Has Australian Economic Growth Been Good for the Poor? Melbourne Institute & Brotherhood of St Laurence. NERO Meeting, OECD.

Similar documents
The Dynamics of Multidimensional Poverty in Australia

Pro-Poor Growth in Turkey

A note on pro-poor growth

Pro-poor growth. Abdelkrim Araar, Sami Bibi and Jean-Yves Duclos. Workshop on poverty and social impact analysis Dakar, Senegal, 8-12 June 2010

On Distributional change, Pro-poor growth and Convergence

Labour markets, social transfers and child poverty

A LONGITUDINAL ANALYSIS OF INCOME-RELATED HEALTH INEQUALITY IN AUSTRALIA

Housing affordability Keeping a home on a low-income

A weakly relative poverty line for South Africa

"Concepts and Operationalisation of Pro-Poor Growth: A Usable PPG Index" Inequality

John Hills The distribution of welfare. Book section (Accepted version)

NON-STANDARD WORK AND INEQUALITY

Rising inequality? A stocktake of the evidence

FACES OF JOBLESSNESS IN PORTUGAL: UNDERSTANDING EMPLOYMENT BARRIERS TO INFORM POLICY

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

Income inequality and mobility in Australia over the last decade

Growth and Income Inequality Effects on Poverty: The Case of Pakistan ( )

Changes to family payments will increase child poverty

Endogenous Labour Supply in CGE-Household Micro-Simulation-Top-Down/Bottom Up Model

Research (Level 6, FBE Building, 111 Barry St), University of Melbourne, Victoria, 3010 Australia. [

Measuring the Pro-Poorness of Income Growth Within an Elasticity Framework

Factor Decomposition of the Wealth Distribution in the Euro Area

ECON 450 Development Economics

BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE INEQUALITY IN LATER LIFE. The superannuation effect. Helen Hodgson, Alan Tapper and Ha Nguyen

Emerging Issues for Community Sector Leaders. #EmergingIssues2018

How Income Segmentation Affects Income Mobility: Evidence from Panel Data in the Philippines

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

Trends in Public Opinion towards Welfare in Australia

The Minimum Wage, Turnover, and the Shape of the Wage Distribution

Workforce participation of mature aged women

JUNE Living Standards REPORT HIGHLIGHTS. ANDREW SHARPE AND JEAN-FRANÇOIS ARSENAULT Centre for the Study of Living Standards (CSLS)

The Links between Income Distribution and Poverty Reduction in Britain

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

A Unified Framework for Pro-Poor Growth Analysis. B. Essama-Nssah. Poverty Reduction Group The World Bank Washington, D.C.

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

How clear are relative poverty measures to the common public?

Marginal Benefit Incidence of Pubic Health Spending: Evidence from Indonesian sub-national data

Poverty in Australia 2018: Methods, Findings and Implications

MEASURING POVERTY USING BOTH INCOME AND WEALTH: A CROSS-COUNTRY COMPARISON BETWEEN THE U.S. AND SPAIN

School Attendance, Child Labour and Cash

Creating Labor Market Diagnostics in LICs and MICs

Growth in Pakistan: Inclusive or Not? Zunia Saif Tirmazee 1 and Maryiam Haroon 2

The labor market in Australia,

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

Industrial Relations Legislation Policy Background Paper

Social Protection and Social Inclusion in Europe Key facts and figures

Report of the National Equality Panel: Executive summary

Investing for our Future Welfare. Peter Whiteford, ANU

ECONOMIC INEQUALITIES IN HEALTH

Does Raising the Minimum Wage Help the Poor?

THE COST OF INACTION ON THE SOCIAL DETERMINANTS OF HEALTH

Healthcare projections in Treasury s Long-term Fiscal Model

Assessing Developments and Prospects in the Australian Welfare State

Inter-ethnic Marriage and Partner Satisfaction

Has Indonesia s Growth Between Been Pro-Poor? Evidence from the Indonesia Family Life Survey

Discussion Papers. Would a Legal Minimum Wage Reduce Poverty? A Microsumulation Study for Germany. Kai-Uwe Müller Viktor Steiner.

