1

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

M d = PL( Y,i) P = price level. Y = real income or output. i = nominal interest rate earned by alternative nonmonetary assets

- ---Microeconomics Mid-term test 09/11/2016 First name Last name n matricola

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Econ 1101 Summer 2013 Lecture 7. Section 005 6/26/2013

Income and Substitution Effects in Consumer Goods Markest

Midterm 2 (Group A) U(C; R) =R 2 C. U i (C 1 ;C 2 ) = ln (C 1 ) + ln (C 2 ) p 1 p 2. =1 + r

Mock Examination 2010

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

ECONOMICS 100A: MICROECONOMICS

ECO 301 MACROECONOMIC THEORY UNIVERSITY OF MIAMI DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS FALL 2008 Instructor: Dr. S. Nuray Akin MIDTERM EXAM I

ECO 301 MACROECONOMIC THEORY UNIVERSITY OF MIAMI DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Dr. S. Nuray Akin. PRACTICE FOR MIDTERM EXAM II and HW 4

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Midterm Exam. Monday, March hour, 30 minutes. Name:

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Chapter 4 Topics. Behavior of the representative consumer Behavior of the representative firm Pearson Education, Inc.

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Intro to Economic analysis

Problems. 1. Given information: (a) To calculate wealth, we compute:

Review for the Second Exam Intermediate Microeconomics Fall 2010

SYLLABUS AND SAMPLE QUESTIONS FOR MS(QE) Syllabus for ME I (Mathematics), 2012

Midterm 2 - Solutions

Assignment 1 Solutions. October 6, 2017

ECN101: Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory TA Section

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Honors General Exam PART 1: MICROECONOMICS. Solutions. Harvard University April 2013

ECON 2001: Intermediate Microeconomics

Write your name: UNIVERSITY OF WASHINGTON Department of Economics

Solving The Perfect Foresight CRRA Consumption Model

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

Economics Honors Exam Review (Micro) Mar Based on Zhaoning Wang s final review packet for Ec 1010a, Fall 2013

Name. Final Exam, Economics 210A, December 2014 Answer any 7 of these 8 questions Good luck!

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Solutions to Assignment #2

ECONOMICS 100A: MICROECONOMICS

3. After you have completed the exam, sign the Honor Code statement below.

Homework 2 ECN205 Spring 2011 Wake Forest University Instructor: McFall

Introduction to economics for PhD Students of The Institute of Physical Chemistry, PAS Lecture 3 Consumer s choice

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

D

Midterm 2 60 minutes Econ 1101: Principles of Microeconomics November 14, Exam Form A

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

VERSION A. Professor s Name (Please circle) Collard-Wexler, Skreta. Lecture Time: :

Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

where Qs is the quantity supplied, Qd is the quantity demanded, and P is the price.

ECON MACROECONOMIC THEORY Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University

Transcription:

Economics 21: Microeconomics (Summer 2000) Midterm Exam 1 Professor Andreas Bentz instructions You can obtain a total of 100 points on this exam. Read each question carefully before answering it. Do not use any books or notes. The use of non-programmable calculators, or the use of only the non-programming and non-graphing functions of a programmable calculator, is permitted. You have 65 minutes to answer all questions. Please use the space provided to answer questions; if you need more space, use the back of the page. There are 7 questions on this exam. These 7 questions are independent of each other. Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency. At the end of the exam, you must turn in your answers promptly: if you continue writing I will take off points. Good luck. Name: Class time (circle one): 9 (section 1) 10 (section 2) questions 1-7 1. Adam has preferences over two goods, apples (a) and fig-leaves (f), represented by the following utility function (subscript A denotes Adam's utility function): u A (a, f) = a 1/2 f 1/2. Eve's preferences over the same two goods can be represented by the following utility function (subscript E denotes Eve's utility function): u E (a, f) = (1/2) ln(a) + (1/2) ln(f) + 20. Suppose that Adam's and Eve's consumption of both apples and fig-leaves is positive. (a) (5 points) Do Adam and Eve have the same preferences? Why or why not? Explain very briefly. Eve's utility function is a positive monotonic transformation of Adam's utility function (it is the monotonic transformation u E (a, f) = ln[u A (a, f)] + 20. Since utility is uniquely defined only up to positive monotonic transformations (i.e. a positive monotonic transformation represents the same preferences as the original utility function), the both have identical preferences. cont'd page 1 of 7

