Market Price Support in Large Developing Countries

Similar documents
Public Stockholding for Food Security Purposes

The WTO Dispute on China s Agricultural Supports

Course on WTO Law and Jurisprudence Part I: Basic WTO Legal Principles

Public Stockholding for Food Security Options for Small Developing Countries and LDCs Towards a Permanent Solution at MC11

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

INFORMATION NOTE, MAY

WTO disciplines on Domestic support. Belgorod, Russian Federation 20 November 2013

Detailed Presentation of Domestic Support

( ) Page: 1/12 WTO NEGOTIATIONS ON AGRICULTURE COMMUNICATION FROM THE CO-SPONSORS OF THE SECTORAL INITIATIVE IN FAVOUR OF COTTON 1

Abstract. Key Words: WTO, Public Stockholdings, Subsidy, India. JEL classification: F13, F53, F55, Q17. Author s

E15 The Initiative. Looking for a Permanent Solution on Public Stockholding Programmes at the WTO: Getting the Right Metrics on the Support Provided

The Denunciation of the Sugar Protocol

The current basis for multilateral negotiations of global agricultural trade is

Dumping: the Beginning of the End?

Prospects for Canadian Agriculture in the WTO Doha Round A Message to the Canadian Delegation A SPECIAL REPORT. Larry Martin and David Coney

WTO s MC10: Agriculture Negotiations Public Stockholding

Aligning U.S. Farm Policy With World Trade Commitments Farm income support and trade programs

US WTO Complaint on China s Agricultural Domestic Support: Preliminary Observations* Lars Brink and David Orden December 10, 2016

5. Stabilization Policies and the WTO

Agriculture Subsidies and Trade. US$ Billion

WTO Agreement on Agriculture. Bishkek, 26 May 2015

COMMENT ON THE EC-US JOINT PAPER ON AGRICULTURE IN WTO. By Martin Khor, Third World Network 14 August 2003

Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress

RE: WTO Agriculture: Revised Blueprint of Final Deal

The need to correct WTO rules on public stocks 1

U.S. Farm Policy and the World Trade Organization: How Do They Match Up?

ICTSD. Cotton: What could a Doha deal mean for trade? 1. Introduction. 2. Cotton: a pivotal trade conflict

Economic and Social Council

Draft Cancun Ministerial Text

MULTILATERAL TRADE NEGOTIATIONS THE URUGUAY ROUND

Food price stabilization: Concepts and exercises

WTO Appellate Body rules against USA in the Cotton Dispute Case. Parthapratim Pal

( ) Page: 1/5. Revision DRAFT. Nairobi Ministerial Declaration PART I

The Potential Budgetary Costs and WTO Implications of the New Farm Bill. Joseph Glauber and Pat Westhoff

US WTO Agricultural Subsidy Notification

WTO S TRADE LIBERALIZATION: IMPLICATIONS FOR PAKISTAN WHEAT ECONOMY

The Economic Effects of State Trading Enterprises: Market Access and Market Failure

EXECUTIVE COMMITTEE OF THE HIGH COMMISSIONER S PROGRAMME. EC/60/SC/CRP.16 9 June 2009

Agreement on Agriculture: Three pillars

Event 1. Module 3. Key Elements of IIAs and their impact on domestic reform Session Two: The rules of the game on investment incentives

Contribution from the World Bank to the G20 Commodity Markets Sub Working Group. Market-Based Approaches to Managing Commodity Price Risk.

Anti-dumping and Subsidy Issues in Agricultural Trade. Presentation by G. Tereposky Thomas & Partners CATPRN Workshop 6 March 2005

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

( ) Page: 1/10 TARIFF IMPLEMENTATION ISSUES COMMUNICATION FROM THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA

The G20 Action Plan Agricultural Market Information System (AMIS)

Central and Eastern Europe: Overview of EU Enlargement and Its Impact on Primary Commodity Markets

Notifications on WTO domestic support in agriculture: how to review?

Country Update. The WTO Nairobi Package: What are Stakeholders Takes? Introduction. Main issues deliberated upon. Tanzania.

