Economics 230a, Fall 2018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition

Similar documents
Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 12: Introduction to International Taxation

Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting. Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

BEPS, SPILLOVERS, ETC.: CURRENT ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL CORPORATE TAXATION

Economics 230a, Fall 2017 Lecture Note 6: Basic Tax Incidence

Consumption and Cash-Flow Taxes in an International Setting Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND TRADE POLICY

Cash Flow Taxes in an International Setting

Sam Bucovetsky und Andreas Haufler: Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries

Lecture 7: Taxation of capital income

Corporate Taxation. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

ec nfip Economists for Inclusive Prosperity

Overview Basic analysis Strategic trade policy Further topics. Overview

The Solow Growth Model. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Ricardo. The Model. Ricardo s model has several assumptions:

Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in Open Economies

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 9: Dynamic Taxation II Optimal Capital Taxation

Macroeconomic Theory IV: New Keynesian Economics

The international mobility of tax bases: An introduction

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 7: Optimal Top Income Taxation

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Monetary credibility problems. 1. In ation and discretionary monetary policy. 2. Reputational solution to credibility problems

The one-minute trade policy theorist. (most of what you need to know)

Capital Taxation after EU Enlargement

Destination-based cash flow tax

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Games Within Borders:

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Growth and Ideas. Martin Ellison, Hilary Term 2017

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

California s ongoing budget crises have prompted a serious evaluation of the state s

Equilibrium with Production and Labor Supply

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Volatility and Growth: Credit Constraints and the Composition of Investment

Strategic environmental standards and the role of foreign direct investment *

Intellectual Property

Lecture 7: Corporate income taxation

Outsourcing under Incomplete Information

Basic structure Supplements. Labor productivity and comparative advantages: The Ricardian Model. Robert Stehrer. Version: March 6, 2013

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

International Tax Reforms with Flexible Prices

Tax Avoidance and Tax Incidence

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Monetary Policy. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

The Multiplier Model

Taxing Corporate Income

International Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Trading Company and Indirect Exports

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY Department of Economics. Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory Spring PROBLEM SET 1 (Solutions) Y = C + I + G + NX

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Stanford Economics 266: International Trade Lecture 8: Factor Proportions Theory (I)

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

MEASURING TAXES ON INCOME FROM CAPITAL:

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Residual Profit Allocation Proposal

International Trade Lecture 8: Strategic Trade Policy

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Keynesian Models

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

MACROECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE TAX REFORM ACT OF 2014

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Issues in the Design of Taxes on Corporate Profit. Michael Devereux

A Global Safe Asset for & from Emerging Economies

Macroeconomic impacts of limiting the tax deductibility of interest expenses of inbound companies

The Development and Use of Models for Fiscal Policy Analysis. Alan Auerbach September 23, 2016

004: Macroeconomic Theory

The Allocation of Profits and the OECD Approach to Business Restructuring. Christopher Heady

Regret Minimization and Security Strategies

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. The challenges of taxing capital in a globalized world. Gabriel Zucman

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

Formula Apportionment, Tax Competition, and the Provision of Local Goods

Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies

ECON4620 Public Economics I First lecture by DL

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

Asymmetric tax competition in the presence of lobbying

Lecture 14. Multinational Firms. 2. Dunning's OLI, joint inputs, firm versus plant-level scale economies

Business fluctuations in an evolving network economy

The Optimal Tax on Capital is Greater than Zero. Joseph E. Stiglitz Columbia University Seminar in Memory of Anthony B. Atkinson

The World Economy from a Distance

Review. Overarching Concepts 12/1/2017 4:42 PM. OUTLINE December 4 & 6, Production Possibilities Frontier. Review of Material.

A new design for the corporate income tax?