(b) If you were to solve Adam's constrained maximization problem, you would find that his demand function for apples is: a = (1/2)m/p a, where p a is the price of apples, and m is Adam's wealth. (i) (4 points) Are apples a Giffen good for Adam? An inferior good? Why or why not? Apples are not a Giffen good: the partial derivative of demand w.r.t. price is negative. Apples are not an inferior good: the partial derivative of demand w.r.t. income is positive. (ii) (2 points) Are apples a gross substitute for fig-leaves for Adam or a gross complement? Explain your answer briefly. Apples are neither a gross substitute nor a gross complement for fig-leaves: the partial derivative of the demand for apples w.r.t. the price of fig-leaves is zero (i.e. neither positive nor negative). 2. (6 points) Sophie O. Moore has the following utility function over beer (b) and pizza (p): u(p, b) = ln(p) + 2b. She currently consumes 2 bottles of beer and 1 pizza. At what rate is she just willing (while remaining at the same level of utility) to exchange a little less beer for a little more pizza? This questions asks for the MRS, where beer is what we usually called good 2, and pizza is good 1. The MRS, therefore is just: minus the partial derivative of utility w.r.t. pizza divided by the partial derivative of utility w.r.t. beer. Here, MRS = - (1/p)/2 = -1/(2p). Since she is currently consuming 1 pizza, her MRS is -1/2. page 2 of 7

3. (10 points) The market for widgets consists of 1,000 identical consumers. Each consumer has an individual inverse demand curve for widgets (w) as follows: p(w) = 100-2w. where p(w) is the price that can be achieved when w widgets are sold. Widgets are only produced by one firm, and that firm currently charges $50 per widget. The widget producer asks you to calculate its marginal revenue. You calculate marginal revenue to be as follows: In order to find the market demand curve, you first need to find the individual demand curve: rewrite inverse demand to find demand: w(p) = 50 - (1/2)p. Now you can add the 1,000 consumers: W(p) = 50,000-500p. To find marginal revenue you can either calculate revenue and then take the derivative, or find elasticity and then use the formula for marginal revenue (p(1+1/elasticity)). This is the direct (first) way. For this, you need the inverse market demand curve, because marginal revenue is "how much does revenue increase as output is increased", so you need everything as a function of output. The inverse market demand curve is: p(w) = 100 - (1/500)W. Multiplying this price by quantity to get revenue we get: R(W) = 100W - (1/500)W 2. And taking the derivative w.r.t. W (in order to get marginal revenue), you have MR(W) = 100 - (2/500)W. The firm currently charges $50 per widget, so they must be selling (read it off the market demand curve) 25,000 widgets. Put this into the expression for MR and you get MR(25,000) = 100-100 = 0. Alternatively, you could calculate the elasticity from W(p) = 50,000-500p. Elasticity is (dw(p)/dp) x (p/w(p)). Here, elasticity is -500 (p/w(p)). Now put in p and W(p) (p = 50, as given, and therefore W(p) = 25,000 as previously calculated), to get an elasticity of - 1. Using the formula MR = p(1+1/elasticity), you see that MR = 0. page 3 of 7

4. Lionel has preferences over consumption this period (c 1 ) and consumption next period (c 2 ) that can be represented by the following utility function: u(c 1, c 2 ) = ln(c 1 ) + c 2. Lionel has income m 1 this period, and m 2 next period. The real rate of interest is 10%. (a) (10 points) Write down, and solve, the Lagrangean for Lionel's choice problem: that is, derive Lionel's optimal demands for c 1 and c 2. The budget constraint is c 2 = m 2 + (1+ρ)(m 1 - c 1 ), as usual, except that now ρ denotes the real interest rate. The Lagrangean therefore is: L = ln(c 1 ) + c 2 - λ(c 2 - m 2 - (1+ρ)(m 1 - c 1 )) The first-order conditions are: (i) 1/c 1 - λ(1+ρ) = 0 (ii) 1 - λ = 0 (iii) c 2 = m 2 + (1+ρ)(m 1 - c 1 ) Using (ii) which solves as λ = 1 in (i), you get 1/c 1 = (1+ρ), or c 1 = 1/(1+ρ). Putting this into (iii) you get c 2 = m 2 + (1+ρ)(m 1-1/(1+ρ)), or c 2 = m 2 + (1+ρ)m 1-1. (b) (4 points) The real rate of interest falls. Which two factors could have lowered the real rate of interest? If the real rate of interest falls, either the (nominal) interest rate has fallen or the inflation rate has risen. Recall that (1+ρ) is defined to be (1+r)/(1+π), where ρ is the real rate of interest. cont'd page 4 of 7

