No. 2009/29. Dimitris Georgarakos and Giacomo Pasini

Similar documents
Trust, Sociability and Stock Market Participation

Chapter 9 The Case for International Diversification

1. Expected utility, risk aversion and stochastic dominance

Notes on the Cost of Capital

CHAPTER 13. Investor Behavior and Capital Market Efficiency. Chapter Synopsis

Misreporting Corporate Performance

An Empirical Analysis of the Role of Risk Aversion. in Executive Compensation Contracts. Frank Moers. and. Erik Peek

Quantitative Results for a Qualitative Investor Model A Hybrid Multi-Agent Model with Social Investors

The Relationship Between Franking Credits and the Market Risk Premium

HYPERTENSION AND LIFE SATISFACTION: A COMMENT AND REPLICATION OF BLANCHFLOWER AND OSWALD (2007)

Chapter 8. Inflation, Interest Rates, and Exchange Rates. Lecture Outline

The Effects of Trust on Stock Market Participation

The Wider Impacts Sub-Objective TAG Unit

Perspective of Individuals on Personal Financial Planning

Securitized Markets and International Capital Flows

The Morningstar Category Average Methodology

TITLE. Performance aspects of Greek bond mutual funds

Competition, Deposit Insurance and Bank Risk-taking

Nontariff Barriers and Domestic Regulation. Alan V. Deardorff University of Michigan

On the Role of Authority in Just-In-Time Purchasing Agreements

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Capital allocation in Indian business groups

Can Social Programs Reduce Producitivity and Growth? A Hypothesis for Mexico

Depression Babies: Do Macroeconomic Experiences Affect Risk-Taking?

THE SLOWDOWN IN GROWTH IN 2008 AND ITS

How to Set Minimum Acceptable Bids, with an Application to Real Estate Auctions

Corporate Socialism Around the World

Optimal Internal Control Regulation

One-Size or Tailor-Made Performance Ratios for Ranking Hedge Funds

Measuring Alpha-Based Performance: Implications for Alpha-Focused Structured Products

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

Do Fire Sales Create Externalities? *

Discussion of Stock Market Investment: The Role of Human Capital by Athreya, Ionescu, Neelakantan Michael Haliassos, Goethe University Frankfurt,

Published in French in: Revue d Economie du Développement, Vol.3, (1995), pp HOUSEHOLD MODELING FOR THE DESIGN OF POVERTY ALLEVIATION

Financial Literacy and Subjective Expectations Questions: A Validation Exercise

The Impact of Labour Market Partial Reforms on Workers Productivity: The Italian Case

Ination Expectations and Consumption Expenditure

Being Locked Up Hurts

Internet Appendix. The survey data relies on a sample of Italian clients of a large Italian bank. The survey,

Financial Literacy and the Demand for Financial Advice

UK Evidence on the Profitability and the Risk-Return Characteristics of Merger Arbitrage

Alain de Janvry and Elisabeth Sadoulet

The fundamentals of the derivation of the CAPM can be outlined as follows:

WORKING PAPER SERIES

Abstract

Household Balance Sheets and Debt an International Country Study

Potential drivers of insurers equity investments

Economic Watch Deleveraging after the burst of a credit-bubble Alfonso Ugarte / Akshaya Sharma / Rodolfo Méndez

Trust in the Central Bank and Inflation Expectations #

Real Estate Ownership by Non-Real Estate Firms: The Impact on Firm Returns

Trust in the Central Bank and Inflation Expectations #

What do we learn about redistribution effects of pension systems from internationally comparable measures of Social Security Wealth?

Data Appendix. A.1. The 2007 survey

Impact of Imperfect Information on the Optimal Exercise Strategy for Warrants

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Financial Advisors: A Case of Babysitters?

Risk Aversion, Prudence, and the Three-Moment Decision Model for Hedging

Securitized Markets, International Capital Flows, and Global Welfare

Fakultät III Univ.-Prof. Dr. Jan Franke-Viebach

Does Growth make us Happier? A New Look at the Easterlin Paradox

To Formalize or Not to Formalize? Comparisons of microenterprise data from Southern and East Africa *

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Annual Asset Management Report: Facts and Figures

Flash Eurobarometer N o 189a EU communication and the citizens. Analytical Report. Fieldwork: April 2008 Report: May 2008

Pension Wealth and Household Saving in Europe: Evidence from SHARELIFE

Weighting issues in EU-LFS

European Commission Directorate-General "Employment, Social Affairs and Equal Opportunities" Unit E1 - Social and Demographic Analysis

Appendix A. Additional Results

Environmental Regulation through Voluntary Agreements

Analysis of the contribution of transport policies to the competitiveness of the EU economy and comparison with the United States.

Consumption, Income and Wealth

S12-4 A STUDY ON THE DEVELOPMENT OF A COST MODEL BASED ON THE OWNER S DECISION MAKING AT THE EARLY STAGES OF A CONSTRUCTION PROJECT

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

Aid, Remittances, and the Informal Economy

SAMPLE DESIGN APPENDIX A

November 5, Very preliminary work in progress

Determination of manufacturing exports in the euro area countries using a supply-demand model

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

Aid, Remittances, and the Informal Economy

Interaction of household income, consumption and wealth - statistics on main results

Cross-Sectional Variation of Intraday Liquidity, Cross-Impact, and their Effect on Portfolio Execution

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Empirical Analysis of Policy Interventions

Themes Income and wages in Europe Wages, productivity and the wage share Working poverty and minimum wage The gender pay gap

Partial Deposit Insurance and Moral Hazard in Banking

Entry Mode, Technology Transfer and Management Delegation of FDI. Ho-Chyuan Chen

The Relative Income Hypothesis: A comparison of methods.

