The optimal in ation rate revisited

Similar documents
Inflation targets, endogenous mark-ups and the non-vertical Phillips curve.

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

On the new Keynesian model

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

Austerity in the Aftermath of the Great Recession

The design of the funding scheme of social security systems and its role in macroeconomic stabilization

Table 1. Statutory tax rates on capital income.

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Discussion: The Optimal Rate of Inflation by Stephanie Schmitt- Grohé and Martin Uribe

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

On the Design of an European Unemployment Insurance Mechanism

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

Some Basic Facts about Government Expenditures and Taxation in Canada. Econ 525

Demographic Trends and the Real Interest Rate

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2017

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2018

Prudential Policy For Peggers

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity Currency Pegs And Involuntary Unemployment

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

EUROPA - Press Releases - Taxation trends in the European Union EU27 tax...of GDP in 2008 Steady decline in top corporate income tax rate since 2000

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Uninsured Unemployment Risk and Optimal Monetary Policy

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Why Are Interest Rates So Low? The Role of Demographic Change

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

Macroprudential Policy Implementation in a Heterogeneous Monetary Union

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

The theoretical framework within which optimal monetary policy was

Statistical Annex ANNEX

Taxation trends in the European Union Further increase in VAT rates in 2012 Corporate and top personal income tax rates inch up after long decline

The Global Financial Crisis and the Return of the Nordic Model?

How does labour market structure affect the response of economies to shocks?

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

2017 Federico Caffè Lectures. Monetary Policy in Times of Low Inflation

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Is Government Spending: at the Zero Lower Bound Desirable?

Understanding the World Economy. Fiscal policy. Nicolas Coeurdacier Lecture 9

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

A Comparison of the Tax Burden on Labor in the OECD, 2017

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

TAX POLICY: RECENT TRENDS AND REFORMS IN OECD COUNTRIES FOREWORD

International Seminar on Strengthening Public Investment and Managing Fiscal Risks from Public-Private Partnerships

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe

Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity in the OECD

Payroll Taxes in Canada from 1997 to 2007

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

International Debt Deleveraging

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

Financial Integration, Financial Deepness and Global Imbalances

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Performance Budgeting (PB) in OECD Countries

Understanding the World Economy Master in Economics and Business. Fiscal policy. Nicolas Coeurdacier

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

International Statistical Release

International Macroeconomics

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2014

The Case for Fundamental Tax Reform: Overview of the Current Tax System

Low employment among the 50+ population in Hungary

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

Self-fulfilling Recessions at the ZLB

Fiscal devaluation and Economic Activity in the EU

T5-Europe The Jus Semper Global Alliance 01/09/16 1 6

The Risk of Hitting the Zero Lower Bound and the Optimal Inflation Target

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Private pensions. A growing role. Who has a private pension?

Fiscal Policy in Japan

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Optimality of Inflation and Nominal Output Targeting

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

A NOTE ON PUBLIC SPENDING EFFICIENCY

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

Housing Market Heterogeneity in a Monetary Union

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Policy Implications of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Fiscal Policy, Welfare, and the Zero Lower Bound

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Taxes and the Fed: Theory and Evidence from Equities

Transcription:

The optimal in ation rate revisited Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Università di Teramo gdibartolomeo@unite.it Patrizio Tirelli, Università di Milano Bicocca patrizio.tirelli@unimib.it Nicola Acocella, Università La Sapienza, Roma nicola.acocella@uniroma1.it Milano Bicocca October, 2010 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 1 / 38

Literature 1/3 Optimal monetary policy analyses (Khan et al., 2003; Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, SGU henceforth, 2004a) identify two key frictions driving the optimal level of long-run (or trend) in ation. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 2 / 38

Literature 1/3 Optimal monetary policy analyses (Khan et al., 2003; Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, SGU henceforth, 2004a) identify two key frictions driving the optimal level of long-run (or trend) in ation. Adjustment cost of goods prices, which invariably drives the optimal in ation rate to zero. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 2 / 38

Literature 1/3 Optimal monetary policy analyses (Khan et al., 2003; Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, SGU henceforth, 2004a) identify two key frictions driving the optimal level of long-run (or trend) in ation. Adjustment cost of goods prices, which invariably drives the optimal in ation rate to zero. Monetary transaction costs that arise unless the central bank implements the Friedman rule, i.e. a negative steady-state in ation rate as long as the steady-state real interest rate is positive. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 2 / 38