Social Determinants of Health: employment and working conditions

Who earns minimum wages in Europe? New evidence based on household surveys

The Eternal Triangle of Growth, Inequality and Poverty Reduction

Can pro-growth policies lift all boats? An analysis based on household disposable incomes

CHAPTER \11 SUMMARY OF FINDINGS, CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTION. decades. Income distribution, as reflected in the distribution of household

Can pro-growth policies lift all boats? An analysis based on household disposable incomes

Quarterly Labour Force Survey Q3:2017

Research Team: Peter Saunders (Chief Investigator) and Melissa Wong (Research Associate)

Regional Tripartite Meeting on Wage Policies in the Arab Countries

CHA-NATSEM Report on Health Inequalities. PREPARED BY Professor Laurie Brown and Doctor Binod Nepal. PREPARED FOR Catholic Health Australia

Policy Brief Estimating Differential Mortality from EU- SILC Longitudinal Data a Feasibility Study

NATSEM

Economic Standard of Living

Test Yourself: Income, Transfers and Taxes

INDIGENOUS DARWIN AND THE REST OF THE NORTHERN TERRITORY

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Income Poverty, Subjective Poverty and Financial Stress

Mobility among the Low Paid Workforce

SOCIAL PROTECTION IN VIETNAM: Successes and obstacles to progressively

Australian welfare spending trends: past changes and future drivers Brotherhood of St Laurence lunchtime seminar

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

POVERTY IN AUSTRALIA: NEW ESTIMATES AND RECENT TRENDS RESEARCH METHODOLOGY FOR THE 2016 REPORT

AN ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY OF RECENT RESEARCH ON LABOUR RELATIONS POLICY, UNIONIZATION, AND CANADA-U.S. LABOUR MARKET PERFORMANCE

Indicators of Poverty and Disadvantage in Queensland

Income inequality: policy response from the EU perspective. 5 October 2017 Aurimas Andrulis, DG EMPL

Staying the Course? Inter-generational Implications of Budget Repair

Findings of the 2018 HILDA Statistical Report

Tools for analysing growth and poverty: An introduction

Inclusive Growth, Poverty and Inequality in Pacific Island Countries

Income Distribution Database (

Economic standard of living

Beyond stereotypes. Myths and facts about people of working age who receive social security

vio SZY em Growing Unequal? INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN OECD COUNTRIES

Multidimensional Poverty in India: Has the Growth been Pro-Poor on Multiple Dimensions? Uppal Anupama (Punjabi University)

Benchmarking Global Poverty Reduction

ANNEX 1: Data Sources and Methodology

The Relationship between Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty

Social Protection Strategy of Vietnam, : 2020: New concept and approach. Hanoi, 14 October, 2010

Gender Pay Gap and Quantile Regression in European Families

On Assessing Pro-Poorness of Governments Programs: International Comparisons

Pro-Poor Growth Strategies in Africa

Tax Progressivity in Australia:

The Association Between Indigenous Australians Labour Force Participation Rates and Access to Transport

Comparison of pension systems in five countries: Iceland Denmark The Netherlands Sweden United Kingdom

Transcription:

Has Australian Economic Growth Been Good for the Poor? Francisco Azpitarte Melbourne Institute & Brotherhood of St Laurence NERO Meeting, OECD June 2012 FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 1 / 30

Aim of the presentation Investigate whether strong economic growth in Australia in the last decade was beneficial for the most disadvantaged individuals in society. We use different approaches and concepts proposed in the literature. Assess how the conclusion about the pro-poorness of economic growth depends on how we measure disadvantage and the approach to poverty considered: )One-dimensional: income poverty )Multidimensional: social exclusion approach FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 2 / 30

Outline 1 The facts 2 Pro-poor growth analysis 3 Data sources 4 Empirical approaches: - Measures and Results 5 Conclusions FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 3 / 30

The Facts We focus on the period between 2001-2008. Australia outperformed most rich economies: income grew more than 2%-$ 1,000 per year; large unemployment decline, from 7 to about 4 per cent. Unemployment(%) 4 5 6 7 Fig. 1 Unemployment & Income pc : 2000 2008 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Unemployment Income 36000 38000 40000 42000 44000 46000 Income FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 4 / 30