An Overview Assessment of the Revised Draft WTO Modalities for Agriculture

WTO Commitments and Support to Agriculture: Experience from Canada

Law. International Trade Law The Agreement on Agriculture

The United States WTO Complaint on China s Agricultural Domestic Support: Preliminary Observations*

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

( ) Page: 1/9 SUBMISSION OF BANGLADESH ON BEHALF OF THE LDC GROUP

A TAX INCENTIVE FOR CERTIFIED SEED: A BROADER ASSESSMENT

Loan Deficiency Payments versus Countercyclical Payments: Do We Need Both for a Price Safety Net?

Protectionism. The term free-trade describes the process of lowering protectionist barriers and thereby realizing those gains from trade.

L 346/12 Official Journal of the European Union

GLOSSARY OF DEFINITIONS FOR USE WITH THE ECA S ANNUAL REPORT

( ) Page: 1/28 ACCESSION OF KAZAKHSTAN DOMESTIC SUPPORT AND EXPORT SUBSIDIES IN THE AGRICULTURAL SECTOR. Revision

Workshop on Agriculture Notifications Geneva, September 2009 Domestic support

Glossary. Average household savings ratio Proportion of disposable household income devoted to savings.

Globalization. University of California San Diego (UCSD) Catherine Laffineur.

Market Access and the Reform of State Trading Enterprises

AGREEMENT ON AGRICULTURE

Perspectives on U.S. Agricultural Trade Policy

THE WTO AGREEMENTS AGRICULTURE

China s Price Support for Wheat, Rice and Corn under Dispute at the WTO: Compliance and Economic Issues. David Orden and Lars Brink May 21, 2018

A NEW STRATEGIC COURSE FOR THE CAP

REPORT 2014/024 INTERNAL AUDIT DIVISION

A. Context, Subsidiarity Check and Objectives

Will Martin and Aaditya Mattoo* 8 November 2011 *This presentation reflects the views of the authors only and not necessarily those of the World Bank.

2014 Farm Bill Provisions and WTO Compliance

Accession to the WTO. Eurasian Economic Union members

Economic Partnership Agreements and EU agricultural trade Alan Matthews Trinity College Dublin

Perils & Risks in Canadian Aquaculture: A Review of Scenarios for Risk Management Programming. D. Stechey, M. Doyon, J. Nolet & E.

Declaration of the Least Developed Countries Ministerial Meeting at UNCTAD XIII

Trade and Development Studies Centre (TRADES)

Appendix 1. Regulatory Impact Statement Retentions in construction contracts. Agency Disclosure Statement

Classifying Barriers to Trade. Abhijit Das Professor and Head Centre for WTO Studies

DOHA MINISTERIAL DECLARATION [excerpts]

TENTH GNLU INTERNATIONAL MOOT COURT COMPETITION 2018 IN THE WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION PANEL

Why and What S & D Treatment for LDCs in the WTO?

Agreement on Trade in Services (TISA) Tuesday, 2 December 2014 Geneva. Round: 1-5 December 2014

COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS OF RELEVANT WTO SAFEGUARD PROVISIONS FOR AGRICULTURE NEGOTIATIONS

CHAPTER 2 NATIONAL TREATMENT AND MARKET ACCESS FOR GOODS ARTICLE 2.1. Objective

Code of governance for resolving tax disputes

Private Sector Facility: Working with Local Private Entities, Including Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises

Agriculture Export competition 9 November 2018

AQA Economics A-level

Shop No.89, 1 st floor, Old Rajinder Nagar, New Delhi DAY REVISION PROGRAM DAY-25

GOVERNMENT OF THE REPUBLIC OF LITHUANIA. RESOLUTION No 1122

CANADA. Chapter 8. Quantitative Restrictions 1) EXPORT RESTRICTIONS ON LOGS

Summary of negotiating objectives

Resolution No. 76/2010 of the Polish Financial Supervision Authority of 10 March 2010

june 07 tpp 07-3 Service Costing in General Government Sector Agencies OFFICE OF FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Policy & Guidelines Paper

Should the WTO Restrict the Use of Export Restrictions? A Policy discussion

GATT Council's Evaluation

The 2014 U.S. Farm Bill: DDA Implications of Increased Countercyclical Support and Reliance on Insurance

Canadian Securities Administrators. CSA Consultation Paper Derivatives: End User Exemption. Page 1 of 18

Transcription:

Tackling Agriculture in the Post-Bali Context - A collection of short essays 147 Market Price Support in Large Developing Countries By Raul Montemayor In the run-up to the Bali Ministerial Meeting in December 2013, various proposals were presented to resolve the predicament of some developing countries that were at risk of violating WTO rules on domestic support because of their public stockholding programmes, which provide market price support to domestic producers. In Bali, WTO Ministers decided to temporarily shield such programmes from challenges until a permanent solution could be found. This paper summarizes the findings of a larger study conducted to provide policy-makers, negotiators and other stakeholders with an impartial, evidence-based analysis of policy options for such a permanent solution (Montemayor 2014). Under the WTO Agreement on Agriculture (AoA), the distortive effect of market price support programmes can be quantified into a product-specific Aggregate Measurement of Support (AMS). This is equal to the difference between a fixed external reference price and an applied administered price multiplied by the quantity of the product that is eligible to receive the administered price. The resultant AMS figure must not exceed the de minimis for such product, which is a monetary value equivalent to a prescribed percentage of the value of annual production of the said product. In other words, the AMS as a percentage of the total annual production value must not exceed the prescribed de minimis percentage. Figure 1: Formula for computing AMS as a percentage of production value Administered Price Reference Price Divided by Eligible Production = Volume of production x % of eligible production Total value of Production = Volume of Production x Average market price per unit of production Because the external reference prices were based on import prices during a distant base period (usually 1986 88), the gap between these prices and the current administered or buying prices increased over time. When the variance was multiplied by the eligible production, some countries found themselves at risk of breaching their de minimis limits. Several proposals have been raised to address this problem. The following sections assess the effect of some of these proposals on the behaviour of AMS and the capacity of countries to comply with the AoA rules on domestic support. The simulations cover five developing countries with existing public stockholding programmes that provide price support to producers. Only food staples, particularly wheat and rice, were included in

148 Tackling Agriculture in the Post-Bali Context - A collection of short essays the analysis. Relevant data on import prices, administered prices, production volumes and values, foreign exchange rates and other information was culled from the FAO Statistical Database and submissions of countries to the WTO. Table 1 provides a profile of the countries (coded from A to D) and commodities covered by the study. Notably, the public stockholding programmes of Countries A, C and D for rice covered a relatively small proportion of total domestic production (ranging from one to five per cent). In turn, procurement of rice in Country B and wheat in Countries B, C and E ranged from one fifth to one third of local production. Table 1: Profile of the countries and commodities covered by the study Country/Product/Crop Year % Procurement Administered/ Reference Price Administered/ Import Price Administered/ Producer Price Country A Rice, 2011 5% 26.53 1.33 1.21 Country B Rice, 2010 11 22% 4.58 0.32 0.55 Country C Rice, 2008 1% 0.87 0.48 0.79 Country D Rice, 2011 2% 5.87 1.14 1.15 Country B Wheat, 2010 11 26% 3.11 0.84 0.92 Country C Wheat, 2008 37% 0.88 0.45 0.90 Country E Wheat, 2010 11 25% 7.55 0.59 0.79 Except in Country C, administered prices were significantly higher than the corresponding reference prices. Country A registered the highest ratio with a derived administered price of almost 26 times the reference price in 2011. In turn, administered prices were generally lower than the equivalent prices of imports, except for rice in Countries A and D. A similar result was found when administered prices were compared to producer prices. Figure 2: Base scenario results Country A-Rice Country D-Rice Country E-Wheat AMS as a percentage of production value Country B-Wheat Country B-Rice Country C-Rice de minimis Country C-Wheat -20% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120%

Tackling Agriculture in the Post-Bali Context - A collection of short essays 149 The simulations confirm apprehensions that a literal and strict application of the AMS formula for market support price programmes could lead most of the developing countries covered by the study to breach their de minimis allowances for product-specific AMS. In this base scenario, no adjustments were made for reference and administered prices, and eligible production was set to total production on the assumption that price-support programmes were open-ended and available to all producers. As shown in Figure 2, only one country was able to comply consistently with the de minimis rule despite agreeing to a lower threshold (8.5% of total production value versus 10% for the others), mainly because its administered prices were significantly lower than its reference prices. The other countries ended up with de minimis percentages of 40% and above. Adjusting reference prices alone had mixed results. The use of three-year rolling averages for import prices produced the most positive outcome, although one country remained in breach of its de minimis cap primarily because of the unusually large gap between its reference and administered prices for rice. Adjusting reference prices for inflation, whether by using producer price indices or converting prices and monetary values to US dollars, also had generally positive effects but this was not sufficient to allow two of the five countries to comply with the de minimis rule for their rice products. Setting eligible production to actual procurement volume worked in favour of countries whose public stockholding programmes covered only a small proportion of local output. Three of the five countries that absorbed less than 5% of local production fared best in this scenario. In turn, the two other countries that purchased about one fourth of local wheat produce exceeded their AMS caps. Figure 3: 3-yr average import price plus actual procurement Country A-Rice Country D-Rice Country E-Wheat Country B-Wheat Country B-Rice Country C-Rice Country C-Wheat -30% -25% -20% -15% -10% -5% 0% 5% 10% 15%