Literature 1/3 Optimal monetary policy analyses (Khan et al., 2003; Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, SGU henceforth, 2004a) identify two key frictions driving the optimal level of long-run (or trend) in ation. Adjustment cost of goods prices, which invariably drives the optimal in ation rate to zero. Monetary transaction costs that arise unless the central bank implements the Friedman rule, i.e. a negative steady-state in ation rate as long as the steady-state real interest rate is positive. Phelps (1973) conjectured that to alleviate the burden of distortionary taxation it might be optimal for governments to resort to monetary nancing, driving a wedge between the private and the social cost of money. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 2 / 38

Literature 2/3 SGU (2004a) show that, even accounting for the Phelps e ect, the optimal in ation rate lies between zero and the Friedman rule, being very close to zero for apparently plausible parameterizations of the model. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 3 / 38

Literature 2/3 SGU (2004a) show that, even accounting for the Phelps e ect, the optimal in ation rate lies between zero and the Friedman rule, being very close to zero for apparently plausible parameterizations of the model. "Consensus" view: stable prices are the proper policy target because monetary transactions costs are relatively low at zero in ation. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 3 / 38

Literature 2/3 SGU (2004a) show that, even accounting for the Phelps e ect, the optimal in ation rate lies between zero and the Friedman rule, being very close to zero for apparently plausible parameterizations of the model. "Consensus" view: stable prices are the proper policy target because monetary transactions costs are relatively low at zero in ation. In their survey of the literature, SGU (2010) argue that the optimality of zero in ation is robust to other frictions, such as nominal wage adjustment costs, downward wage rigidity, hedonic prices, incompleteness of the tax system, the zero bound on the nominal interest rate Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 3 / 38

Literature 3/3 "Consensus" view is in sharp contrast with empirical evidence. Both in the US and in the Euro area, average in ation rates over the 1970-1999 period have been close to 5%. Even the widespread central bank practice of adopting in ation targets between 2 and 4% is apparently at odds with theories of the optimal in ation rate (SGU, 2010). Estimates of the Fed implicit in ation target: Ireland. "The target rose from 1.25% in 1959 to over 8% in the mid-to-late 1970s before falling back below 2.5% percent in 2004" Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2008) 3.2% over the period 1957-2000 and 5.6% over the high in ation sub-sample 1973-1991 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 4 / 38

Aim of the paper In this paper we reconsider the issue, showing that dismissal of the Phelps e ect is due to an unrealistic parameterization for public expenditures and overall taxation and thus appears premature. Standard calibrations of public expenditures focus on public consumption-to-gdp ratios, typically set at 20% (SGU, 2004a; Aruoba and Schorfeide, 2009). This follows a long-standing tradition in business cycle models, where only public consumption decisions have real e ects. In our framework this choice is not correct, because the focus here is on distortionary nancing of public expenditures in steady state, where also other components of public expenditure matter. In the US, over the peiod 1998-2008 government transfer payments and government purchases respectively were 11.8% and almost 20% of GDP. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 5 / 38

Table 1 Government expenditures and revenues (1998-2008)* (1) (2) (3) (1) (2) (3) Australia 18,00 16,97 36,26 Japan 17,07 21,28 31,81 Austria 19,10 32,29 49,71 Netherlands 23,57 22,19 45,34 Belgium 22,13 27,82 49,39 New Zealand 17,97 20,89 42,01 Canada 19,49 21,56 42,08 Norway 20,76 23,54 56,63 Czech Republic 21,24 22,81 40,12 Poland 17,95 25,34 39,20 Denmark 25,84 27,88 55,96 Portugal 19,57 25,48 41,59 Finland 21,75 27,74 53,12 Slovak Republic 20,24 21,35 36,55 France 23,39 29,21 49,90 Spain 17,75 21,52 38,67 Germany 18,96 27,58 44,61 Sweden 26,67 29,03 57,21 Greece 16,52 28,32 40,19 Switzerland 11,4 23,48 34,40 Hungary 21,98 27,42 43,20 United Kingdom 19,83 22,28 40,38 Ireland 15,11 19,40 44,16 United States 15,26 20,51 33,47 Italy 19,10 28,94 45,25 Euro area 20,17 27,11 45,39 (1) public consumption; (2) other public expenditures; (3) total revenues * ratios to GDP Source OECD Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 6 / 38