What Firms Know. Mohammad Amin* World Bank. May 2008

Discussion Reactions to Dividend Changes Conditional on Earnings Quality

How Do Households Allocate Their Assets? Stylized Facts from the Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Survey

Fertility Decline and Work-Life Balance: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications

INDIVIDUAL CONSUMPTION and SAVINGS DECISIONS

Essays on Asset Pricing and Downside Risk

Financial Literacy and Savings Account Returns *

Does Taking Part in Social Activities prevent the Disablement Process?

On the way to 2020: data for vocational education and training policies

EFFECT OF GENERAL UNCERTAINTY ON EARLY AND LATE VENTURE- CAPITAL INVESTMENTS: A CROSS-COUNTRY STUDY. Rajeev K. Goel* Illinois State University

WORKING PAPERS. International Outsourcing and Labour with Sector-specific Human Capital. Kurt Kratena

Flash Eurobarometer 386 THE EURO AREA REPORT

ARE LEISURE AND WORK PRODUCTIVITY CORRELATED? A MACROECONOMIC INVESTIGATION

Transcription:

No. 2009/29 Trust, Sociability and Stock Market Participation Dimitris Georgarakos and Giacomo Pasini Center or Financial Studies Goethe-Universität Frankurt House o Finance Grüneburgplatz 1 60323 Frankurt Deutschland Teleon: +49 (0)69 798-30050 Fax: +49 (0)69 798-30077 http://www.ik-cs.de E-Mail: ino@ik-cs.de

Center or Financial Studies The Center or Financial Studies is a nonproit research organization, supported by an association o more than 120 banks, insurance companies, industrial corporations and public institutions. Established in 1968 and closely ailiated with the University o Frankurt, it provides a strong link between the inancial community and academia. The CFS Working Paper Series presents the result o scientiic research on selected topics in the ield o money, banking and inance. The authors were either participants in the Center s Research Fellow Program or members o one o the Center s Research Projects. I you would like to know more about the Center or Financial Studies, please let us know o your interest. Pro. Dr. Jan Pieter Krahnen Center or Financial Studies Goethe-Universität House o Finance Grüneburgplatz 1 60323 Frankurt am Main Deutschland Teleon: +49 (0)69 798-30050 Fax: +49 (0)69 798-30077 http://www.ik-cs.de E-Mail: ino@ik-cs.de

CFS Working Paper No. 2009/29 Trust, Sociability and Stock Market Participation* Dimitris Georgarakos 1 and Giacomo Pasini 2 November 18, 2009 Abstract: We investigate the eects o both trust and sociability or stock market participation, the role o which has been examined separately by existing inance literature. We use internationally comparable household data rom the Survey o Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe supplemented with regional inormation on generalized trust rom the World Value Survey and on speciic trust to inancial institutions rom Eurobarometer. We show that trust and sociability have distinct and sizeable positive eects on stock market participation and that sociability is likely to partly balance the discouragement eect on stockholding induced by low generalized trust in the region o residence. We also show that speciic trust in advice given by inancial institutions represents a prominent actor or stock investing, compared to other tangible eatures o the banking environment. Probing urther into various groups o households, we ind that sociability can induce stockholding among the less well o in Sweden, Denmark, and Switzerland where stock market participation is widespread. On the other hand, the eect o generalized trust is strong in countries with limited participation and low average trust like Austria, Spain, and Italy, oering an explanation or the remarkably low participation rates o the wealthy living therein. JEL-Classiications: A13, D12, D8, G11 Keywords: Trust, Sociability, Household Finance, Stockholding. * Georgarakos acknowledges inancial support by the Center or Financial Studies (CFS) under the Research Program Household Wealth Management. Pasini acknowledges inancial support by the NETSPAR theme Pensions, savings, and retirement decisions and rom the University o Padua (research grant CPDA071899). We would like to thank Dimitris Christelis, Sergio Currarini, Ernst Fehr, Luigi Guiso, Michael Haliassos, Tullio Jappelli, Daniel Schunk, Stephan Siegel and seminar participants at the Annual Congress o the European Economic Association in Barcelona, the Annual Meeting o the German Finance Association (DGF) in Frankurt, the MEA Conerence on the Economics o Ageing in Deidesheim, the SHARE users conerence in Mainz and at Venice University or useul suggestions. We are also grateul to Sven Fürth or excellent research assistance. 1 Department o Money and Macroeconomics, House o Finance, Grueneburgplatz 1 PF H32, 60323, Frankurt am Main, Germany. E-mail: georgarakos [at] wiwi.uni-rankurt.de; tel: +49 69 798 33830. 2 Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche, Università Ca Foscari, Cannaregio 821, 30121,Venezia, Italy. E-mail: giacomo.pasini [at] unive.it; tel: +39 041 2349228.

