International Trade and Income Differences

Similar documents
Capital Goods Trade and Economic Development

International Trade and Income Differences

International Trade Gravity Model

Eaton and Kortum, Econometrica 2002

Chapter 3: Predicting the Effects of NAFTA: Now We Can Do It Better!

International Development and Firm Distribution

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

Gravity, Trade Integration and Heterogeneity across Industries

Technology, Geography and Trade J. Eaton and S. Kortum. Topics in international Trade

Structural Change in Investment and Consumption: A Unified Approach

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Trade, Domestic Frictions, and Scale Effects

International Trade: Lecture 4

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Welfare Consequences of Globalization

Using a thought experiment to explore models of relative prices and trade balance:

Regional unemployment and welfare effects of the EU transport policies:

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

The Composition of Exports and Gravity

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

International Trade, Technology Diffusion, and the Role of Diffusion Barriers

The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and Evidence from U.S. Firms by Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort and Felix Tintelnot

Quality, Variable Mark-Ups, and Welfare: A Quantitative General Equilibrium Analysis of Export Prices

Trade, Domestic Frictions, and Scale Effects

Structural Change within the Service Sector and the Future of Baumol s Disease

Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Capital Accumulation and Dynamic Gains from Trade

Non-Homotheticity and Bilateral Trade: Evidence and a Quantitative Explanation

Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle

Gravity Redux: Structural Estimation of Gravity Equations with Asymmetric Bilateral Trade Costs

Offshore Financial Centers: Parasites or Symbionts? Andrew K. Rose and Mark M. Spiegel

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Proximity vs Comparative Advantage: A Quantitative Theory of Trade and Multinational Production

GAINS FROM TRADE IN NEW TRADE MODELS

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

Testing the predictions of the Solow model: What do the data say?

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Conference Presentation

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

Diversi cation through Trade

Working Paper Series. Capital Accumulation and Dynamic Gains from Trade. B. Ravikumar Ana Maria Santacreu and Michael Sposi

Capital Accumulation and Dynamic Gains from Trade

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

International Trade Lecture 1: Trade Facts and the Gravity Equation

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Working Paper Series. Capital Goods Trade, Relative Prices, and Economic Development. Piyusha Mutreja B. Ravikumar and Michael Sposi

The Effects of Common Currencies on Trade

Is Informality a Barrier to Convergence?

International Economics: Lecture 10 & 11

The Composition of Knowledge and Long-Run Growth

Testing the predictions of the Solow model:

Size, Geography, and Multinational Production

Research at Intersection of Trade and IO. Interest in heterogeneous impact of trade policy (some firms win, others lose, perhaps in same industry)

Structural Change and the Skill Premium in a Global Economy

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Indexing and Price Informativeness

Industrial characteristics, the size of countries, and the extensive margin of trade

Lecture 3: Quantifying the Role of Credit Markets in Economic Development

Trade and long term unemployment: aquantitativeassessment

Theory Appendix for: Buyer-Seller Relationships in International Trade: Evidence from U.S. State Exports and Business-Class Travel

External Rebalancing, Structural Adjustment, and Real Exchange Rates in Developing Asia

Structural Change and Global Trade

Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization

A Knowledge-and-Physical-Capital Model of International Trade, Foreign Direct Investment, and Multinational Enterprises: Developed Countries

Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences with Public Capital

Trade in intermediate goods and the division of labour

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

Introduction Intuitive Gravity Structural Gravity Discrete Choice Gravity. The Gravity Model. James E. Anderson. Boston College and NBER.

Technology, Ecology and Agricultural Trade

Gains from Trade 1-3

Sovereign default and debt renegotiation

Dornbusch, Fischer, Samuelson (1977): 160 years of international economics in one paper

Structural Change and Global Trade

Switching Monies: The Effect of the Euro on Trade between Belgium and Luxembourg* Volker Nitsch. ETH Zürich and Freie Universität Berlin

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

From imitation to innovation: Where is all that Chinese R&D going?

Sectoral Volatility, Trade Partners, and Development

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Trade Liberalization and Labor Market Dynamics

Information Globalization, Risk Sharing and International Trade

NOT FOR PUBLICATION. Theory Appendix for The China Syndrome. Small Open Economy Model

How Much of South Korea s Growth Miracle Can be Explained by Trade Policy?