Our results Results in a nutshell We show that just allowing for a plausible parameterization of public transfers to households in the SGU (2004a) model reverses their conclusion about the optimal in ation rate, which now monotonically increases from 2% to 12% as the transfers-to-gdp ratio goes from 10% to 20%. We also nd that an identical increase in the public-consumption-to GDP ratio would have a negligible impact on the optimal in ation rate. So, what is special about public transfers? Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 7 / 38

Intuition Assume that lump-sum taxes can be used to nance expenditures. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 8 / 38

Intuition Assume that lump-sum taxes can be used to nance expenditures. In case of public transfers changes, the overall e ect on the household budget constraint is nil, and labor-consumption decisions are unchanged. An increase in public consumption generates a negative wealth e ect that raises the labor supply. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 8 / 38

Intuition Assume that lump-sum taxes can be used to nance expenditures. In case of public transfers changes, the overall e ect on the household budget constraint is nil, and labor-consumption decisions are unchanged. An increase in public consumption generates a negative wealth e ect that raises the labor supply. If lump sum taxes are not available, the di erent wealth e ect, i.e. the di erent labor supply response, explains why nancing transfers requires higher tax rates than nancing an identical amount of public consumption. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 8 / 38

Intuition Assume that lump-sum taxes can be used to nance expenditures. In case of public transfers changes, the overall e ect on the household budget constraint is nil, and labor-consumption decisions are unchanged. An increase in public consumption generates a negative wealth e ect that raises the labor supply. If lump sum taxes are not available, the di erent wealth e ect, i.e. the di erent labor supply response, explains why nancing transfers requires higher tax rates than nancing an identical amount of public consumption. Since the incentive to monetary nancing is increasing in the amount of tax distortions, this explains why the optimal nancing mix requires stronger reliance on in ation when we take transfers into account. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 8 / 38

Extensions Our result is robust to the inclusion of nominal wage rigidity, and is strengthened when we allow for a moderate degree of price and wage indexation (20%). Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 9 / 38

Extensions Our result is robust to the inclusion of nominal wage rigidity, and is strengthened when we allow for a moderate degree of price and wage indexation (20%). Consumption scale e ects in the monetary transactions technology (Theoretical models: Baumol, 1952; Khan et al., 2003; empirical evidence: Attanasio et al., 2002). We nd that such consumption scale e ects unambiguously contribute to raise the optimal in ation rate. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 9 / 38

Extensions Our result is robust to the inclusion of nominal wage rigidity, and is strengthened when we allow for a moderate degree of price and wage indexation (20%). Consumption scale e ects in the monetary transactions technology (Theoretical models: Baumol, 1952; Khan et al., 2003; empirical evidence: Attanasio et al., 2002). We nd that such consumption scale e ects unambiguously contribute to raise the optimal in ation rate. Intuition. An increase in in ation allows a reduction in distortionary taxation but it raises the monetary transaction costs. This latter e ect is weakened when the transaction cost is inversely related to the amount of consumption, which, in turn, increases if the tax rate falls. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 9 / 38

Calibration Finally, we calibrate the model to the US economy. Our purpose is to benchmark the optimal in ation rate against Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2008) estimates of the time-varying in ation target implicitly adopted by the Federal Reserve over the period 1957-2000 and over the high in ation subsample 1973-1991. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 10 / 38

Calibration Finally, we calibrate the model to the US economy. Our purpose is to benchmark the optimal in ation rate against Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2008) estimates of the time-varying in ation target implicitly adopted by the Federal Reserve over the period 1957-2000 and over the high in ation subsample 1973-1991. We consider di erent estimates of price rigidities found in the literature, and nd that in all cases the optimal in ation rate is positive and increasing during the 1973-1991 subsample. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 10 / 38

The model Households U = C t,i = t=0 Z 1 0 β t u (C t,i, l t,i ) ; u (C t,i, l t,i ) = ln C t,i + η ln (1 l t,i ) 1 ρ Z 1 c t,i (j) di ρ, l t,j = 0 σ l t,j (i) σ σ 1 σ 1 di C t,i (1 + S t,i ) + M t,i + B t,i = (1 τ t) w t,i l t,i + M t 1,i + T t + R t 1B t 1,i P t,i P t P t P t P t P t Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 11 / 38