1. Introduction Literature on the implications o various aspects o social capital on household portolio decisions has rapidly developed. Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2004) show that Italian households tend to invest higher amounts in inancial assets and to make less use o inormal credit when they live in regions with high blood donation, electoral participation, and trust rates. Recently, Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2008, henceorth GSZ) have examined the eects o trust on stock market participation using Dutch and Italian survey data with inormation on a sel-reported measure o trust. GSZ also associate dierences in stock market participation across countries with variation in aggregate levels o trust by regressing the share o stockholders in each country on the average levels o trust and ew other country-wide indicators (quality o legal enorcement and existence o a common law system). They show that countries with high prevailing trust exhibit on average high stock ownership rates, consistently with the act that prospective investors in low-trust countries perceive a higher probability o being cheated. In a related ramework, Hong, Kubik and Stein (2004, henceorth HKS) provide evidence that sociability, as proxied by relationships with neighbors and church visits, osters stock market participation. They mainly attribute this inding to the act that word-o-mouth inormation sharing lowers inormation costs, triggering participation o the more sociable individuals. As the authors stress: While the social-capital variables used by Guiso et al. (2004) are obviously quite dierent rom our social-interaction proxies, one might stretch and argue that our results relect a similar kind o social-capital mechanism. [ ] Although it is hard or us to address this hypothesis ully with our data, we can take a small step by looking at the eect o our social interaction variables on checking account use. Their presumption is that current accounts are subject to small entry costs and thus sociability, unlike social capital, should not play any role in their use. HKS derive an insigniicant eect o their social interaction indicators on current account ownership that is interpreted as indirect evidence or the distinct role o sociability rom other particular aspects o social capital like trust. Trust and sociability might be positively associated but aect stock ownership via two dierent channels, as the aorementioned studies imply. Sociability serves to reduce ixed participation costs through cheaper inormation sharing. Mistrust lowers the expected return rom an investment, given that potential investors need to take into account the possibility that a 1

contract will not be respected by the counterpart. The distinct role o the two is also supported by literature on social capital that will be reviewed in the next section. The key motivation o our study is to examine under the same ramework the contributions o trust and sociability to stockholding and evaluate the possible implications or observed dierences in households investment behavior across European countries. To this end, we employ the standard portolio model o GSZ, which takes into account the probability to be cheated, and we extend it by incorporating sociability coherently with HKS. We then obtain distinct predictions about the role o trust and sociability or stock investing. We empirically examine these predictions using internationally comparable survey data containing inormation on household sociability and asset holdings, supplemented with inormation on trust prevailing in each region ( generalized reerring to other community members and speciic reerring to inancial institutions). A noteworthy observation that one can make out o these data is that while households median net wealth holdings are roughly comparable across groups o European countries in the sample, stock market participation rates exhibit remarkable dierences. For example, in countries with widespread stock market participation (Sweden, Denmark, and Switzerland) households with below median wealth exhibit twice as high participation rates relative to their more than median wealth counterparts in low participation countries (Austria, Spain, and Italy). As our study compares to HKS it takes into account, apart rom sociability, the trust levels that households experience in the region they reside. With reerence to GSZ we extend to the household level their cross country investigation on the relevance o generalized trust or aggregate stockholding by using internationally comparable survey data and exploiting withincountry variation in trust levels. Extending international comparisons in stockholding to the household level allows us to take into account, apart rom country-wide indicators, the prevailing trust in the region o residence, individual sociability, and various socio-economic actors that aect households investment behavior. Another novel aspect o this approach is that it allows to examine and compare the investment decisions o speciic groups o households and to make appropriate quantitative statements. Furthermore, we shed light on the role o trust rom a dierent perspective by considering speciic trust in advice given by inancial institutions and examining its implications or stock investing when belies about certain eatures o the banking environment are taken into account. In comparison to the part o GSZ analysis that investigates 2

the inluence o sel-reported trust on stockholding decisions within a given country (Netherlands and Italy), we allow or an independent role o sociability and we use a regional-average rather than an individual-speciic measure o trust. Our approach is consistent with the notion o contextual trust in the social capital literature, namely that trust is determined by the aggregate perceptions o all members in the community and thus individuals are trust-takers (Knack and Keeer, 1997). As it will be discussed later, such a measure is less likely to suer rom endogeneity bias. This paper contributes to the existing literature in the ollowing ways. First, we show that generalized trust and sociability have distinct and signiicant eects on stockholding and that their relative contribution changes with household wealth holdings as well as with average stock market participation rates and trust levels in the country. Second, speciic trust in advice given by inancial institutions represents a prominent actor or stock investing, over and above the inluence o other eatures o the banking environment aced by households (e.g. costs required to change banks, access to ormal credit and internet banking). Third, we shed more light on the striking dierences in stockholding across Europe by linking them to the regional variation in prevailing generalized trust and household heterogeneity in sociability. We use data rom the Survey on Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe (SHARE), that interviews households aged 50 and above across eleven countries. SHARE data represent a rich source o inormation on various demographics and asset holdings and contain a series o questions about households social behavior (participation in voluntary activities, in educational training courses, in sport and political clubs and so on). We use answers to these questions to construct a household-speciic measure o sociability. We supplement SHARE with inormation on generalized trust prevailing at dierent regions within each country that we recover rom the World Values Survey (WVS), a cross national survey on values and norms. WVS asks households whether they think other people should be trusted or not. This inormation allows us to compute the raction o people who trust in each region in a given country and subsequently assign this to SHARE respondents who live in the same region. In the same way we merge SHARE data with regional inormation on speciic trust in the advice given by inancial institutions as well as households assessment o the quality o inancial services that we recover rom a special Eurobarometer module. In addition, we include in our dataset regional GDP 3