Pro-poor growth analysis Recent literature in economics on how to measure pro-poorness. Focus in income-poor countries and poverty reduction. Pro-poor growth analysis can provide insights also in high-income countries. Pro-poor growth evaluations use distribution analysis to assess the extent to which income gains benefit the poorest in society. Pro-poor growth measures provide valuable insights about the distributional consequences of growth that could not be obtained from standard inequality and poverty studies. What is pro-poor? Many ways of evaluating distributional changes They agree pro-poor growth must benefit the poor...but no consensus on how large the benefit should be FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 5 / 30

Pro-poor growth analysis: Definitions 1 Poverty reducing: pro-poor iff it increases the income of the poor (Ravallion, 2004) )pro-poor growth is independent of the distribution of gains between the poor and non-poor 2 Relative pro-poor: the poor should benefit relatively more than the non-poor (Kakwani et al.,2004) )income growth rate of the poor is larger that the average growth rate 3 Absolute pro-poor: the poor should receive in absolute terms more than the non-poor (Kakwani et al.,2004))absolute income gain of the poor larger than the mean increase in the population so clearly [3] ) [2] ) [1] FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 6 / 30

Pro-poor growth analysis: Approaches Two approaches: 1 Standard approach [Ravallion and Chen 2003; Kakwani 2003] )Cross-section comparisons of marginal distributions of income: F 2001 (y) and F 2008 (y) )Income change of different positions within the distribution )Consistent with the anonymity axiom. Economic mobility is not taken into account 2 Non-anonymous approach [Grimm 2007; Bourguignon 2010] )Income gains experimented by those who were poor before growth )Axiom is removed. Consider economic mobility as we examine the benefits of those who were initially most disadvantaged FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 7 / 30

Data Sources We use data from the first eight waves of the Hilda survey run by the MIAESR. It includes multiple information convenient for our needs: )Anonymity : Every wave includes income information for a sample that is representative of the Australian population, so we can infer F 2001 (y) and F 2008 (y). [Wave 1:19,000, Wave 5 and 8 >17,000] )Non-anonymity: Hilda includes a panel of individuals who were above 15 years old when first interviewed in 2001. We can link income changes with the initial conditions of individuals in 2001. [Panel with more than 8,700 observations] FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 8 / 30

Data Sources Unit of analysis: individual. Income measure: real equivalent household disposable income. It is the sum of: 8 >< >: Wages and salaries Business and investment income Private pensions Public transfers: government income and non-income support payments Taxes Equivalence scale: p N, where N is the household size FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 9 / 30

Anonymity: measures ) Partial instrument We use the Growth incidence curve [Ravallion & Chen (2003)] g(p) = Q 2008(p) Q 2001(p) 1, where Q(p) is the quantile function, s.t. g(p) summarizes the change at every position - p- between two periods. ) Complete [Ravallion & Chen (2003): Kakwani & Son (2008)] PEGR = δ t η t γ t (δ t and η t ; growth elasticities of poverty) > 0 ) poverty reducing > γ ) relative pro poor > γ ) absolute pro poor FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 10 / 30

Anonymity: results Rise in all positions)growth was poverty reducing Fig.2 GIC Australia 2001 2008 Fig.3 GIC Australia 2001 05 and 2005 08 Annual growth % 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 20 40 60 80 100 percentile gps_2001_08 mean Annual growth % 0 2 4 6 8 0 20 40 60 80 100 percentile gps_2001_05 mean gps_2005_08 FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 11 / 30

Anonymity: results We know growth was poverty reducing... but poorer positions benefited relatively less, so growth cannot be considered pro-poor according to the more strong definitions FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 12 / 30

Anonymity: results Income-growth in Australia between 2001-08 can be considered pro-poor only we adopt a "weak" definition of pro-poorness. It cannot be considered pro-poor according to the more demanding definitions proposed by Kakwani et al.(2004) that require a particular distribution of benefits between the poor and the non-poor. The reason is that top-positions benefited more than bottom positions in both absolute and relative terms. FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 13 / 30

Non-anonymity: idea Problem: anonymous measures do not take into account the extent to which growth benefited the initially poor Idea: Measure the income changes of those individuals with more disadvantage in the first period: two measures of initial disadvantage )One-dimensional: income level in 2001 )Multidimensional: Brotherhood SL-MI Social exclusion measure: Sum-Score measure based on 21 indicators from 7 domains: Material, Employment, Education, Health, Social, Community, and Safety FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 14 / 30