The model Monetary transaction costs Monetary transaction costs (no consumption scale e ects) strictly follow SGU (2004a) S t,i = s(v t,i ) = Av t,i + B v t,i 2 p AB Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 12 / 38

The model Sticky price We assume a sticky price speci cation based on Rotemberg (1982) quadratic cost of nominal price adjustment: ξ p 2 P t (j)/p t π δ t 1 1 (j) 1! 2 where ξ p > 0 is a measure of price stickiness and π t = P t /P t 1 denotes the gross in ation rate and δ 2 [0, 1] is the degree of price indexation to past in ation. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 13 / 38

The model Wage-setting decisions The labour market is also characterized by monopolistic competition and rigid nominal wages. Under exible wages W t = µ w u l (C t, l t ) Ω t P t u c (C t, l t ) where µ w = σ (σ 1) 1 denotes the gross wage markup and Ω t = 1+s(v t )+v t s 0 (v t ) 1 τ t denotes the policy wedge, which depends on both tax and in ation decisions. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 14 / 38

The model Wage stickiness We model nominal wage stickiness as in Rotemberg (1982). ξ w 2 W t (j)/w t 1 (j) π δ 1 w t 1! 2 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 15 / 38

The model Government and aggregate resource constraint Government budget constraint R t 1 B t 1 P t w t + G t + T t = τ t l t + M t M t 1 + B t P t P t P t Aggregate resource constraint Y t = C t (1 + S t ) + G t + ξ p 2 π t π δ t 1! 2 1 + ξ w 2 w t w t 1 π δ w t 1 1! 2 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 16 / 38

Simulantions I Replicate SGU (2004a) with the addition that 0 < T Y < 20%. Table 2 β = 0.96 µ p = 1.20 µ w = 1.00 A = 0.011 ξ p = 4.37 ξ w = 0.00 B = 0.075 δ p = 0.00 δ w = 0.00 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 17 / 38

inflation (%) 14 12 variation in government consumption variation in government transfers 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 0 5 10 15 20 expenditure on output (%) Figure 1 Public expenditure and optimal in ation Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 18 / 38

Driving factors behind the optimal policy mix The distortionary taxation necessary to nance the additional transfers adversely a ects the labour supply and reduces the tax base. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 19 / 38

Driving factors behind the optimal policy mix The distortionary taxation necessary to nance the additional transfers adversely a ects the labour supply and reduces the tax base. By contrast, the increase in public consumption generates a negative wealth e ect that triggers a positive labour supply response and expands the tax base. In this case the incentive to increase in ation is much reduced. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 19 / 38

The policy wedge π t, τ t have di erent e ects on the policy wedge Ω t = 1 + s(v t) + v t s 0 (v t ) 1 τ t Ω 0 t (τ t ), Ω 0 t (π t ) > 0 but Ω 00 t (τ t ) > 0, Ω 00 t (π t ) = 0. This explains why the Ramsey planner increasingly relies on the in ation tax as public expenditures grow. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 20 / 38

In Figure 2 we compare the optimal steady state value of Ω with the value that would obtain if in ation were constrained at zero. policy wedge 2.1 zero inflation optimal policy 2 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 0 5 10 15 20 government transfers on output (%) Figure 2 Public transfers and the policy wedge Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 21 / 38

Frequency of price adjustment Eichenbaum and Fischer (2007) infer that rms re-optimize prices once every 2.3 3 quarters, but cannot reject the hypothesis that rms reoptimize prices once every two quarters). Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 22 / 38

Frequency of price adjustment Eichenbaum and Fischer (2007) infer that rms re-optimize prices once every 2.3 3 quarters, but cannot reject the hypothesis that rms reoptimize prices once every two quarters). We consider the e ects of di erent degrees of stickiness (measure as average duration of price-setting decisions) assuming that T /Y = 10%. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 22 / 38

inflation (%) 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 12 9 8 7.5 6 average adjustment (months) Figure 3 Price adj.and trend in ation T /Y = 10% Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 23 / 38

inflation (%) Monopolistic distortions and optimal in ation 14 12 markup 10% markup 20% 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 0 5 10 15 20 government transfers on output (%) Figure 4 Public transfers, monopolistic distortions and optimal in ation Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 24 / 38

inflation (%) Sticky wages µ w = 1.2, ξ w = ξ p = 4.37 14 flexible competitive wages sticky monopolistic wages 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 0 4 8 12 16 20 government transfer on output (%) Figure 5 Optimal in ation: Flexible vs. sticky wages Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 25 / 38

inflation (%) Indexation δ p = δ w 16 14 no indexation 20% indexation 40% indexation 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 0 4 8 12 16 20 government transfer on output (%) Figure 6 Public transfers, indexation and optimal in ation Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 26 / 38

