JEFF MACKIE-MASON. x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e

Similar documents
Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Instructor: Songzi Du

Moral Hazard. Economics Microeconomic Theory II: Strategic Behavior. Shih En Lu. Simon Fraser University (with thanks to Anke Kessler)

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Characterization of the Optimum

Graduate Microeconomics II Lecture 7: Moral Hazard. Patrick Legros

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

PhD Qualifier Examination

Simple e ciency-wage model

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

Game Theory with Applications to Finance and Marketing, I

ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1. Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301. General Equilibrium V: Public Goods

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

Prerequisites. Almost essential Risk MORAL HAZARD. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. April 2018 Frank Cowell: Moral Hazard 1

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Relational Incentive Contracts

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

market opportunity line fair odds line Example 6.6, p. 120.

(0.50, 2.75) (0,3) Equivalent Variation Compensating Variation

Lecture Slides - Part 2

Lecture Note: Monitoring, Measurement and Risk. David H. Autor MIT , Fall 2003 November 13, 2003

Lecture Notes - Insurance

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

ECON 4245 ECONOMICS OF THE FIRM

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Topic 6: Optimal Monetary Policy and International Policy Coordination

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

Problem Set: Contract Theory

One-Period Valuation Theory

Choice Under Uncertainty (Chapter 12)

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Problem Set: Contract Theory

Homework 2: Dynamic Moral Hazard

Mohammad Hossein Manshaei 1394

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

So we turn now to many-to-one matching with money, which is generally seen as a model of firms hiring workers

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

Reuben Gronau s Model of Time Allocation and Home Production

Adverse Selection and Costly External Finance

Effects of Wealth and Its Distribution on the Moral Hazard Problem

Risk Neutral Agent. Class 4

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Transactions with Hidden Action: Part 1. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Teoria das organizações e contratos

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

ECON Micro Foundations

Practice Problems 2: Asymmetric Information

Diskussionsbeiträge des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin. The allocation of authority under limited liability

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Penalty Functions. The Premise Quadratic Loss Problems and Solutions

Economics 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics Final Exam Suggested Solutions

Exploring the Effect of Wealth Distribution on Efficiency Using a Model of Land Tenancy with Limited Liability. Nicholas Reynolds

Slides III - Complete Markets

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Part II Classical Theory: Long Run Chapter 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

Economics II - Exercise Session, December 3, Suggested Solution

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Price Theory of Two-Sided Markets

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 7: Optimal Top Income Taxation

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Homework 1: Basic Moral Hazard

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Bargaining and Coalition Formation

Loss-leader pricing and upgrades

Backward Integration and Risk Sharing in a Bilateral Monopoly

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Solution Problem Set 2

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

Chapter 7 Moral Hazard: Hidden Actions

Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory

Moral Hazard. Two Performance Outcomes Output is denoted by q {0, 1}. Costly effort by the agent makes high output more likely.

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Transcription:

BASE (SYMMETRIC INFORMATION) MODEL FOR CONTRACT THEORY JEFF MACKIE-MASON 1. Preliminaries Principal and agent enter a relationship. Assume: They have access to the same information (including agent effort) All information is verifiable (a contract contingent on observable information can be enforced by courts) The relationship will have a random outcome x X (a finite set): x is a random variable with prior distrib known to both principal and agent, and the distribution depends on agent effort e Pr[x = x i e] = p i (e), for i {1, 2,..., n} p i (e) > 0 for all e, i: Cannot rule out any result for any given effort level (no perfect backward inferences). (NB: This matters for future analyses, when effort is hidden (unobservable or unverifiable by principal). Doesn t matter for the model below.) Principal s utility function is π(x t) where t is the transfer (payment) to the agent. π > 0, π 0 (concave utility = risk neutral or risk averse). Profit doesn t depend directly on agent effort or state of nature, but only the outcome. Agent s utility function is U(t, e) = u(t) v(e), which depends on transfer and effort. Additive separability means risk-aversion is independent of effort level (not a crucial assumption). Utility is concave in transfer, convex in effort: u (t) > 0,u (t) 0, v (e) > 0, v (e) 0. Date: Revision: March 15, 2008. 1

2 JEFF MACKIE-MASON Agent has free will: will not sign contract unless the expected utility is at least as high as his next best opportunity: reservation utility U 0 There is a clear conflict of interest: (1) principal cares about result, agent doesn t (directly) (2) principal not directly interested in effort, agent is (3) but effort makes better results more likely (NB: Macho-Staedler and Perez-Castrillo state this but don t make the assumption explicit.) The transfer t is the design variable for the contract. This is what the principal can set to try to reconcile the conflict: principal wants effort, pays agent t for effort. How big should t be? On what should t depend? 2. The optimal transfer With symmetric verifiable info, the principal s problem is to choose e required, and offer {t(x i )}, i = 1,..., n, to maximize surplus (expected profit), subject to agent willing to take the contract (E[U(x, e)] > U 0 ). The principal can specify the level of effort require and the contract terms because effort is verifiable. Thus, the principal can make a take it or leave it offer of the form work e hours for me, and I ll pay you t(x), or don t work for me at all. It s up to the agent to decide whether to accept this offer (the participation constraint). 1 (IR) max e,{t(x i )} s.t. p i (e)π(x i t(x i )) p i (e)u(t(x i )) v(e) U 0 Set up the Lagrangian and take first order condition for t(x i ): L = p i (e)π(x i t(x i )) λ p i (e)u(t(x i )) v(e) U 0 (FOC1) λ = π (x i t (x i )) u (t (x i )) for all i 1 When we get to hidden action, of course, the principal will not be able to specify both the effort level and the transfer terms.