growth rates and participation in EU elections rom various data sources in order to perorm a number o robustness checks. We estimate net positive eects o both trust and sociability on stock market participation and we present some evidence suggesting that sociability can partly balance the discouragement eect on stockholding induced by low generalized trust in the region o residence. We ind that more sociable households are more likely to invest in stocks compared to their less sociable counterparts and this eect is stronger in countries with widespread stock market participation. We also estimate independent positive eects on stockholding due to the regional variation in generalized trust as well as in trust speciic to inancial institutions that are net o the role o sociability, o various socio-economic characteristics, and o dierences in institutional and other nationwide actors that are captured by country dummies in our models. Trust in the advice given by inancial institutions in particular has a prominent role in stock investing, over and above the inluence o regional disparities in the costs required to change banks and in the access to internet services. The eect o generalized trust is signiicant in countries with low stock market participation rates and relatively low average trust and is particularly strong or the wealthy households. For example, we ind that i a wealthy household living in a low trust region in Austria, Spain, and Italy moves to a region o higher generalized trust within these countries, other things equal, can nearly double the probability o investing in stocks directly. Thus, low prevailing generalized trust oers a possible explanation or the remarkably low participation rates among the better o who live in the aorementioned countries. On the other hand, living in a region with higher generalized trust does not contribute to an increase in stockholding in countries where stock market participation is widespread and the average trust level is high, like in Sweden, Denmark, and Switzerland. Nevertheless, higher sociability in these countries can oster direct stock market participation among the less wealthy households. The rest o the paper is organized as ollows. Section 2 reviews the existing literature and provides the theoretical justiication in treating trust and sociability as distinct concepts. Section 3 presents the implications o considering both the probability to be cheated and sociability in a standard portolio model. In section 4 we provide details on the data at hand and we present related descriptive statistics. Section 5 discusses the econometric speciication, and section 6 reports the empirical results. Section 7 oers concluding remarks. 4

2. Trust and Sociability in the Social Capital Literature Trust and sociability are recurrent concepts in the social capital literature, both in Sociology and in Economics. Durlau and Fachamps (2004), ater reviewing several relevant studies distinguished three common eatures: (a) Social capital generates positive externalities or members o a group; (b) these externalities are achieved thanks to shared trust, norms and values and their eect on expectations and behavior; and (c) shared trust, norms and values arise rom inormal organizations based on social network and associations. Thus, it is diicult to reduce social capital to a single deinition, and it is quite common in empirical investigations to ocus on particular and measurable aspects o social capital. Islam, Merlo, Kawachi, Lindström and Gerdtham (2006) proposed a distinction into cognitive and structural social capital which is coherent with Durlau and Fachamps (2004) observations: the ormer is operationalized into people s perceptions about the level o interpersonal trust, sharing and reciprocity; the latter regards the density o social networks, or patterns o civic engagements. We irst concentrate on the economic rationale behind the association o cognitive social capital with stock market participation. La Porta, Florencio and Shleier (2006) state that inancial agreements require adequate level o transparency. The buyer must believe that the asset issuer (i.e. the inancial institution or the Government) will be able to repay the agreedupon yield in the uture; she must also be sure that the contract that she is writing is enorceable and covers all the relevant contingencies; moreover she should believe that in case o a litigation the attorney ees are bearable and the judicial process is air and ast. Those conditions can be guaranteed by an appropriate set o securities laws or, as Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2004) suggest, by generalized trust. In a high-trust society inormal agreement may substitute or costly contracts, litigations are less requent, costs to protect rom property rights violations are lower, and institutions, both private and public, are likely to be perceived as more credible. Knack and Keeer (1997) ormalize this idea and deine trust in terms o belies in a game theoretic ramework: [Trust is] the raction o people in a society who expect that most others will act cooperatively in a prisoner s dilemma context. The intuition is that trust is a eature o the community an individual leaves in, and not a personal trait: a single member may be trustworthy towards his peers, but this eeling must be reciprocated by others in order to be rewarding. Thus, trust is determined by the aggregate perceptions o all the members, while single individuals are 5

trust-takers, meaning that no one can modiy the overall level o trust perceived in a community. 1 We measure the prevailing trust in a given region as the proportion o people in this region who state that trust the others. This is a quite common approach to measuring generalized trust and it has been used by Guiso, Sapienza and Zingales (2004), Knack and Keeer (1997) and by Rostila (2008) to assess the impact o trust on portolio decisions, economic growth, and health outcomes respectively. In the same way we construct a measure o regional trust in the advice given by inancial institutions that gives a direct insight into this speciic aspect o trust. 2 Structural social capital (i.e. the density o social networks) can also aect stock market participation. Jackson (2006) reviews the recent advances in the ield ocusing mainly on the role o inormation acquired through social interactions in determining human behavior and economic outcomes. 3 Social interactions can serve as a mean o word-o-mouth inormation diusion or o observational learning, reducing inormation costs and lowering eectively the stock market participation hurdle (see HKS). For example, a prospective investor may learn rom riends or acquaintances about high-return stocks or how to manage stocks eiciently. Thereore, sociability in our context is a measure o interactions with reliable and potentially inormative acquaintances. Granovetter (1978) argues that a single connection with someone outside the restricted network o relatives and close riends can be more helpul in inding a job than a dense but isolated set o relations, i.e. what matters are weak ties as contrasted to strong ties. 4 Following HKS, we adopt an index that is consistent with weak ties and it is based on responses to survey questions regarding participation in political parties, sport and cultural clubs, charities and similar activities. This approach is quite common in the sociology literature (see Granovetter, 1983 and Putman, Leonardi and Nanetti, 1993). Measures o network centrality as in Calvó-Armengol, Patacchini and Zenou (2005) or network density as in Vega-Redondo 1 The argument that trust should be studied as a collective phenomenon and not as a property o individuals has been also made in the sociology literature (see or example Newton, 2001). 2 We use the terms trust and generalized trust interchangeably, while trust in the advice given by inancial institutions is always termed as speciic trust. 3 There is also a growing related literature o peer group eects on various economic decisions. See or example the works o Madrian and Shea (2000) and Dulo and Saez (2002) who show that individuals decisions about their retirement investment plans are inluenced by the choices o their working colleagues. 4 Such a distinction resembles the one between bridging and bonding social capital, proposed by Putnam (2000). Bonding social capital reers to the relationships within homogenous groups, i.e. the links within a amily, among relatives or close riends. Bridging social capital reers to the ties among those who belong to dierent ethnic or religious groups, or among individuals with dierent educational and occupational background. 6

