Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security

Similar documents
Optimal portfolio choice with health-contingent income products: The value of life care annuities

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

Session 132 L - New Developments in Mortality Risk Pooling. Moderator: Deborah A. Tully, FSA, EA, FCA, MAAA. Presenter: Rowland Davis, FSA

The implications of mortality heterogeneity on longevity sharing retirement income products

AN ANNUITY THAT PEOPLE MIGHT ACTUALLY BUY

ANNUITIES AND INDIVIDUAL WELFARE. Thomas Davidoff* Jeffrey Brown Peter Diamond. CRR WP May 2003

Portfolio Choice in Retirement: Health Risk and the Demand for Annuities, Housing, and Risky Assets

Retirement Saving, Annuity Markets, and Lifecycle Modeling. James Poterba 10 July 2008

Annuity Decisions with Systematic Longevity Risk. Ralph Stevens

Long-term care risk, income streams and late in life savings

Annuity Markets and Retirement Security

Accounting for non-annuitization

Optimal Life Cycle Portfolio Choice with Variable Annuities Offering Liquidity and Investment Downside Protection

Understanding Longevity Risk Annuitization Decisionmaking: An Interdisciplinary Investigation of Financial and Nonfinancial Triggers of Annuity Demand

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

Review of Economic Dynamics

Choices and constraints over retirement income. streams: comparing rules and regulations *

IS ADVERSE SELECTION IN THE ANNUITY MARKET A BIG PROBLEM?

White Paper on Retirement Highlights Importance of Annuities

Is Retiree Demand for Life Annuities Rational? Evidence from Public Employees *

Retirement. Optimal Asset Allocation in Retirement: A Downside Risk Perspective. JUne W. Van Harlow, Ph.D., CFA Director of Research ABSTRACT

Nordic Journal of Political Economy

Payout-Phase of Mandatory Pension Accounts

Optimal Life Cycle Portfolio Choice with Variable Annuities Offering Liquidity and Investment Downside Protection

Financial Innovation for an Aging World. Olivia S. Mitchell, John Piggott, Michael Sherris, and Shaun Yow

Enhancing Singapore s Pension Scheme: A Blueprint for Further Flexibility

Optimal Allocation and Consumption with Guaranteed Minimum Death Benefits with Labor Income and Term Life Insurance

Jeffrey Brown and Theo Nijman. Opportunities for Improving Pension Wealth Decumulation in the Netherlands. Discussion Paper 01/

Optimal Decumulation of Assets in General Equilibrium. James Feigenbaum (Utah State)

Evaluating Lump Sum Incentives for Delayed Social Security Claiming*

Framing, Reference Points, and Preferences for Life Annuities

Why the deferred annuity makes sense

Adverse Selection in the Annuity Market and the Role for Social Security

Article from. ARCH Proceedings

A Better Systematic Withdrawal Strategy--The Actuarial Approach Ken Steiner, Fellow, Society of Actuaries, Retired February 2014

Health Cost Risk, Incomplete Markets, or Bequest Motives - Revisiting the Annuity Puzzle

Why Advisors Should Use Deferred-Income Annuities

The Effect of Uncertain Labor Income and Social Security on Life-cycle Portfolios

Retirement, Saving, Benefit Claiming and Solvency Under A Partial System of Voluntary Personal Accounts

Will Bequests Attenuate the Predicted Meltdown in Stock Prices When Baby Boomers Retire?

A Conceptual Framework For Retirement Products: Risk Sharing Arrangements Between Providers And Retirees

The Role of the Annuity s Value on the Decision (Not) to Annuitize: Evidence from a Large Policy Change

Accounting for non-annuitization

About PrARI. Background

LIFETIME FINANCIAL ADVICE: HUMAN CAPITAL, ASSET ALLOCATION, AND INSURANCE

Longevity Risk Mitigation in Pension Design To Share or to Transfer

Optimal portfolio choice with health-contingent income products: The value of life care annuities

Evaluating Post-Retirement Investment Strategies. Shaun Levitan and Youri Dolya

Optimal Annuitization with Stochastic Mortality and Correlated Medical Costs

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

Assessing the Impact of Mortality Assumptions on Annuity Valuation: Cross-Country Evidence

Optimal Annuitization with Stochastic Mortality Probabilities

Annuity Puzzle is a Reasonable Choice: Evidence from Korean Annuity Market

Saving During Retirement

Methods of pooling longevity risk

ALLOCATION DURING RETIREMENT: ADDING ANNUITIES TO THE MIX

MAKING YOUR NEST EGG LAST A LIFETIME

DISCUSSION PAPER PI-1014

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Introduction to "Pensions in the U.S. Economy"

Options for Moving in Retirement Using the HECM for Purchase

Have the Australians got it right? Converting Retirement Savings to Retirement Benefits: Lessons from Australia

And All the days of Methuselah were nine hundred sixty and nine years: and he died (Genesis 5:27).

