Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples

Similar documents
This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

Dynamic Portfolio Choice II

Portfolio Optimization using Conditional Sharpe Ratio

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

The Optimization Process: An example of portfolio optimization

Lecture IV Portfolio management: Efficient portfolios. Introduction to Finance Mathematics Fall Financial mathematics

THE OPTIMAL ASSET ALLOCATION PROBLEMFOR AN INVESTOR THROUGH UTILITY MAXIMIZATION

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Characterization of the Optimum

Mathematics in Finance

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

Multistage risk-averse asset allocation with transaction costs

Computing Bounds on Risk-Neutral Measures from the Observed Prices of Call Options

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Quantitative Risk Management

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Some useful optimization problems in portfolio theory

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Risk minimization and portfolio diversification

Chapter 8. Markowitz Portfolio Theory. 8.1 Expected Returns and Covariance

Chapter 7: Portfolio Theory

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

4: SINGLE-PERIOD MARKET MODELS

Introduction Credit risk

1 Asset Pricing: Replicating portfolios

Markowitz portfolio theory

How good are Portfolio Insurance Strategies?

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Dynamic Asset and Liability Management Models for Pension Systems

Mortgage Loan Portfolio Optimization Using Multi-Stage Stochastic Programming

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Extend the ideas of Kan and Zhou paper on Optimal Portfolio Construction under parameter uncertainty

Final Projects Introduction to Numerical Analysis Professor: Paul J. Atzberger

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Minimizing Timing Luck with Portfolio Tranching The Difference Between Hired and Fired

Lifetime Portfolio Selection: A Simple Derivation

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Systemic Influences on Optimal Investment

Effectiveness of CPPI Strategies under Discrete Time Trading

Stochastic Programming and Financial Analysis IE447. Midterm Review. Dr. Ted Ralphs

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Techniques for Calculating the Efficient Frontier

Portfolio Optimization with Alternative Risk Measures

MULTISTAGE PORTFOLIO OPTIMIZATION AS A STOCHASTIC OPTIMAL CONTROL PROBLEM

Lecture Notes 1

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

Calibration of Interest Rates

Statistical Methods in Financial Risk Management

Mean-variance optimization for life-cycle pension portfolios

Optimal Investment with Deferred Capital Gains Taxes

MS-E2114 Investment Science Lecture 5: Mean-variance portfolio theory

A Worst-Case Approach to Option Pricing in Crash-Threatened Markets

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

Birkbeck MSc/Phd Economics. Advanced Macroeconomics, Spring Lecture 2: The Consumption CAPM and the Equity Premium Puzzle

Dynamic Model of Pension Savings Management with Stochastic Interest Rates and Stock Returns

Algorithmic and High-Frequency Trading

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

Investment strategies and risk management for participating life insurance contracts

1 Dynamic programming

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Yield curve event tree construction for multi stage stochastic programming models

A Model with Costly-State Verification

The Valuation of Bermudan Guaranteed Return Contracts

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

9.1 Principal Component Analysis for Portfolios

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

Portfolio optimization problem with default risk

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Overnight Index Rate: Model, calibration and simulation

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Optimal Portfolios under a Value at Risk Constraint

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

MODELLING OPTIMAL HEDGE RATIO IN THE PRESENCE OF FUNDING RISK

Handout 8: Introduction to Stochastic Dynamic Programming. 2 Examples of Stochastic Dynamic Programming Problems

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Lecture 10: Performance measures

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Computer Exercise 2 Simulation

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Optimization II: Model-Based Portfolio Management

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

Black-Litterman Model

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Optimizing S-shaped utility and risk management

Mathematics in Finance

Distortion operator of uncertainty claim pricing using weibull distortion operator

Transcription:

Financial Giffen Goods: Examples and Counterexamples RolfPoulsen and Kourosh Marjani Rasmussen Abstract In the basic Markowitz and Merton models, a stock s weight in efficient portfolios goes up if its expected rate of return goes up. Put differently, there are no financial Giffen goods. By an example from mortgage choice we illustrate that for more complicated portfolio problems Giffen effects do occur. Keywords: Portfolio choice, Giffen good, mortgage financing. JEL code: G11 Subject category: IE13 This version: August 4, 2006. We thank Bent Jesper Christensen and Carsten Sørensen for helpful comments. (Corresponding author.) Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Universitetsparken 5, University of Copenhagen, DK-2100, Denmark. Email: rolf@math.ku.dk Informatics and Mathematical Modelling, Technical University of Denmark, Bldg. 305, DK-2800 Lyngby, Denmark. Email: kmr@imm.dtu.dk 1