Determinants of Structural Change

Foreign Direct Investment I

International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Trade and Synchronization in a Multi-Country Economy

Tax Cuts for Whom? Heterogeneous Effects of Income Tax Changes on Growth & Employment

International Banks and the Cross-Border Transmission of Business Cycles 1

Income Differences and Input-Output Structure

"Gains from Intra-Firm Trade and Multinational Production"

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Data Development for Regional Policy Analysis

Real Exchange Rates and Primary Commodity Prices

Conditional Convergence Revisited: Taking Solow Very Seriously

Credit constraints, inequality and the growth gains from trade

Inattentive Importers

International Trade: Lecture 3

Geography and Path Dependence

Transcription:

International Trade and Income Differences By Michael E. Waugh AER (Dec. 2010)

Content 1. Motivation 2. The theoretical model 3. Estimation strategy and data 4. Results 5. Counterfactual simulations 6. Conclusions

1. Motivation Many empirical studies showed that transport costs for exporters are assymetric between rich and poor countries Olarreaga, Nicita and Kee (2006); Moreira, Volpe and Blyde (2008); Krueger, Schiff and Valdes (1988); IMF data on f.o.b. and c.i.f. prices Many theoretical models and empirical studies still assume symmetry in trade costs Waugh s argument is based on the theoretical gravity equation and 3 observations on trade shares and aggregate price data of tradables across countries

1. Home bias for both rich and poor countries 2. Systematic correlation between bilateral trade shares and relative level of development 3. Aggregate tradable goods prices are similar between rich and poor countries

To reconcile bilateral trade volumes and price data within a standard gravity model transport costs must be assymetric between rich and poor countries: Assuming assymetric trade costs gives much better fit for bilateral trade volumes (R 2 is 36% higher) Waugh argues that assymetries in trade costs arrise because of exporter effects rather than importer effects Assymetry in trade costs are an important reason for differences in TFP and income per worker between countries (counterfactual analysis)

2. The theoretical model Close to Eaton and Kortum (2002) and Alvarez and Lucas (2007) 2 production sectors (non-tradable final good y, continuum of differentiated tradable goods x ϵ [0,1] ) Perfect competition in both sectors N countries endowed with labor L i and capital K i, exogenous technology parameter λ i determines distribution of productivity z i (x) -θ for tradable goods Production factors: capital, labor and aggregate tradable goods q i All variables are normalized by L i

Nested Cobb-Douglas production function for tradables Aggregate tradable good, m(x) is purchased from lowest cost producer across all countries (like in EK, 2002) z i (x) is independently and exponentially distributed with parameter λ i, so z i (x) -θ follows Fréchet-distribution

Therefore interpretation of θ is now opposite of EK (2002), λ i is same as T i in EK (2002) Iceberg transport costs for trade in tradable goods τ ij allowed to be assymetric (τ ij composed of both policy and non-policy related barriers) Balanced trade (value of total imports = value of total exports, only tradable goods are traded) Consumer utility only depends on the final good Production function for the final good:

Competitive equilibrium Cobb-Douglas production technologies: fraction γ of labor and capital (aggregate value added) and fraction β of aggregate tradable good is allocated towards the final goods sector Rest of equilibrium equations follow from same reasoning than EK (2002) (probabilistic computations) Only 3 equations determine the equilibrium Aggregate price index of tradables in country i (1)

Country i s expenditure share on tradables from country j (equals fraction of tradable goods that i imports from j): (2) equilibrium wage rate for each country i: (3)

from (1) and (2) we get: (4) dividing (4) by opposing expression: (5) Observations 1-3 and (5) imply, that exporting costs for poor countries are higher than for rich ones

3. Estimation strategy and data Objective: Structural estimation of assymetric trade costs and technology parameters using cross-sectional data on bilateral trade volumes and a specific functional form for trade costs Benchmark year is 1996, 77 countries in the sample (represent over 90% of world GDP) Tradable goods sector corresponds to manufactures, aggregation across all 34 BEA manufacturing industries Trade shares are computed in the following way:

Trade and production data for manufactures from Feenstra et al. (1997), UNIDO, OECD and World Bank Aggregate price indices for manufactures (tradables) are constructed from UN-ICP and PWT data (1996) Disaggregated price data for estimation of θ comes from PWT (1985) Distance data comes from CEPII Dividing X ij by X ii (from (2)): (6) Where S i is defined as:

Due to assymetry of trade costs restrictions on parameter space are necessary (restrictions on trade costs: exporter fixed effects vs. importer fixed effects) Benchmark estimation with exporter fixed effects (ex j ): (7) d k is distance as a categorial variable, b ij is the border dummy and ε ij are assumed to be orthogonal to the regressors Alternative approach with importer fixed effects (m i ): (8)

Estimating (6) using (7) or (8) by OLS leads to estimates for S i and by specifying a certain θ also for τ ij Then we can recover p i from (1): Using the definition of S i and the estimates for p i and S i, we can compute the convolution of Using (3), data on labor endowments and trade shares gives wages, which together with data on capital-labor ratios determine rental rates and finally we get each countries λ i

Estimating θ Using disaggregated price data (PWT 1985) to get another estimate for τ ij (same as EK (2002)) Using these estimates for τ ij, data on aggregate price indices and bilateral trade volumes (for 1985), we get an estimate for θ by estimating (4) Benchmark estimate across all countries is 0.18 (or 1/θ = 5.5) assumption: θ is time invariant Robustness check shows, that θ is slightly higher for poor countries!

Calibration of the model For counterfactual simulations we need to compute equilibrium prices and calibrate parameter values Data on labor endowments and capital labor ratios from Caselli (2005) are used to compute equilibrium prices Parameter α is set to 0.33 (capital share of total income, consistent with income accounting literature) Parameter β (share of value added in gross manufacturing production) is calculated using data from UNIDO (1996) (β=0.33) Parameter γ (share of value added in non tradable goods production) is set to 0.75

4. Results R 2 is 0.83 with exporter or importer fixed effects (only 0.61 without assymetric trade costs, which is same as standard approaches)

Exporter fixed effects (expressed as % change on trade costs) decrease with income per worker (poor countries have higher costs of exporting!)

In order to discriminate between exporter and importer fixed effects model, look at estimated S i plotted against income per worker

Note: In the model S i is a monotonically decreasing function of the unit cost of a producer with the average productivity level λ i in country i Differences in domestic unit costs between countries map into differences in aggregate price indices of tradables and income differences

Discriminate between exporter/importer fixed effects model: 1. Compute price indices predicted by the model and compare them with real aggregate price indices of tradables 2. Compute income per worker predicted by the model and compare with data on GDP per worker

Summary Both approaches of modeling assymetric trade costs predict bilateral trade volumes equally well and lead to same estimates for determinants of trade costs (distance, border dummy) But exporter fixed effects model fits real data on aggregate price indices and real income per worker much better Importer fixed effects model predicts higher aggregate price indices for poor countries and therefore overestimates the variance of real income per worker across countries Waugh (2010) finds that bilateral trade costs are assymetric, poor countries face higher costs of exporting than rich countries (costs of importing do not correlate with level of development)

5. Counterfactual simulations Using the calibrated model, change trade costs exogenously (comparative statics) Eliminating assymetry (τ ij = min(τ ij, τ ji )) reduces income differences by 59% relative to complete elimination of trade costs Introducing average trade costs of OECD countries reduces income differences by only 41%

Mechanism behind reductions in income differences (y i is real GDP per worker): TFP is decomposed into an endogenous trade factor and an exogenous domestic factor Lower trade costs lead to more specialization and imports from lower cost producers (X ii <1), which raises TFP and GDP per worker Elimination of assymetric trade costs leads to decrease in variance of GDP per worker, because X ii decreases more for poor countries than for rich ones Therefore observation 1 (X ii is same across level of development) is only due to assymetric trade costs!

6. Conclusions Waugh (2010) finds that trade costs are assymetric across levels of development (poor countries face higher costs of exporting than rich countries) These assymetric trade costs explain an important part of the differences in TFP and income per worker across countries Waughs argument for exporter fixed effects relies on the observation that aggregate price indices for tradables do not vary systematically across levels of development (robustness check supports his view) Furthermore, there are other empirical studies on costs of exporting that support Waughs findings