Index. Index. More information. in this web service Cambridge University Press. actively managed funds, 197, 200

Revisiting the Risk-Neutral Approach to Optimal Policyholder Behavior: A Study of Withdrawal Guarantees in Variable Annuities 1

Target-Date Funds, Annuitization and Retirement Investing

Analytical Problem Set

A Proper Derivation of the 7 Most Important Equations for Your Retirement

In physics and engineering education, Fermi problems

Topic 3: Policy Design: Social Security

Asset Location and Allocation with. Multiple Risky Assets

What do you want? Managing risks for better outcomes when you retire

You do not have to sign in and out for InFRE credits InFRE tracking forms were included in conference registration materials.

Non-qualified Annuities in After-tax Optimizations

Do Required Minimum Distributions Matter? The Effect of the 2009 Holiday on Retirement Plan Distributions

What is it that makes the Swiss annuitize? A description of the Swiss retirement system. Benjamin Avanzi Australian School of UNSW

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

What are the additional assumptions that must be satisfied for Rabin s theorem to hold?

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Design considerations for retirement savings and retirement income products Received (in revised form): 14 th October 2010

Mortality Risk, Insurance, and the Value of Life *

The Demand for Annuities with Stochastic Mortality Probabilities

The Role of Annuities in Retirement Plans

Optimal Withdrawal Strategy for Retirement Income Portfolios

ADVERSE SELECTION IN INSURANCE MARKETS: POLICYHOLDER EVIDENCE FROM THE U.K. ANNUITY MARKET

Saving and investing over the life cycle and the role of collective pension funds Bovenberg, Lans; Koijen, R.S.J.; Nijman, Theo; Teulings, C.N.

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

The current US Social Security system provides retirees with a real annuity during their

w w w. I C A o r g

The Handbook of Variable Income Annuities

The ratio of consumption to income, called the average propensity to consume, falls as income rises

Maturity, Indebtedness and Default Risk 1

Stochastic Analysis Of Long Term Multiple-Decrement Contracts

Annuity Markets and Capital Accumulation

Retirement Income Source Diversification

DO REQUIRED MINIMUM DISTRIBUTIONS MATTER? THE EFFECT OF THE 2009 HOLIDAY ON RETIREMENT PLAN DISTRIBUTIONS

Using Fixed SPIAs and Investments to Create an Inflation-Adjusted Income Stream

Housing, Health, and Annuities

Issue Number 60 August A publication of the TIAA-CREF Institute

Characterization of the Optimum

Transcription:

Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security March 2017

2 Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security AUTHOR Daniel Bauer Georgia State University SPONSOR Pension Section Research Committee Caveat and Disclaimer The opinions expressed and conclusions reached by the authors are their own and do not represent any official position or opinion of the Society of Actuaries or its members. The Society of Actuaries makes no representation or warranty to the accuracy of the information Copyright 2017 by the Georgia State University Research Foundation, Inc. All rights reserved.