(1996), which are widely used in economics due to their theoretical link to network theory, do not it in our setup given that they measure characteristics o strong ties networks. 3. Trust and Sociability in a Standard Portolio Model In order to illustrate in an analytical ramework the distinct roles o trust and sociability, we employ the portolio model presented by GSZ and we extend it in order to account or sociability in a way coherent with HKS. There are two assets available to investors: a sae asset, which yields return r, and a risky asset with an uncertain return ~ r distributed with mean E[ ~ r ] r. Given an initial wealth W, an individual who invests a positive share o her r wealth in the stock market maximizes the ollowing expected utility unction: max EU ~ rw (1 ) r W (1) Thereore, she will choose to participate in the stock market (i.e., >0) i ~ rw (1 ) r W U r W EU (2) While ~ r r measures the return rom bearing market risk, the potential investor may ace risk actors that are not accounted in ~ r : or example, the recent deault o Lehman Brothers was clearly unanticipated and was not relected in its market valuation. The stock investment can also become worthless i the contract signed is not enorceable (e.g. because the intermediary goes bankrupt or the broker runs away with money) or i costs are unbearable in case o litigation. Thus, we deine mistrust as the probability p, independent rom the probability distribution o the risky asset return, that individuals assign to the event that the value o a planed investment (initial capital and interest) goes to zero. In the previous section we described trust as a eature o the community an individual belongs to. Thus, we treat p as common to all the individuals living in the same region. It actually serves as a discount actor that a prospective investor applies to her utility unction. This is an inherently partial equilibrium ramework: individuals are trust 7

takers i.e. each o them behaves as her choice had no eect on the equilibrium level o p. The new participation condition is given by: ~ rw (1 ) r W pu (1 r W U r W ( 1 p) EU ) (3) It is apparent rom various survey data that many households do not participate in the stock market and ixed participation costs have been proposed as a leading explanation or this trend (Mankiw and Zeldes, 1991, Haliassos and Bertaut, 1995, Vissing-Jorgensen, 2003). Such costs include not only brokerage and monetary ees but also non-tangible costs such as costs o time, costs o processing inormation as well as costs o picking and monitoring advisors and keeping up with market developments. Following GSZ, we introduce a ixed cost o participation : i individual i decides to enter the stock market, she has to pay an entry ee and then to allocate the remaining disposable wealth W- between the sae and the risky asset. Alternatively, she can decide not to invest in stocks, saving the participation cost. Hence, the participation condition becomes: ~ r ( W ) (1 ) r ( W ) pu (1 ) r ( W U r W ( 1 p) EU ) (4) implying that or each given level o mistrust p, the introduction o lowers participation. Sociability allows individuals to reduce the ixed participation costs through cheaper inormation sharing and eectively augments the disposable wealth, which in turn induces participation. Following HKS we assume that the ixed participation cost or an individual can be speciied as ollows: ( ) where ( 0), d ( ) d 0, lim where 0 (5) is bounded between and and it is decreasing in, the number o people who invest in stocks among individual s acquaintances. This is consistent with the notion that the cost o participation or an individual is reduced when more o her peers participate. As already explained, the network serves as a mean o word-o-mouth inormation diusion. A sociable individual has a 8

larger social circle and thus she is more likely to meet people who have invested in the stock market and thus can convey valuable inormation about stockholding. It should be noted that represents the total number o peers who participate, and not the raction o people who participate: a more sociable individual, even i she takes part to activities that are not directly related to asset investment, is likely to meet a larger number o people who participate in the stock market than her non-sociable counterparts. Thereore, each individual chooses in order to maximize her expected utility conditional on trust, sociability, wealth, and rates o return: max ~ EU[ p,, r, r, W ] (1 p) EU ~ r where EU[ ] pu W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) U r W i 0 i 0 (6) Then, the participation condition is written as: ~ r W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) pu (1 ) r W ( ) U r W ( 1 p) EU (7) Given that market risk is treated as in standard portolio models and the introduction o trust and sociability neither aects the properties o the utility unction nor the distribution o risky return r~, we can abstract rom market risk and re-deine equation (7) in terms o rˆ, the certainty equivalent o ~ r : rˆ W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) pu (1 ) r W ( ) U r W ( 1 p) U (8) The main dierence rom GSZ model is the act that the participation cost is no longer constant but it is now assumed to decrease in sociability. This implies that more sociable individuals dispose o a higher wealth endowment to invest in the stock market. More ormally, the irst empirical implication o the model is that or any value o p, the let hand side o (8) is monotonically increasing in disposable wealth W ( ) and thus it is monotonically increasing in. Consequently, the probability o participation (i.e. when condition (8) is 9

satisied) is increasing in given the level o trust (1-p). Note that represents a peer eect, and as such it may act as a social multiplier on wealth (and potentially on other determinants o participation omitted rom this simple model) 5 : this eature o the model may lead to multiple equilibria. Establishing the set o conditions on U that rule out multiple equilibria is beyond the scope o this paper. The second empirical implication o the model derives rom proposition 3 o GSZ. Deine A rˆ W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) and B ( 1 ) r W ( ) ~ r r 0 E, as long as W ( ) U rˆ W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) U (1 ) r W ( ) (9). Since we assumed Thereore, or a given, 1 p) U A pu B ( is decreasing in p: the probability o participation is increasing in the level o trust (1-p). The above suggest that trust and sociability have distinct eects on stock market participation when the standard portolio model o GSZ that takes into account trust is extended to incorporate sociability coherently with HKS. This is not the only implication we can obtain rom the model: the let hand side o equation (8) is a linear combination o continuous utility unctions, thus i there exists a solution * to the maximization problem with p>0 and 0, then it must exist a triplet (W=W, p p, ) such that (8) holds with equality: rˆ W ( ) (1 ) r W ( ) pu (1 ) r W ( ) U r W ( 1 p) U (10) Equation (10) implies that there exists a minimum value o wealth W, a maximum value o mistrust p, and a minimum value o sociability or which a potential investor is indierent * between paying the ixed entry cost upront and investing a raction (such that 0 ) o the disposable wealth W- in stocks on the one hand, and staying out o the market avoiding the ixed cost and investing all her wealth W in the sae asset on the other hand. We can now 5 Inormally, the mechanism can be described as ollows: a marginal increase in wealth o individual i, W i could induce i to participate. This creates externalities or her peers and thereore aects their chances to participate. Thus the raction o i s peers who participate i is likely to increase itsel, reinorcing the eect o a marginal increase in W i. 10