(c) (10 points) Suppose Lionel is a lender. When the interest rate falls, there are two effects on Lionel's consumption choices. Describe, in words (no calculation is required), the wealth and substitution effects on Lionel's consumption of c 1. Be as specific as possible, including all the information you have about Lionel's preferences. Can you predict whether Lionel will lend more, or less? An interest rate fall is a fall in the relative price of period 1 consumption. So the substitution effect is going to make Lionel consume more of period 1 consumption (c 1 ). Since Lionel is a lender, the interest rate fall, however, has made him "poorer" (since he gets some of his income from interest income, that is now lower). As a result, he will want to consume less of all normal goods. In this particular case of a quasilinear utility function, however, there is no wealth effect on c 1. You can see that from the demand curve you have derived in part (a), or remember this from the workout. So in this special case, there is no wealth effect, only a substitution effect. So you can say that Lionel will definitely consume more of c 1. 5. Tessa has the following utility function over consumption this period (c 1 ) and consumption next period (c 2 ): u(c 1, c 2 ) = ln(c 1 ) + ln (c 2 ). Tessa has income m 1 this period, and m 2 next period, and c 1 costs p 1 per unit (before any tax) and c 2 costs p 2 per unit (before any tax). The (nominal, that is: not adjusted for inflation) interest rate is r. There is also a sales tax of t 1 in period 1 and of t 2 in period 2. (Explanation (sales tax): For instance, if the sales tax in period 1 is 10%, that is, if t 1 = 0.1, and if the price of a good is usually $50, with the tax that good's price is $55.) (a) (10 points) Write down Tessa's intertemporal budget constraint, making sure that your expression contains the inflation rate instead of the (pre-tax) prices p 1 and p 2. The only thing that is different from how we did this in class is that instead of writing p 1 you now write (1 + t 1 )p 1, and similarly (1 + t 2 )p 2, as the explanation implies. Then you do the same thing we did in class: write down the budget constraint, and replace p 1 /p 2 appropriately by an expression involving inflation. Here's how: (1 + t 2 )p 2 c 2 = (1 + t 2 )p 2 m 2 + (1 + r)((1 + t 1 )p 1 m 1 - (1 + t 1 )p 1 c 1 ), or: c 2 = m 2 + (1 + r) [(1 + t 1 )/(1 + t 2 )] [p 1 /p 2 ] (m 1 - c 1 ). Now replace [p 1 /p 2 ] by 1/(1 + π), as in class to get: c 2 = m 2 + [(1 + r)/(1+ π)] [(1 + t 1 )/(1 + t 2 )] (m 1 - c 1 ). cont'd page 5 of 7

(b) If you were to write down, and solve, Tessa's constrained maximization problem (no need to do this), you would find that her demand function for c 1 is: (1 + π) (1 + t2 ) c 1 = 0.5 m1 + m2 (1 + r) (1 + t1) Suppose that the government announces an increase in the tax rate in period 2 (that is, t 2 increases), while the tax rate in period 1 remains the same. (i) (4 points) What happens to Tessa's consumption in period 1 when t 2 increases? it increases (ii) (10 points) If Tessa was a borrower before that tax increase, could you have predicted (from wealth and substitution effects alone, i.e. without knowledge of Tessa's demand function), how she would alter her consumption of c 1? Explain your intuition (no need to perform a calculation). The intuition is just that if the tax in period 2 increases, period 2 consumption becomes relatively more expensive and therefore, period 1 consumption becomes relatively cheaper. Now the intuition about wealth and substitution effects applies: period 1 consumption is relatively cheaper so the substitution effect tells Tessa to consume more in period 1. The wealth effect tells Tessa (since she is a borrower) to consume more of period 1 consumption also. So Tessa will definitely consume more in period 1. 6. (5 points) Suppose that a perpetuity with a $10 coupon currently trades for $200. (Assume that the first coupon payment you get is next year.) If you are willing to buy or sell this bond (that is, if you are partaking in the market for this bond), you must have a view on what the interest rate is over the lifetime of this bond. What is this interest rate? The present value of a perpetuity is c/r (where c is the coupon and r the interest rate). Here we know that the present value, 200 = 10/r, so you can calculate r to be 0.05, or 5%. This is the interest rate that the market expects, and which is implicit in the market's valuation of this perpetuity. (This will be an idea you encounter again in the 26-36-46 sequence when you discuss the time structure of interest rates, or the "yield".) page 6 of 7

7. (20 points) "Given perfect capital markets, a firm's investment decisions are separate from the consumption preferences of the firm's shareholders." (a) Explain this statement (use diagrams as appropriate) and: (b) discuss the importance of the assumption of perfect capital markets (i.e. equal lending and borrowing rates), again using diagrams as appropriate. answer suggestion: You should explain the Fischer separation theorem, using the diagram. Make sure you explain all key concepts, such as the investment opportunity schedule, the way in which firms can make payouts to investors, how that determines the investors' endowment and how from this endowment investors can save and borrow in a perfect capital market. This implies that investors (whatever their preferences are like) will wish the firm to make the payouts that shift their budget constraint out as far as possible, that is the payouts that maximize the present value of the firm. As I discussed in class (on the board, not on the slides), if lending and borrowing rates differ, this result no longer obtains: differing lending and borrowing rates imply a kinked budget constraint (i.e. kinked about the endowment point). If that is the case, a simple diagram (such as the one I used in class) illustrates that shareholders again disagree on what the firm should do, and the separation of investment decisions from consumption preferences no longer obtains. page 7 of 7