3 Longevity Risk Pooling Opportunities to Increase Retirement Security * Overview of Current Findings A long-standing result in pension economics suggests that individuals should optimally invest a significant portion of their nest egg in pooled retirement accounts such as life annuities or defined benefit pension schemes. In fact, calculations by the author that use a simple version of the standard life-cycle utility framework demonstrate that equivalent retirement security can be provided with 15 25% fewer savings when there is access to investing in a pooled life annuity, depending on an individual s wealth level and risk preferences. However, with the shift toward lump-sum payments of retirement benefits in recent decades, the amount of assets in pooled vehicles has been decreasing significantly. Although several papers attempt to rationalize this trend, this article argues that they do not provide satisfactory evidence that existing asset allocations are optimal from the policyholders or policymakers vantage points. This article concludes that there may be opportunities in regulation, financial advice and product design to increase the financial efficiency of delivering retirement security. Prior Research In his seminal paper, Yaari (1965) addresses the question of how a risk-averse investor should optimally allocate funds considering the uncertainty of lifespans. Yaari shows that investors without bequest motives should optimally completely annuitize their savings, a result that provides the basis for the academic analysis of retirement portfolio allocation. Although Yaari s assumptions are somewhat restrictive, Davidoff et al. (2005) show that this full annuitization result persists under substantially weaker conditions. These conditions stipulate that consumers have no bequest motives and that annuities pay a rate to surviving investors that exceeds the return of conventional assets of matching financial risk. They demonstrate that pooled retirement investments are then dominant assets in comparison to other fixed or variable investments, implying that investors should prefer them under all circumstances. In other words, since survivors earn an extra return financed by the funds of individuals that die under a pooled annuity investment (commonly called a mortality credit), individuals should prefer pooling their longevity risk. And even with a bequest motive, that is, when individuals want to leave a fraction of their wealth to their heirs, investors should at least annuitize (pool) partially. The simplicity of this argument immediately settles the most obvious objections against investing in annuities. For instance, various authors have shown that life annuities contain a substantial loading. Mitchell et al. (1999) show that life annuities, on average, deliver payouts of less than 91 cents per dollar of annuity premium, where the actuarially fair price of an annuity is defined to be the expected discounted present value using current yields of treasury and corporate bonds as well as appropriately adjusted cohort mortality tables. They posit this difference is due to expenses, profit margins and contingency funds. In a similar study, Finkelstein and Poterba (2002) emphasize that a large portion of this difference can be attributed to adverse selection. However, irrespective of the reason for * The author is grateful to the Society of Actuaries for its sponsorship and thankfully acknowledges the members of the Project Oversight Group (POG) for their expertise, time and assistance with this project. The POG members included Evan Inglis (chair), Rowland Davis, John Deinum, Edson Edwards, Moshe Milevsky, Andy Peterson, Lisa Schilling and Steve Siegel.

4 this spread, following the logic of Davidoff et al., individuals should still prefer investing in a pool as long as the yield differential relative to nonpooled investments is positive. From a market perspective, this investment prescription does not align with observations of consumer behavior in the United States, where the fraction of individuals converting their nest egg into a life annuity remains small. 1 For instance, a 2015 TIAA-CREF survey reports that only 14% of respondents purchased an annuity. 2 Different studies have presented different arguments to reconcile theoretical prescriptions with observed behavior, but these studies do not annul the basic logic for pooled investments. Aside from behavioral aspects, it appears that there may be other causes for the limited investment in pooled solutions, including the regulation of retirement investments (e.g., which assets are permissible in certain retirement accounts), potential biases among financial advisers and shortcomings in the product landscape. Measuring the Impact of Pooling Analyses by Mitchell et al. (1999) and subsequent literature evaluate the money s worth of a retirement asset by comparing the expected payout and its price. However, this metric ignores that the payout is contingent on risky outcomes, and a comparison should take into account how desirable an asset s pattern of cash flows is relative to its price. In particular, from a retiree s vantage point or that of an organization interested in the retiree s well-being payments in situations where the retiree survives will be more valuable than in situations where the retiree is dead. The conventional approach in economics is thus to evaluate the utility of aggregate consumption in so-called lifecycle utility models. More precisely, the approach considers an individual s decision problem of how to optimally spend ( consume ) savings subject to a budget constraint, which in turn may include other choice variables (e.g., investments). One can then compare different retirement/investment schemes by evaluating total welfare or willingness to pay (e.g., Bovenberg et al. 2007; Koijen et al. 2016). Such models favor pooled investments, such as in the form of a basic life annuity; this is the formal version of Yaari s basic result. For instance, in a very basic life-cycle utility model with solely a fixed investment opportunity, assuming a risk-free rate of 3%, for a 65-year old risk-averse female (constant relative risk aversion coefficient of 1.5) with wealth level of $500,000, the individual would be willing to give up roughly 20% of her wealth to gain access to an annuity investment (see the Appendix for details on the calculations). This implies the individual would be able to produce the same retirement security as measured by aggregate utility for 20% less of the nest egg or $400,000 rather than $500,000 when taking advantage of pooling the individual s longevity risk. This number is highly sensitive to underlying assumptions, including the individual s wealth level, preference specification (utility function), risk aversion parameter, existing investment opportunities and bequest motive, and corresponding assumptions in the academic literature vary vastly. However, as indicated above, the qualitative result prevails even when considering a variety of modifications and generalizations of the framework. 1 Friedman and Warshawsky (1990) seem to be the first to mention this annuity puzzle that individuals behavior deviates from the economic prescription. 2 See www.tiaa.org/public/pdf/c21731_2015_lifetime_income_survey-executive_summary.pdf.