Lecture 14 Consumption under Uncertainty Ricardian Equivalence & Social Security Dynamic General Equilibrium. Noah Williams

DISCLOSURE OF MUTUAL FUND AFTER-TAX RETURNS 1

3. The Deadweight Loss of Taxation

Capital Controls and Currency Wars

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV. If any mistakes or typos are spotted, kindly communicate them to

Transcription:

Economics 30a, Fall 018 Lecture Note 14: Tax Competition We have discussed the incentives for individual countries in designing tax policy, but an important issue is how the tax policies in one country affect the options in others, and how, in turn, this affects their tax policies. These responses fall under the heading of tax competition, although competition is not necessarily a good characterization of all governmental policy interdependencies. For example, even within a country, the decisions of governments at, say, the national level affect the incentives of subnational governments. While our discussion will often refer to the interactions of different countries, similar issues come up among governments at a subnational level, as among US states, the main differences being (1) that tax rates, and differences among them, are typically much larger in the international context than in the interstate context; and () there is a higher-level government in the case of US states, which may help the states coordinate activities. However, there are lessons from the experience of interstate competition for tax policy choices in the international context. The Handbook chapter by Keen and Konrad provides a comprehensive survey of the literature. Tax Competition: Basic Concepts and Results Perhaps the simplest model of tax competition involves two identical (and hence, large ) countries competing for capital that is internationally mobile but, in the simplest specification, fixed worldwide. Each country produces homogeneous output with capital and labor according to the CRS production function F(K,L), a representative household in each country has an endowment of capital and supplies labor to maximize a utility, and each government imposes taxes on capital (on a source basis) and labor to raise revenue for government spending, G, with the level of government spending chosen to maximize the representative household s utility, U(C,L,G), where C is private consumption. Given the nature of this set-up, we can focus our attention on possible symmetric equilibria, in which aggregates are the same in the two countries. Thinking first about global optimality, that is, maximizing the (equal) utility of the representative agents in the two countries, this would be achieved by having an equal tax rate on capital in the two countries which is nondistortionary, since capital is in fixed overall supply no taxes on labor, as these would involve deadweight loss, and government spending set so that the marginal utility of government spending equals the marginal utility of private consumption, UC = UG. However, this outcome is not a Nash equilibrium of a game in which each government chooses its own capital and labor income tax rates. This is because, from each government s perspective, capital supply is responsive to its tax rate. Thus, starting from the first-best optimum just described, either government will seek to improve national welfare by reducing the capital income tax and introducing the labor income tax, given that a small labor income tax has only second-order deadweight loss. With each government having this incentive, this process will lead to lower capital income taxes and positive labor income taxes in both countries. Also, because each country will be using distortionary taxes at the margin to raise revenue, government spending will be too low, relative to its efficient level, and the mix of government taxes will rely too much on labor and too little on capital. (In this symmetric equilibrium, production will still be efficient because tax rates are the same in the two countries.)

We thus have a race to the bottom in the choice of capital income tax rates and government spending. In terms of the mechanism at work, the capital income tax rate in each country has a positive fiscal externality in the other, because raising the capital income tax rate in one country drives capital to the other, thereby increasing tax revenue in the second country. As with standard externalities, the failure to internalize the externality leads each country to set its tax rate too low; and, as with standard externalities, welfare could be improved by implementing some sort of corrective measure to cause the externalities to be internalized. If we are dealing with national governments, though, what can fill the role of government in this case? International organizations like the OECD attempt to fill this role in developing norms for tax policy, but they lack the coercive power of governments. In the symmetric case, one might also hope that countries could achieve a cooperative solution to the game of choosing their taxes. But cooperation becomes more challenging in an asymmetric setting, because countries with different characteristics differ not only in the policies chosen in a noncooperative equilibrium but also in the extent to which they could gain from a cooperative process, particularly if that process excludes side payments among countries. In particular, if countries differ in size and capital endowments, one might expect that smaller countries would set their capital income tax rates lower. The logic, as in Keen and Konrad (pp. 73-4) is as follows: Intuitively, in considering a tax rate cut, countries must weigh the loss of revenue from their own capital against the benefits of attracting more inward investment; and for a small country, with a narrow domestic capital base and a lot of capital abroad that it might attract, the attractions of a rate cut will be greater. The above figure (from CBO, Corporate Income Tax Rates: International Comparisons, 005), which plots countries rankings of corporate tax rates against their rankings in size of gross capital formation, is quite consistent with this story. In the extreme, countries with virtually no domestic capital or production will have strong incentives to have low tax rates in order to attract the reported profits of multinationals. Such