Extensions 1/3 Consumption scale e ects in the monetary transactions technology Theoretical models accounting for consumption scale e ects include Baumol (1952) and Khan et al. (2003). Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 27 / 38

Extensions 1/3 Consumption scale e ects in the monetary transactions technology Theoretical models accounting for consumption scale e ects include Baumol (1952) and Khan et al. (2003). Attanasio et al. (2002) nd substantial economies of scale in cash management using microdata. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 27 / 38

Extensions 1/3 Consumption scale e ects in the monetary transactions technology Theoretical models accounting for consumption scale e ects include Baumol (1952) and Khan et al. (2003). Attanasio et al. (2002) nd substantial economies of scale in cash management using microdata. Why bother? In a di erent model, Guidotti and Vegh (1993) show that the constant elasticity of scale is an unduly restrictive assumption and that it is optimal to resort to the in ation tax if the transactions costs technology does not exhibit constant returns to scale. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 27 / 38

Extensions 2/3 S t,i = s(v t,i )g(c t,i ) ; g(c t,i ) > 0, g 0 (C t,i ) < 0 g(c t,i ) = C θ t,i θ 0 η m = (M t /P t ) C M t P t = q B C M t /P t = C t A + (R t 1 1) C θ t A 1 θ (R 2 B + (R 1) C θ 1) C θ 1 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 28 / 38

Extensions 3/3 λ t = u c (C t, l t ) 1 + S t + C t S t C t = u c (C t, l t ) 1 + s 0 (v t )v t +(1 θ)s(v t ) C θ The transactions-induced wedge between the marginal utility of consumption and the marginal utility of wealth unambiguously falls in θ for any level of money velocity. Our conjecture is that this should support an increase in the optimal in ation rate. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 29 / 38

Scenarios Three di erent scenarios. 1 We represent an economy calibrated as in SGU (2004a), where parameters are calibrated as in table 2 with G /Y = 0.2, T /Y = 0. 2 We assume sticky wages (with µ p = 1.2 and ξ w = 4.37), 20% indexation on both prices and wages, public consumption set at 20% and a transfer equal to 11% of output. 3 We assume that prices are relatively exible and the degree of price indexation to past in ation is modest, whereas wages are characterised by strong indexation, as found in Galí and Rabanal (2005), Rabanal and Rubio-Ramírez (2005), Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2008) and Christiano et al. (2010). Relative to scenario 2, we set ξ p = 2.5 (i.e., price are reset about every six months on average), δ p = 0.15 and δ w = 0.85 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 30 / 38

Table 3 Consumption scale e ects scenario 1 scenario 2 scenario 3 θ π η π η m π η m 0.0-0.15 1.000 4.43 1.000 7.87 1.000 0.4 0.00 0.959 4.63 0.962 8.26 0.962 0.8 0.12 0.956 4.80 0.963 8.55 0.963 1.2 0.19 0.967 4.92 0.974 8.95 0.974 1.6 0.23 0.978 4.98 0.984 9.13 0.984 2.0 0.25 0.987 5.00 0.991 9.22 0.991 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 31 / 38

Time-varying in ation targets Fernandez-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramirez (2008) estimates the time-varying in ation target implicitly adopted by the Federal Reserve over the period 1957-2000 and over the high in ation sub-sample 1973-1991. Can we match their estimates? During the period 1957-2000 the average government-consumptionand transfers-to-gdp have respectively been 20% and 9%. For the sub-sample 1973-1991 we nd similar gures for G /Y and a slightly higher transfers ratio, about 10%. For the crucial parameters θ, ξ p, ξ w, δ p, δ w, µ p, µ w we consider 5 alternatives. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 32 / 38

Five alternatives 1 SGU (2004a) model: perfect competition in the labor market and no indexation. 2 Add consumption scale e ects in monetary transaction costs. 3 Introduce monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities in the labor market and allow for a moderate degree of price and wage indexation (25%). 4 The parameters describing nominal rigidities ξ p, ξ w imply that prices re-optimized on average every 10 months and wages every 9 months as in Smets and Wouters (2007). 5 We consider the highest frequency of price adjustment we found in the literature, 2 quarters, as reported in and Eichenbaum and Fisher (2007). Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 33 / 38