5 So Why Don t People Annuitize? Several authors have contemplated alternative (rational) reasons for the lack of investment in annuities and other retirement solutions that pool mortality risk. Schulze and Post (2006) investigate the implications of aggregate demographic risk that is, the possibility that average life expectancy may decrease or increase on individuals annuitization decisions. They show that there won t be any influence if demographic risk is assumed to be independent of other risks affecting the individual s income, although the situation changes if dependencies are taken into account. Correlations between aggregate demographic risk and an individual s income may originate, for example, from a retirement plan s ruin probability or government pensions depending on aggregate life expectancy or if investment returns of existing risky assets depend on the demographic state of nature. 3 And the result can go in either direction, increasing or decreasing the demand for the pooled investment vehicle. However, although both these described effects as well as loadings for demographic risk may affect the demand for pooled retirement solutions, these aspects may be alleviated in investment schemes that shift the aggregate portion of the risk to the pool while preserving the basic benefit of pooling. More precisely, such schemes allow for the payments to the individuals to depend on the aggregate realized life expectancies in the pool, while still providing the benefit of mortality credits. This may take the form of flexible bonus arrangements for the insurer (Norberg 1999), annuity payments depending on aggregate risk (Wadsworth et al. 2001) or specific risk sharing arrangements such as self-annuitization plans (Piggott et al. 2005) or modern versions of tontine schemes (Milevsky and Salisbury 2015). Reichling and Smetters (2015), on the other hand, argue that in a model with health shocks, correlated medical costs will decrease the demand for annuities. More precisely, they argue that health shocks will decrease the present value of the annuity investment but will lead to additional costs; this implies that many households should not be invested in annuities. However, their study takes the positive correlation between health shocks and medical spending as given. As shown in Bauer et al. (2017), health care expenses given a medical shock will be larger in the absence of pooled investments. In other words, the large correlation between health shocks and medical spending may be a consequence of the limited participation in pooled solutions, rather than the other way around. Furthermore, again product innovations can alleviate this issue. For instance, several annuity products in the North American as well as in the European market now provide differentiated benefits in different health states, such as increased benefits in the case of long-term care status. This will counteract the potential adverse correlation properties of a fixed lifelong annuity with health expenses as described in Reichling and Smetters (2015), allowing individuals to enjoy the benefits of pooling. Hence, the health shocks argument, to the extent it is valid, only pertains to investment in a very particular pooled retirement asset. Conclusion All these aspects echo the basic argument in Davidoff et al. (2005) that the rational demand for annuities or retirement assets that pool longevity risk in general is subject to market incompleteness. The extent to which individuals can generate their desired consumption in consideration of uncertainty in their future is dependent on the availability of solutions in the market. Investments that provide differentiated payoffs across states, for example, payoffs that depend on the realized aggregate life expectancy in the pool as within self-annuitization plans or 3 See, e.g., Abel (2001) and references therein for possible interactions of demographic and economic trends.

6 payoffs that depend on different health states such as life annuities with enhanced benefits under long-term care, will allow individuals to take advantage of the indisputable advantages of pooling longevity risk. This calls for the industry to respond with product innovations that address the downsides of existing solutions while preserving the benefits of pooling. Economic researchers can help by identifying the most important risk dimensions. It calls for enabling financial advisers to better communicate the advantages of pooled retirement solutions in light of behavioral biases that work against advantageous individual choices. And it calls for pension and insurance regulators to provide access to a variety of solutions within retirement accounts so that individuals have the possibility to best structure their portfolio, taking advantage of demographic risk pooling.