BASE (SYMMETRIC INFORMATION) MODEL FOR CONTRACT THEORY 3 What can we say about the solution? First, the participation constraint (IR) must bind: if not, the principal could reduce the transfer in every state by E[U] U 0. What do we know from (FOC1)? (1) The outcome (with symmetric information) is Pareto efficient: Holding fixed agent U, maximize the principal s utility, π(x t). Can change distribution of surplus by changing U 0. (2) (FOC1) says ratio of marginal utilities (the MRS) should be constant: usual condition for Pareto efficient outcome. (3) If π is constant (P is risk-neutral) then u (t (x i )) = constant for all i, since the ratio is a constant (λ ). If u is not constant for all transfers (that is, if the agent is not risk neutral), then the solution when π is constant requires that all transfers

4 JEFF MACKIE-MASON be constant, that is t (x i ) = t (x j ) for all i, j. In short, when the principal is risk-neutral, she completely insures the agent (who gets constant t ). (4) Indeed, with P risk-neutral, we can solve for the optimal transfer explicitly, since (IR) is binding (E[U] = U 0 ) : t = u 1 (U 0 +v(e )). That is, it s the cash equivalent of U 0 plus the amount necessary to compensate A for disutility of working. (5) Suppose A is risk-neutral (u constant) and P is not. Then π (x i t (x i )) is constant, so t (x i ) = x i k for some constant k. Essentially, P gives entire output to A, and A pays a constant franchise fee k back. Or, put another way, P sells the firm to A for price p. Since (IR) must be satisfied: p i (e )(x i k) = U 0 + v(e ), so k = p i (e )x i U 0 v(e ). That is, k (the price of buying the firm) is set equal to expected profit of owning the firm less the amount necessary for A to participate. When both are risk averse, the optimal contract lies somewhere in-between: share risk so that both have some uncertainty about their outcome (but A still gets only U 0 ). 3. The optimal effort The choice of effort affects the probability of different output levels (that is, of course, the whole point). Without strong restrictions on the effect that effort has on distribution of output, expected utility might not be concave: and that means the first order conditions might not provide a maximum. 2 Main intuitive result (necessary, not sufficient): the expected profits from an increase in effort must be equal to the transfer increment P pays A to compensate for increased disutility of effort. Effort: I mentioned above that solving for effort is complex (because the problem may not be concave). Let s look at a simple case that is easy to solve: no uncertainty. Assume that output depends on effort according to x = f(e), with f > 0, f < 0. Then principal solves: max f(e) t(e) e,{t(e)} s.t. t(e) v(e) U 0 2 The principal, or the analyst cannot insist that the relationship between effort and output satisfy the conditions necessary for expected utility to be concave: how effort affects output is more or less a given for a particular problem. It s true, the principal might design her production process to change the way that effort affects output, to some extent, but you wouldn t do this just to make the math easier!

BASE (SYMMETRIC INFORMATION) MODEL FOR CONTRACT THEORY 5 (since x = f(e) we now express everything in terms of e for simplicity). Suppose the principal offers a linear wage contract with fixed payment, t(e) = we + K. Then the agent chooses how much to work according to: max we + K v(e) e which has FOC: w = v (e). Now the principal chooses the parameters of the wage function: max f(e) we K w,k (IR) s.t. we + K v(e) U 0. Since K only makes principal worse off, it is chosen to be as small as possible so that (IR) is binding (satisfied as an equality). Then we can substitute the (IR) constraint into the profit function and optimize: max w,k f(e) v(e) U 0 which has FOC: f (e) = v (e) = w where the last equality is from the solution of the agent s effort choice problem. So, the principal sets the variable component of compensation equal to the marginal product of effort, f (e). Summary: wage equals marginal product. Fixed payment just enough to make the worker willing to work overall (K = U 0 + v(e) we). Output is efficient (f (e) = v (e)), which is the usual efficiency condition that marginal product equal marginal cost. 4. Questions for thought What change in the information conditions above might lead to a result in which the agent would get expected utility from the contract that is greater than U 0? (1) If U 0 were unknown by P, then P and A would have to bargain over how much rent to give to A and the outcome will generally be E[U] U 0. That is, because P does not know A s walking away point (U 0 ), P can t push A all the way down to the minimal level of utility. How much better A will do depends on A s bargaining power. (2) If e is unobservable (or unverifiable), then the same idea: they would bargain. Although P knows A s walking away point (U 0 ), P doesn t know how close she is pushing A to that point because she doesn t know exactly how much effort e that A will exert. This situation (asymmetric information about e, the hidden action problem) is the topic of next week s analysis.

6 JEFF MACKIE-MASON The amount by which E[U] > U 0 is A s information rent. The more valuable is the unknown information, and the more bargaining power A has, the more information rent A will receive (the higher will be E[U]).