Non-anonymity: measures ) Partial instrument:[grimm (2007)] We use the Individual Growth incidence curve : g(p(ω 2001 )) = Y 2008(p(Ω 2001 )) Y 2001(p(Ω2001 )) 1, Now, g(p) summarizes the change of individuals for every level of initial disadvantage. ) Complete measure: [Grimm (2007)] Mean growth rate among the most disadvantaged p % MGRIP(p) = 1 H t 1 R Ht 1 0 g t (p(ω t 1 ))dp, FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 15 / 30

Non-anonymity: results Income gains for those in low income in 2001 larger than among the most excluded increment $ 0 500 1000 1500 IGIC Increments: 2001 08 growth % 2 0 2 4 6 IGIC growth: 2001 08 0 20 40 60 80 100 percentile Income_i SE_i 0 20 40 60 80 100 percentile Income_r mean_r SE_r FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 16 / 30

Non-anonymity: results Growth was pro-income poor than pro-socially excluded FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 17 / 30

How can we explain the gap between IP and SE? The panel allows us to link income changes with initial characteristics)we can identify the groups that benefited most from economic growth Low growth: High growth: Above 60, Long-term unemployed, Poor-English, Disabled and Poor Health (mental) Age<35, working full time, students Comparison of IP vs SE (bottom 15%) ) SE are younger (share of above 65 is half that of the IP) ) Incidence of Disabled, Poor-English, Poor health and long term unemployed is higher among the SE FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 18 / 30

How can we explain the gap between IP and SE? We use counterfactual analysis: reweighting method proposed by DiNardo et al.(1996). We derive the distribution of growth rates of the SE assuming the characteristics of the SI Z Z G IP G SE (g) = f (gjx, G SE ) f x (xjg IP )dx = Ω x Ω x f (gjx, G SE ) Ψ x (x) f x (xjg SE )dx The contribution of each covariates (or group) to the "explained" gap is estimated using the Shapley value: Sh j = SK, j2s (s 1)!(k 1)! k! [e(s) e(snfjg)] e(k) with k j=1 Sh j = 1 FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 19 / 30

How can we explain the gap between IP and SE? COUNTERFACTUAL ANALYSIS: IP VS SE (15%) Distribution of growth rates (all in %) Income poor SE SE Coun Variation Explained gap Mean 5.10 1.96 3.22 64.02 40.09 P 10th -1.81-6.31-5.20 17.59 24.67 P 20th 0.06-3.43-2.58 24.78 24.36 P 50th 3.32 1.76 1.88 6.82 7.69 P 80th 10.97 7.38 7.97 7.99 16.43 FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 20 / 30

How can we explain the gap between IP and SE? COUNTERFACTUAL ANALYSIS: IP VS SE (15%) Shapley contributions: explained gap in the mean Initial characteristics Demographic Socioeconomic Household Age, sex of head, and family type Poor region (SEIFA index), Equ.income Housing tenure, jobless household Demographic Labour status and skills Health and disability Individual Age, Sex, Indigenous background Labour status, years of education, English General, physical, mental health, and disabilities FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 21 / 30

How can we explain the gap between IP and SE? COUNTERFACTUAL ANALYSIS: IP VS SE (15%) Shapley contributions: explained gap in the mean Initial characteristics Marginal effect Shapley (%) Household Demographic 0.16 13.05 Socioeconomic 0.35 27.72 Individual Demographic 0.0005 0.38 Labour status and skills 024 18.74 Health and disability 0.50 40.06 Total 100.00 FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 22 / 30

Conclusions We find that growth in Australia between 2001-08 can be considered pro-poor only for the "weak" definition of pro-poor growth. It cannot be considered pro-poor according to more demanding definitions as growth benefited relatively more top-positions than bottom positions Growth was more pro-income poor than pro-socially excluded as those who were income-poor in 2001 grew more in both relative and absolute terms than the socially excluded The larger presence of poor-health individuals, disabled people, individuals with low English skills, and long-term unemployed among the SE, helps us to understand why growth was more pro-income poor than pro-socially excluded FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 23 / 30

NERO MEETING OECD, PARIS JUNE, 2012 FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 24 / 30

Appendix FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 25 / 30

Appendix FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 26 / 30

Appendix FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 27 / 30

Appendix FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 28 / 30

Appendix FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 29 / 30

Appendix FAzpitarte (MIAESR & BSL) June 2012 30 / 30