examine the interrelationship among p, and W, the values o mistrust, sociability, and wealth respectively that trigger participation. Provided that the utility unction is well behaved, the ollowing proposition holds: Proposition 1: Given 0 and W=W, the level o trust ( 1 p) and the minimum sociability level which trigger participation are inversely related. This is proved in appendix I using the implicit unction theorem. Moreover, once sociability is ixed, proposition 4 by GSZ holds: or any probability [ ] p there exists a wealth threshold W(p) that triggers participation and W(p) is increasing on p 6. Based on the above, we perorm a series o comparative statics exercises and the implications we draw can be summarized as ollows: i. Sociable households should have a higher probability to invest in stocks, because o their interactions with other investors. Thus, given mistrust p and wealth W, the marginal eect o sociability should be higher in countries where there is a high density o stockmarket participants. This is in line with the HKS model predictions and consistent with the notion that in regions where only a minority invests in stocks even the sociable individuals will have ew inormative acquaintances in their social circle. * ii. Given and, the higher the wealth is, the lower is the trust threshold ( 1 p) that iii. triggers participation and vice versa. Thus, among the wealthy, we expect to observe a signiicant eect o a marginal increase in trust even in low trust communities, while this eect should not be present among the less wealthy. The same implication derives rom the GSZ model. * Given and wealth W, participation can be triggered by a low level o trust ( 1 p) i sociability is high enough and vice versa. In our empirical investigation we ind evidence in avor o i and ii. As regards iii, our indings based on the pooled sample o countries suggest that sociability has a stronger eect on stockholding in low trust regions compared to its eect in high trust regions. Yet, the intensity o the relative eects o generalized trust and sociability varies across dierent countries or groups 6 For a ormal proo reer to appendix I and to GSZ. 11

o households (e.g. sociability should be more eective in countries with high stockownership; trust can be more relevant or the wealthy). Thus, we assess empirically their relative impact on stockholding by examining various population subgroups. 4. SHARE and WVS data We use data rom the irst wave o SHARE which was conducted in 2004. 7 SHARE is a multi-disciplinary, cross-national survey that is representative to the population aged 50 and over. The survey took place in eleven European countries, namely Sweden (SE), Denmark (DK), Germany (DE), the Netherlands (NL), Belgium (BE), France (FR), Switzerland (CH), Austria (AT), Italy (IT), Spain (ES), and Greece 8. The unit o analysis is the household, given that most o the asset questions are asked at household level. 9 The common design o the survey has enabled international comparisons o household wealth holdings (see Christelis, Georgarakos and Haliassos, 2008). SHARE contains all the necessary inormation to construct a sociability indicator similar to the one proposed by HKS. A household is classiied as sociable i at least one o the partners took part to one (or more) o the ollowing social activities the month preceding the interview: voluntary or charity work; educational or training course; a sport, social or other kind o club; activities organized by a political or community organization. 10 The measure or generalized trust is obtained rom the WVS using the same question that GSZ employ to calculate country wide trust rates. WVS is a collection o surveys across more 7 This paper uses data rom SHARE 2004 wave 1, release 2.0.1. SHARE data collection in 2004-2007 was primarily unded by the European Commission through its 5th and 6th ramework programs (project numbers QLK6-CT- 2001-00360; RII-CT- 2006-062193; CIT5-CT-2005-028857). Additional unding by the US National Institute on Aging (grant numbers U01 AG09740-13S2; P01 AG005842; P01 AG08291; P30 AG12815; Y1-AG-4553-01; OGHA 04-064; R21 AG025169) as well as by various national sources is grateully acknowledged (see http://www.share-project.org or a ull list o unding institutions). 8 Greece is not included in the analysis due to diiculties in merging with WVS data. More details on data issues are provided in appendix II. 9 The raw data consist o about 17,000 households, either couples or singles. We exclude households with nonresponding partners. 10 The survey also asks about participation in activities organized by religious organizations. However, in some countries, due to dierences in translation, the question was asked with reerence to participation in church services. Given the inconsistent way that this question was asked, we do not consider it in the list o the social activities. 12