150 Tackling Agriculture in the Post-Bali Context - A collection of short essays The only scenarios where all countries and commodities registered AMS within their de minimis was when the eligible production was equated to the actual procurement volume and reference prices were adjusted simultaneously, either by applying producer price indices, converting prices to US dollars, or using three-year or five-year rolling average prices of imports. Figure 3, for example, shows that, if reference prices were set to the average prices of imports in the preceding three years and the eligible production was pegged to the actual volume procured, all countries would be able to comply with the de minimis rule. In fact, only Country A ended up with a positive AMS equivalent to 2% of its annual value of rice production, which was nevertheless significantly below its 10% de minimis percentage cap. In terms of crafting a permanent solution, an Appellate Body ruling in a dispute involving Korean beef opened the possibility for countries to officially set a limit to the scope of their price-support programmes. On this basis, they could legally declare their eligible production to be a certain portion or percentage of local production. By setting the eligible production to a suitably low level, the gap between the administered and reference prices could be effectively overcome so as to arrive at an AMS falling within the de minimis. In fact, the simulations show that this option, which would require any change in AoA rules, could even allow countries to increase their procurement over current levels and still comply with AMS rules. This option appears to be the most practical and feasible approach for countries that want to maintain their price-support programmes but do not plan to absorb large portions of domestic production. If this option is not able to adequately address the concerns of some countries, the least contentious alternative would be to allow the use of US dollars in notifying prices and monetary values in AMS calculations and to equate eligible production only to the proportion of local output that is actually marketed by producers. These two adjustments would not be sufficient to resolve the problems of three countries, but they would at least bring one country s support programme, which was in breach in the base scenario, in compliance with de minimis rules. Another possible area of compromise would be to exempt developing countries from de minimis caps if their actual procurement does not exceed a given percentage of local production. This would address the concerns of countries whose procurement programmes are small and arguably contribute little to market distortions. However, since this option requires a change in AoA rules, the previous suggestion for countries to simply set a limit to their eligible production appears to be preferable as it would largely achieve the same result. Rebasing reference prices to a more recent period, adjusting them for inflation through the use of producer price indices, or replacing them with three-year or five-year Olympic averages for historical import prices may be difficult to pursue since this runs counter to the fixed nature of reference prices. In turn, increasing de minimis levels has minimal effects and would conceivably provide only temporary relief from breaches. Aside from adjusting the AMS formula, developing countries have the option to convert their buying programmes to green box measures by removing administered prices altogether. This will address fears that the price-support programmes of developing countries could lead to significant market distortions and even harm other developing countries if they involve large volumes that would eventually get dumped in export markets. Developing countries have the option to replace these

Tackling Agriculture in the Post-Bali Context - A collection of short essays 151 trade-distorting measures with practically unlimited amounts of input subsidies as long as these are extended to low-income or resource-poor farmers. Using budgetary outlays as proxies for the AMS through the equivalent method of support modality could be another option that could resolve the dilemma. The study concludes that the public stockholding issue is solvable and that developing countries have many options, both within and outside the AMS formula, to continue providing support to their farmers. At the same time, the pursuit of a permanent solution to the public stockholding issue should be viewed in the light of calls from several developing countries to rectify existing imbalances in the domestic support allowances accorded to developed vis-à-vis most developing countries. Care should nevertheless be exercised so that such programmes do not end up unduly distorting markets and even harming other developing countries.

152 Tackling Agriculture in the Post-Bali Context - A collection of short essays References Montemayor, Raul. 2014. Public Stockholding for Food Security Purposes: Scenarios and Options for a Permanent Solution. ICTSD Programme on Agricultural Trade and Sustainable Development, Issue Paper No. 51. Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development.