countries are commonly called tax havens. A recent list of such countries is provided by Dharmapala and Hines (J. Pub. E. 009), who also discuss the factors determining whether countries become tax havens. While all tax havens are small, not all small economies are tax havens; a key determinant is the quality of a country s governance. The logic is that, even with low tax rates, only countries with good governance are likely to be able to attract multinational profits and the associated financial flows, as the threat of expropriation and other dangers will limit the attractiveness of countries with weak institutions. Are tax havens good or bad? On the one hand, their existence promotes the erosion of tax bases in high-tax countries. On the other hand, their existence may limit the incentives of multinationals to move real activities from the high-tax countries, as these companies can generate lower effective tax rates on such activities simply by reporting some of their profits in tax havens. Indeed, for a country with some domestic companies unlikely to move activities elsewhere, the existence of tax havens and profit-shifting opportunities for multinationals amounts to the imposition of differential tax rates on companies with low vs. high sensitivity of location with respect to tax rates, which may at least to some extent be justified from an optimal-tax perspective. This may help explain why higher-tax countries do not exert more pressure on low-tax countries. Another, more direct approach to providing a lower tax rate for more internationally mobile income comes through a mechanism recently adopted in a number of countries, sometimes referred to as a patent box, which taxes income attributable to intellectual property at a lower rate than other income. Patent boxes have also been justified by arguments that they encourage activity for which there may be positive externalities. Gaessler, Hall, and Harhoff find that such schemes lead to little change in real activity, as opposed to profit shifting. This does not necessarily make the schemes suboptimal from a national perspective (since they may attract tax revenue at the expense of other countries by causing a relocation of reported income), but it does suggest that they may not be socially desirable, in terms of encouraging productive activity. Benefits of Tax Competition? The message of the previous discussion seems to be that tax competition is bad in the sense that it increases the distortions encountered in the provision of goods and services by governments. The literature does include some models, discussed in Keen and Konrad, in which tax competition has positive attributes, either limiting the potential attraction of capital tax policies that are dynamically inconsistent (because governments have less to gain by raising capital income taxes after promising to keep them low), or by reducing the capacity of Leviathan governments, which seek a suboptimally large size, to extract too much from the private sector. Alternative Tax Reforms An alternative often proposed for existing tax systems is formula apportionment, under which a jurisdiction determines the tax base for a company operating within its jurisdiction as well as possibly several others based on the shares of that company s overall sales (S), assets (K), and/or payroll (wl) that fall within that jurisdiction. That is, if the company s worldwide profits are π, KK jurisdiction i imposes tax on a fraction of π equal to αα ii ww KK + αα ii LL ii SS jj KK PP + αα ii jj jj ww jj LL SS, where αα jj jj SS KK + jj αα PP + αα SS = 1. Formula apportionment is the standard approach used by US state corporate taxes. A main attraction of formula apportionment is that it eliminates the opportunity for companies to engage in profit shifting, as the tax base in any jurisdiction does not depend on profits reported 3