1 Introduction and Summary A Giffen good is one for which demand goes down if its price goes down. At first, it is counter-intuitive that such goods exist at all. But most introductory text-books in economics will tell you that they do; some with stories about potatoes and famine in Ireland, some with first order conditions for constrained optimization and partial derivatives. In this note we study similar effects by which we mean a negative relation between expected return and demand in financial models. We first show that in the basic Markowitz mean/variance model, there are no Giffen goods; if a stock s expected rate of return goes up, its weight in any efficient portfolio goes up. This seems a text-book comparative statics result. We have, however, only been able to find it hidden in some recent articles, Stevens (1998) for example. So we give a simple proof. We then look at Merton s dynamic investment framework. In its basic version demand for any asset depends positively on its expected rate of return, but if a subsistence level is included, demand for the risk-free asset falls with the interest rate. Skeptics would say that Giffen goods exist in and only in economic text-books. Our final contribution is an illustration that Giffen effects do occur in real-life portfolio choice problems. Our example is an extension of the framework from Rasmussen & Clausen (2006) and shows that some completely rational mortgagors react to lower costs of long-term financing (reflecting a smaller market price of risk) by using more short-term 2

financing. 2 The Markowitz Model Consider a model with n risky assets with expected rate of return vector µ and invertible covariance matrix Σ. The mean/variance efficient portfolios (parametrized by risk-aversion γ) are found by solving max w w µ 1 2 γw Σw st w 1 = 1, where 1 = (1,...,1). The optimal portfolios are ŵ = γ 1 Σ 1 (µ η(γ; µ, Σ)1) where η(γ; µ, Σ) = 1 Σ 1 µ γ 1 Σ 1 1 can be interpreted as the expected rate of return on ŵ s zero-beta portfolio. A sensible definition of a Giffen good in this context would be an asset, say the i th, for which ŵ i / µ i < 0 for some γ, this meaning that when the asset s expected rate of return goes up, its weight in some optimal portfolio goes down. Let us show that there are no such assets. Look at the problem with the modified expected return vector µ + αe i, where α R and e i is the i th unit vector. This gives ŵ =... + α γ 1 (Σ 1 e i e i Σ 1 1 1 Σ 1 1 Σ 1 1) }{{} 3 h 1,

where... represents a vector that does not depend on α. Showing that ŵ i / µ i > 0 amounts to proving positivity of the i th coordinate of h 1, which we can write as The positivity then boils down to ( ) e i h 1 = γ 1 e i Σ 1 e i (e i Σ 1 1) 2. 1 Σ 1 1 (e i Σ 1 e i )(1 Σ 1 1) (e i Σ 1 1) 2? > 0. Because Σ 1 is strictly positive definite and symmetric, we may think of it as a covariance matrix of a random variable, say Y. But the left hand side in the inequality above is then the determinant of the covariance matrix of (Y i, n j=1 Y j), and thus strictly positive. The inclusion of a risk-free asset is handled in the same way with η replaced by the risk-free rate of return because the risk-free asset is any portfolio s zero-beta portfolio. 3 The Merton Model Another classic portfolio model is Merton s dynamic investment framework. In its most simple case, an agent invests his wealth, W, in either a risk-free asset with rate of return r or a risky asset whose price, S, is a Geometric Brownian motion, ds(t) = µs(t)dt + σs(t)dz(t), where Z is a Brownian motion. Suppose the agent maximizing expected utility cares only about terminal wealth, W(T), and has a utility function with constant relative risk 4

aversion, U(W(T)) = W(T)1 γ 1 γ. It is then well-known that it is optimal to invest a fixed fraction, π, of wealth in the risky asset, specifically π = µ r γσ 2. So if the expected rate of return of an asset (be that risky or risk-free) goes up, that asset gets higher weight in any agent s portfolio. Further, by combining 2-fund separation with the Markowitz analysis from the previous section, the same conclusion is reached in a model with n rather than just one risky asset. A popular extension is a utility function of the form Ũ(W(T)) = 1 γ (W(T) W), 1 γ where W is some minimal required wealth level; a subsistence level. Assuming initial wealth is greater than the present value of of W, the optimal strategy is to buy e rt W units of the risk-free asset and invest the rest of the wealth according to the Merton-rule from above. Thus the optimal fraction invested at time t in the risky asset is π(t) = W(t) e r(t t) W W(t) µ r γσ 2, so that π(0) r = 1 ( ) e rt W (T(µ r) + 1) 1. γσ 2 W(0) 5