than 60 countries that provide inormation about social norms and peoples belies. 11 Respondents are asked the ollowing question: Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted or that you need to be very careul in dealing with people? 1. `Most people can be trusted' 0. `Can't be too careul' In both SHARE and WVS we know the region o residence o respondents. Thus, we irst calculate region-level averages based on responses to the above trust indicator rom WVS and then assign the relevant average to every SHARE respondent who lives in the same region. In the same way we supplement SHARE data with inormation on regional GDP growth rates and participation in EU elections that we employ in a number o robustness checks. 12 It should be noted that the regional average trust is computed over the sample o all adults in WVS, and it is not restricted to those aged 50 and above. This is consistent with the contextual nature o our trust indicator: a more than 50 years old individual (represented in the SHARE sample) interacts with adults o any age in her region o residence. Thereore, merging the two datasets allows us to employ a trust indicator that is ully coherent with the notion o contextual trust discussed in Section 2. 13 The dierent nature o our trust and sociability indicators (contextual versus householdspeciic) implies a dierent interpretation o an assumed marginal increase in the underlying variables. As regards the ormer, the hypothetical experiment corresponds to moving an individual, keeping unchanged her characteristics, rom a region o given prevailing trust into another region with relatively higher trust. For sociability, the comparison is between an individual who is engaged in social activities and her non-social counterpart living in a region with the same prevailing trust. Our analysis ocuses on households decision to participate directly in the stock market. SHARE oers straight inormation on direct stock ownership that enables international comparisons, abstracting rom country dierences in the availability o inancial products that 11 We used the European and World Values Surveys our-wave integrated data ile, 1981-2004, v.20060423, 2006. Surveys designed and executed by the European Values Study Group and World Values Survey Association. File Producers: ASEP/JDS, Madrid, Spain and Tilburg University, Tilburg, the Netherlands. File Distributors: ASEP/JDS and GESIS, Cologne, Germany. 12 More details about the data sources and the construction o the trust measure can be ound in appendix II. 13 As a robustness check, we have experimented with regional trust averages computed across WVS respondents more than 40 and 50 years old and the results are qualitatively similar to those we report. 13

allow indirect investments in stocks. It also makes possible comparisons with GSZ who examine the association between average trust rates and the raction o individuals owning stocks directly across countries. SHARE asks households who own mutual unds whether they are mostly invested in stocks, bonds or split between the two. Based on this inormation we have constructed a proxy o indirect stockholding by classiying each mutual und holder as a stock owner. In section 6.2, apart rom our baseline indings on direct stockholding, we also discuss the quantitative implications o our trust and sociability indicators with respect to this broader orm o stockholding across various groups o households. Figure 1 reports ownership rates o directly held stocks by country. It is immediately evident that there is signiicant variation across Europe: more than one out o three Swedish and Danish households invest in stocks directly, while this raction goes down to 5% in Spain. Figure 2 illustrates country averages o sociability and generalized trust. The two measures display considerable heterogeneity across countries and there is not an obvious trend suggesting any systematic relationship between the two. Figure 3 uses a map to depict dierences in regional trust levels across Europe. Regions are divided into 6 classes: the light blue regions have an average trust below 20%, while in the darkest ones trust rates exceed 60% (each class in between covers a 10% range). Trust levels by region display a signiicant within-country variation. 14 5. Econometric Speciication We estimate the ollowing binary choice model which corresponds to a reduced orm speciication o model (8): y i x where y trust i ' 1 j 2 i v 1 i U( A) U( B), and v 0 otherwise i i i (11) ~ N (0,1) That is, y i is a dichotomous variable taking the value 1 i household i owns stocks (i.e. utility rom stock market participation, as described in section 3, is greater than utility in case o non participation) and 0 otherwise. We include under x i a rich array o demographic and pecuniary characteristics that will be discussed in detail later. The variables o interest are z i, a 14 Such heterogeneity has been justiied or Italy in the seminal work o Putnam, Leonardi and Nanetti (1993). 14

dummy showing engagement in social activities that we use as a proxy or the unknown i (i.e. the total number o peers who participate in the stock market) and trust j, that represents the raction o trusting individuals in the region o residence j o household i. As discussed, we construct a sociability indicator that is similar to the one employed by HKS. It should be noted that sociability is exogenous to stock market participation as long as we assume that a stockholder does not decide to engage in social activities in order to acquire inormation about the stock market. Given the type o activities we consider (voluntary work, participation in sport, social, political clubs or training courses) this seems a plausible assumption. 15 Still, one might argue that the sociability indicator partly relects the inluence o other traits like pessimism, attitudes towards risk, health or cognitive limitations that are associated with engagement in social activities and are also likely to aect the propensity to invest in stocks. First, SHARE data oer details on various household characteristics and attitudes that we incorporate in our estimation in order to rule out the possibility that our sociability indicator picks up the eect o these traits. As it will be discussed later, we take into account, apart rom standard demographic characteristics and resources, the inluence o depression, objective and subjective health indicators, as well as cognitive abilities. In addition, we veriy the robustness o our indings when an indicator o willingness to assume more than average inancial risk is taken into account. Second, a direct implication deriving rom the assumed inluence o sociability on stock market participation, is that the marginal eect o sociability should be higher in areas with widespread stockholding. This is the case given that a sociable household living in these areas is more likely to meet many acquaintances with useul inormation about stock investing, reducing eectively the participation costs that this household aces. At the other extreme, the estimated eect o sociability should be smaller in areas where only ew have invested in stocks, provided that a sociable prospective investor is quite unlikely to ind an inormative acquaintance in her social circle. Results rom our analysis, presented in section 6.2, oer empirical support to the 15 As HKS stress, even i inormation on was directly available, the inerence would be subject to the well-known relection problem (i.e. had to be drawn rom the estimated eect o the average participation o a given group on the participation choice o an individual belonging to this group) - see also Manski (1993). Instead, z i circumvents the issue o reverse causality, while it is natural to assume that an individual engaged in social activities is more likely to meet - other things equal - a larger number o people who participate in the stock market than her nonsociable counterpart. 15