there, but only on overall profits and the apportionment factors αk, αp, and αs. On the other hand, firms will have incentives to shift the factors used in the apportionment formula, as this affects their overall tax liability. A tax based on apportionment factors has effects similar to a tax on the apportionment factors themselves. For example, if a company s tax liability in jurisdiction i depends on the share of its assets in that jurisdiction, then increasing the share of its assets in jurisdiction i will increase its tax liability in jurisdiction i. To see this, consider a simple example in which a firm produces in two jurisdictions, each of which taxes profits based on the share of the firm s assets in that jurisdiction. Then the firm s profits after tax are: FF(KK 1, LL 1 ) + FF(KK, LL ) rr(kk 1 + KK ) ww(ll 1 + LL ) KK 1 KK tt 1 + tt KK 1 + KK {FF(KK KK 1 + KK 1, LL 1 ) + FF(KK, LL ) ww(ll 1 + LL )} where we assume that production functions and after-tax capital and labor costs are the same in both jurisdictions and that wages, but not capital costs, are tax deductible. The first-order condition for capital in jurisdiction 1 is: FF KK 1 (1 TT) ππ dddd ddkk 1 = rr where TT = tt 1 KK 1 + tt KK 1 +KK KK and ππ = FF(KK KK 1 +KK 1, LL 1 ) + FF(KK, LL ) ww(ll 1 + LL ) are taxable profits. Since dddd = KK (tt ddkk 1 (KK 1 +KK ) 1 tt ), we have: KK FF 1 KK 1 TT ππ (KK 1 + KK ) (tt 1 tt ) = rr Thus, the tax wedge the firm faces in using capital in jurisdiction 1 equals the average tax rate in the two jurisdictions, T, plus a term that is increasing in the excess tax rate in jurisdiction 1, (tt 1 tt ) and the level of taxable profits, ππ. The same reasoning applies to taxes apportioned based on payroll or sales, and this helps explain the evolution of formulas used by US states. Using sales to apportion profits, rather than assets or payroll, may provide multistate companies with a stronger incentive to locate production activities within a jurisdiction. As shown in this figure, from Suárez Serrato and Zidar (AER 016), US states, which historically relied on an equally weighted formula based on assets, payroll, and sales, have steadily moved toward a greater reliance on sales in their apportionment formulas. 4

Indeed, there is some evidence (e.g., in the paper by Rauh and Giroud), that corporate location responses to state corporate tax rates are greater in cases where states rely on payroll and property apportionment than sales apportionment. Formula apportionment, though, has many drawbacks of its own. As discussed in Keen and Konrad, although formula apportionment alleviates tax competition with respect to the profit shifting, competition might even be stronger than under source-based taxation with respect to the location of productive factors. Further, particularly for the case of sales-based apportionment (for which competition for productive factors might be lessened), formula apportionment is open to tax avoidance strategies that would not be present under source-based taxation. For example, under sales-based apportionment, company A could sell its entire output to a second company, B, which is located in a tax haven, with company B then reselling the output to purchasers in high-tax countries. Because it is simply reselling company A s output, company B has minimal profits subject to tax based on sales in the high-tax countries, and company A, which may have substantial profits, pays little or no tax because its sales all occur in the tax haven. Another alternative is destination-based taxation, as proposed in Auerbach, Devereux and Simpson and described more fully in Auerbach. The approach is somewhat related to salesbased apportionment, in that the location of sales governs the location of taxation. But the mechanism for calculating tax liability is different, and not subject to avoidance schemes like the one just discussed. A jurisdiction wishing to impose a destination-based tax would start with source-based taxation and then impose border adjustments on exports and imports by multinationals. That is, if the country s corporate tax rate is t, then exports would receive a tax credit at rate t and imports would be taxed at rate t. This would have the effect of eliminating the tax consequences of exports and imports (since export revenues would otherwise be taxable, and import costs otherwise deductible). Hence, profit-shifting opportunities for multinationals based on intracompany transactions would disappear. The US seriously considered this approach in 017 before adopting a more modest change, which has more limited border adjustment elements, including a lower tax rate on certain export income and the loss of deductibility for certain imports. National and Subnational Policy Coordination One final issue is the interdependence of tax policies at different levels of government within a country. We have already discussed fiscal externalities across countries. But there are also vertical fiscal externalities in tax policy, in that tax policy at one level of government affects the tax base at other levels. Here, though, the externalities are likely to push in the opposite direction. For example, if the US federal government taxes corporate income and states do as well, increases in state corporate income tax rates are likely to reduce the national corporate tax base. By the usual logic of analyzing externalities, tax rates in this case will be too high, rather than too low, because governments at each level will ignore the negative effects of their taxes at other levels. Within a country, with positive fiscal externalities across states and negative fiscal externalities between states and the federal government, the net impact on tax rates is ambiguous, in theory. 5