Reasonably µ r > 0 and we see that if the subsistence level is sufficiently large compared to initial wealth then π(0)/ r > 0, so the percentage of initial wealth invested in the risky asset goes up, and hence the investment in the risk-free asset goes down when the risk-free rate of return goes up. The intuition behind is that if the return of the risk-free asset goes up, you need less of it to ensure survival, and you have more money to do what you like, rather than what you have to. 4 A Mortgage Choice Model A way to quantify mortgage planning for many people the largest financial decisions, they ever make as a portfolio optimization problem is to study minimize θ γ E(X(θ)) + (1 γ) ES β (X(θ)), where: X(θ) is the (cumulative discounted) payments from following the dynamic strategy θ; the loan portfolio the mortgagor chooses. ES β (X) = E(X X q β ) is the expected shortfall based on the β-quantile q β. Expected shortfall is a coherent risk-measure and, as shown by Rockafeller & Uryasev (2000) it gives a piece-wise linear objective function. This is an extension of the problems considered in Rasmussen & Clausen (2006), who look only at fully linear or min-max type objective functions; ie. only risk-neutrality or 6

extreme risk aversion. The minimization must be performed subject to a stochastic interest rate model discretized by paths through trees, each node having a universe of securities balance and cash-flow equations including transaction costs portfolio and cash-flow constraints such as non-negativity, liquidity This is a multi-stage stochastic programming problem that can be solved numerically using for instance GAMS and CPLEX, see Rasmussen & Clausen (2006) for details. To model the stochastic behaviour of interest rates, we use a Vasicek model dr(t) = κ(θ r(t))dt + σdz(t). To specify the full yield curve dynamics, a market price of risk is needed. We parameterize this by λ, that technically shifts the stationary mean of r to θ + λ under the risk-neutral measure, but more tellingly, determines the typical difference between long and short rates. This represents the fundamental trade-off in the mortgagor s problem: Short rates are typically lower than long rates, but with short-term financing, he doesn t know how much he ll have to pay. 7

zero coupon yield (%) 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 October 2004 February 2005 2 4 6 8 10 maturity Figure 1: Danish yield curves from October 2004 and February 2005; full curves are calibrated model curves, dotted lines are observations. The estimated Vasicek model parameters (θ, κ, σ) = (0.042, 0.21, 0.01) are held fixed and only the calibrated market price of risk, λ, differs from October 2004 (0.023) to February 2005 (0.003). Table 1 shows the composition of the initial optimal portfolios for two different values of the market price of risk. These two values correspond to calibration to observed Danish yield curves in October 2004 and February 2005, as depicted in Figure 1. (We use β = 0.95 and a 7-year horizon. Only the 1-year adjustable-rate bond and the 30- year callable, fixed-rate bond are used in the optimal portfolio, although the numerical algorithm allowed for a larger universe of mortgage products.) 8

Optimal initial loan portfolio compositions October 2004 February 2005 Mortgagor risk Fixed rate Full yearly Fixed rate Full yearly aversion (γ) callable refinancing callable refinancing 0 0% 100% 0% 100% 1/4 16% 84% 4% 96% 1/2 48% 52% 49% 51% 3/4 48% 52% 58% 42% 1 48% 52% 60% 40% Table 1: Optimal initial loan portfolio compositions for different mortgagors facing the different yield curves shown in Figure 1. Row-wise comparisons in Table 1 give no surprises. The risk-neutral mortgagor uses full short-term financing and with higher risk-aversion (higher weight to expected shortfall) more long-term financing is used. Note, however, that because short rates were historically low and the yield curve quite steep, even very risk-averse mortgagors use a significant amount of short-term financing (52% for October 2004, 40% for February 2005). Comparing the columns tells us what a lowering of the market price of risk parameter can do to optimal portfolios. The very risk-averse mortgagor uses a larger proportion (60% compared to 48%) of fixed-rate loans, and the risk-neutral mortgagor 9

does not care. But for a moderately risk-averse mortgagor (γ = 1/4), the lower λ- value, which makes short-term financing relatively less attractive, causes him to use more short-term financing (up to 96% compared to 84% before). Although a more complicated model, the intuition is again that this mortgagor uses long-term financing initially not because he wants to, but because he has to, and lower long rates still higher than typical short rates make the necessity cheaper; like the Irish potatoes. References Rasmussen, K. M. & Clausen, J. (2006), Mortgage Loan Portfolio Optimization Using Multi Stage Stochastic Programming. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, forthcoming. Rockafeller, R. T. & Uryasev, S. (2000), Optimization of conditional value-at-risk, Journal of Risk 2, 21 41. Stevens, G. V. G. (1998), On the Inverse of the Covariance Matrix in Portfolio Analysis, Journal of Finance 53, 1821 1827. 10