7 References Abel, A. B. 2001. Will Bequests Attenuate the Predicted Meltdown in Stock Prices When Baby Boomers Retire. Review of Economics and Statistics 83: 589 595. Bauer, D., D. Lakdawalla, and J. Reif. 2017. Mortality Risk, Insurance, and the Value of Life. Working Paper. Georgia State University, University of Southern-California, and University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. Bovenberg, L., R. Koijen, T. Nijman, and C. Teulings. 2007. Saving and Investing over the Life Cycle and the Role of Collective Pension Funds. De Economist 155: 347 415. Davidoff, T., J. R. Brown, and P.A. Diamond. 2005. Annuities and Individual Welfare. American Economic Review 95: 1573 1590. Finkelstein, A., and J. Poterba. 2002. Selection Effects in the Market for Individual Annuities: New Evidence from the United Kingdom. Economic Journal 112: 28 50. Friedman, B., and M. Warshawsky. 1990. The Cost of Annuities: Implications for Saving Behaviour and Bequests. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105: 135 154. Koijen R. S. J., S. Nieuwerburgh, and M. Yogo. 2016. Health and Mortality Delta: Assessing the Welfare Cost of Household Insurance Choice. Journal of Finance 71: 957 1010. Milevsky, M. A., and T. S. Salisbury. 2015. Optimal Retirement Income Tontines. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 64: 91 105. Mitchell, O. S., J. M. Poterba, M. J. Warshawsky, and J. R. Brown. 1999. New Evidence on the Money s Worth of Individual Annuities. American Economic Review 89: 1299 1318. Norberg, R. 1999. A Theory of Bonus in Life Insurance. Finance and Stochastics 3: 373 390. Piggott, J., E. A. Valdez, and B. Detzel. 2005. The Simple Analytics of a Pooled Annuity Fund. Journal of Risk and Insurance 72: 497 520. Reichling, F., and K. Smetters. 2015. Optimal Annuitization with Stochastic Mortality and Correlated Medical Costs. American Economic Review 105: 3273 3320. Schulze, R. N., and T. Post. 2010. Individual Annuity Demand under Aggregate Mortality Risk. Journal of Risk and Insurance 77: 423 449. Wadsworth, M., A. Findlater, and T. Boardman. 2001. Reinventing Annuities. Working Paper, Staple Inn Actuarial Society. Yaari, M. E. 1965. Uncertain Lifetime, Life Insurance, and the Theory of the Consumer. Review of Economic Studies 32: 137 150.

8 Appendix The financial impact of longevity pooling presented in the text is calculated using a life-cycle utility model that is commonly used in economic analysis. A very basic version of the life cycle model takes the form K max ct E [ e ρt u(c t ) t=0 ] s. t. w t+1 = (w t c t ) e r. The model represents the idea that utility (a person s welfare or satisfaction) can be maximized by some pattern of consumption during one s remaining lifetime. Consumption at time t is denoted by c t, and w t is the wealth at time t. The term e ρt represents the basic concept that the individual prefers consumption now relative to later according to a personal discount factor ρ. The utility function, u(c t ), is concave (as is typical), which means that each additional unit of consumption increases utility less than the last additional unit. The equation w t+1 = (w t c t ) e r represents that consumption decreases wealth, and that wealth is compounded K at an interest rate r from one period to the next. E[ x t=0 e ρt u(c t ) ] represents the expected value of the discounted utility amounts that an individual will experience during the remainder of his or her life (until the year of death K). The optimal consumption pattern is determined by maximizing the expected present value of utility subject to the individual s budget constraint. The model is only a simplified representation of the real world and excludes many aspects of retirement savings. For instance, one could include risky investments, or income from other sources, which would impact the results but would not negate the basic insight from the economic literature that pooling longevity risk increases utility. The model used for this article also excludes value that individuals might place on a bequest. To determine the benefit of pooling, the fraction of wealth x that an individual is willing to give up for access to a (pooled) single-premium immediate life annuity is calculated. For simplicity, and as is common in the economic literature, we assume r = ρ. For the utility function, as is also common in the literature, we use a so-called power or constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function: u(c) = c1 γ, with a (relative) risk aversion parameter γ. Then, if we use parameter values in line with other studies, 4 for a 65-year-old female with an initial wealth of $500,000, we obtain the following fractions x: 1 γ r = ρ = 3% γ = 0. 5 γ = 1 γ = 1. 5 γ = 2 x 13% 17% 20% 22% r = ρ = 1. 5% γ = 0. 5 γ = 1 γ = 1. 5 γ = 2 x 15% 21% 24% 27% 4 All calculations are based on the models in Bauer et al. (2017). In particular, the underlying mortality probabilities are based on the Future Elderly Model compiled by the USC Schaeffer Center. (This model was supported by the National Institute on Aging of the National Institutes of Health under Award Number P30AG024968. The content is solely the responsibility of the author and does not necessarily represent the official views of the National Institutes of Health.)