Five alternatives (calibrations) Table 4 The US economy calibration Fixed parameters Alternative calibrations (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) β = 0.96 θ 0 2 2 2 2 A = 0.011 ξ p 4.37 4.37 4.37 7 2.47 B = 0.075 ξ w 0 0 4.37 9.5 4.37 δ p 0 0 0.25 0.25 0.25 δ w 0 0 0.25 0.25 0.25 µ p 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 µ w 1 1 1.2 1.2 1.2 Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 34 / 38

Optimal, observed and targeted in ation Table 5 Optimal, observed and targeted in ation US economy scenario observed* est. target (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (1) whole sample 4.4 3.2 1.4 2.7 3.4 2.0 4.0 (2) high inf. period (73-91) 6.4 5.6 2.9 3.9 4.3 2.7 5.2 (*) CPI in ation, excluding food and energy. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 35 / 38

Conclusions 1/3 Since Phelps we know that a positive in ation rate might mitigate the distortions induced by need to nance government budgets. In contrast with previous research, we show that this argument is relevant given the policy mix between government consumption and transfers that we observe in OECD countries. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 36 / 38

Conclusions 1/3 Since Phelps we know that a positive in ation rate might mitigate the distortions induced by need to nance government budgets. In contrast with previous research, we show that this argument is relevant given the policy mix between government consumption and transfers that we observe in OECD countries. This result holds for plausible parameterization of price and nominal wage adjustment costs. The size of monopolistic distortions, the degree of price and wage indexation, the consumption scale e ect in monetary transaction costs unambiguously increase the optimal in ation rate. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 36 / 38

Conclusions 1/3 Since Phelps we know that a positive in ation rate might mitigate the distortions induced by need to nance government budgets. In contrast with previous research, we show that this argument is relevant given the policy mix between government consumption and transfers that we observe in OECD countries. This result holds for plausible parameterization of price and nominal wage adjustment costs. The size of monopolistic distortions, the degree of price and wage indexation, the consumption scale e ect in monetary transaction costs unambiguously increase the optimal in ation rate. Unfortunately, empirical evidence on these latter variables is rather limited. In fact estimated DSGE models typically impose markup parameters, assume a vertical long-run Phillips curve and neglect monetary transaction costs. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 36 / 38

Conclusions 2/3 Calibrations show that the prediction of a positive in ation rate holds for the US, where government size is relatively small. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 37 / 38

Conclusions 2/3 Calibrations show that the prediction of a positive in ation rate holds for the US, where government size is relatively small. A fortiori, our reconsideration of the Phelps conjecture appears even more appropriate when considering countries in the Euro area where the welfare state plays a more important role. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 37 / 38

Conclusions 2/3 Calibrations show that the prediction of a positive in ation rate holds for the US, where government size is relatively small. A fortiori, our reconsideration of the Phelps conjecture appears even more appropriate when considering countries in the Euro area where the welfare state plays a more important role. In contrast with SGU (2010), who argue that central bank in ation targets are too high, our contribution shows that a 2% target might be too low, at least for countries where the burden of taxation is rather high, such as continental Europe. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 37 / 38

Conclusions 3/3 The explanation for this might be that commitment to a low in ation rate is used to discipline spending decisions, assumed exogenous in our model. In fact several political economy models point out that distorted policymakers incentives in ate public expenditures (Tornell and Lane, 1999; and Persson and Tabellini, 2003, 2004).). Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 38 / 38

Conclusions 3/3 The explanation for this might be that commitment to a low in ation rate is used to discipline spending decisions, assumed exogenous in our model. In fact several political economy models point out that distorted policymakers incentives in ate public expenditures (Tornell and Lane, 1999; and Persson and Tabellini, 2003, 2004).). As shown in Acemoglu et al. (2009), the Ramsey-optimal taxation is substantially a ected when taxes and public good provision are decided by a self-interested politician who cannot commit to policies. In a similar vein, further research should investigate how these two frictions, i.e. politicians self-interest and lack of commitment, may a ect the choice of the optimal in ation target. Tirelli (Milano Bicocca) The optimal in ation rate revisited October, 2010 38 / 38