above premise. As it is stressed by HKS this act strengthens the case that the sociability indicator picks up the real inluence o social interactions and not that o personal traits that have not been adequately accounted or. That is, i the sociability indicator mostly relects the inluence o such personal traits, there is not any a priori reason to expect a dierential eect o this indicator across areas with dierent prevalence o stockholding. As regards the indicator o trust, the recent work by Fehr (2009) has raised concerns about the causal role o trust on various economic outcomes. The author argues that sel-reported trust, as it is measured in survey data, is partly shaped by own belies about other people s trustworthiness which in turn have been inluenced by ormal and inormal institutions. More generally, prevailing trust in a country can be partly determined by interactions with the institutional environment. For example, policies introduced to promote transparency in a country s stock market may have contributed to an increase in an individual s trust and in general trust in the population. Given the obvious diiculties in inding valid instruments that will correlate with trust but not with economic outcomes, Fehr suggests that such instruments can be obtained through laboratory experiments. 16 Our measure or trust implicitly assumes that every individual residing in a given region is trust taker. That is, a change in her trusting behavior or in her belies about others trustworthiness cannot alter the overall trust level prevailing in this region. 17 Moreover, cross country dierences in average trust that are most likely related with country wide dierences in policies and institutions or in aggregate belies, will be absorbed by the country dummies in our model. Thus, in the light o the above arguments our measure o trust as it compares to those that have been broadly used (either individualspeciic at the micro level or country-speciic at the macro level) is less likely to suer rom endogeneity bias almost by construction. Furthermore, we perorm various robustness checks to ensure that our regional trust indicator does not incorrectly pick up eects that are due to regional dierences in development, access to inormal and ormal borrowing, banking environment, and use o internet services. 16 The author proposes to induce exogenously in one group optimistic belies and in another group pessimistic belies about other people s trustworthiness and subsequently examine the extent to which they result in divergent economic behavior. 17 The concept can be seen as similar to considering individual consumers as price takers. 16

We examine household participation in direct stockholding by estimating (11) by probit models. 18 Given that our measure o trust is regional invariant, the estimated standard errors are corrected or clustering at regional level (see Moulton, 1990). In addition, we take into account the act that missing values have been imputed in SHARE using a multiple imputation method. Hence, we perorm the estimation and compute standard errors corrected or clustering within each implicate, and then combine the estimates and standard errors across implicates using the rules described in Rubin (1987). The estimated coeicients rom binary choice models are not directly interpretable, thus we calculate and report marginal eects averaged across individuals using calibrated survey weights. All our speciications control, apart rom sociability and trust indicators, or a rich set o household demographics and measures o resources. More speciically, we take into account a broad set o demographics like age, gender, marital status, and the number o children. Given that bequest planning can aect portolio allocations we also condition on the sel-reported probability to leave a sizeable bequest. We take into account labor status by distinguishing among those working, retired, and unemployed. In addition, we allow or an independent role o resources including separate controls or net total wealth and income through an inverse hyperbolic sine transormation that allows or non-linear eects o these variables (see Burbidge, Magee and Robb, 1988). Controlling or resources is dictated both by theory, with its emphasis on cash on hand as a key determinant o asset investments, and by the need to avoid conounding the role o determinants o interest with that o wealth, when the latter is not controlled or in the regression. 19 Households with health problems are discouraged rom investing in stocks according to Rosen and Wu (2004). In order to take into account the eect o adverse health conditions we include as explanatory variables both a subjective (sel-reported health) and an objective (number o limitations in activities o daily living - ADL) health indicator. Christelis, Jappelli and Padula (2009) using SHARE data ound a signiicant role o cognitive abilities or stockholding. In our speciication we employ their cognitive indicator, namely the respondents 18 See Guiso, Haliassos and Jappelli (2002) or previous studies on household stock market participation and Campbell (2006) or a review on issues related to household inance. 19 In each speciication we exclude rom total net wealth the value o stocks in order to avoid endogeneity issues. 17

ability to recall words correctly out o a list that is read to them by the interviewer. On top o recall ability we control or depression as a measure o pessimism. 20 Finally, we include country dummies to capture country-speciic actors that are likely to aect stockholding, such as the level o inancial development, market transparency, the legal environment, as well as the dierences in companies deault risks. Country dummies will also capture dierences in the average levels o trust across countries that as it was discussed are most likely to be due to country dierences in the institutional environment. This implies that our trust indicator which measures dierences in the regional levels o trust represents a conservative estimate o the overall eect o trust on stockholding. Summary statistics and a detailed description o all variables used in the empirical analysis are presented in Tables AII.1 and AII.2 in appendix II. 6. Empirical results In what ollows we irst discuss empirical results rom regressions on the ull sample at hand as well as rom a series o robustness checks that examine the sensitivity o our baseline indings. Next we examine the relative contribution o generalized trust and sociability to stockholding across countries with dierent participation rates and households with dierent wealth holdings. 6.1. The Eects o trust and sociability on stock market participation 6.1.1. Generalized trust and sociability We model the probability o direct stocks investments as a unction o a broad set o household socioeconomic characteristics and o combinations o our generalized trust and sociability indicators. Table 1 presents average marginal eects and their standard errors rom a series o probit regressions. In speciication 1 we control or trust without taking into account the inluence o sociability and vice versa in speciication 2. In speciication 3 we control or both, 20 Characteristics in the case o couples represent a combination o the inormation rom the two partners. In particular we use average age, worse reported health status, total number o limitations in daily activities and the maximum o: educational level, recall abilities and depression. Furthermore, the household is determined to be in the labor orce i any o the two partners is working. 18

while in speciication 4 marginal eects have been computed rom a model that includes an interaction term between trust and sociability. 21 Marginal eects rom the above speciications suggest an independent, economically important, and precisely estimated role or trust and sociability. More social households are 3.1 percentage points (pp) more likely to invest in stocks and this eect remains unchanged when regional trust is taken into account (it slightly increases to 3.6 pp when interactions with trust are allowed). 22 On the other hand, living in a region where a higher raction o people trust (we assume a 15 pp increase in regional trust which roughly corresponds to one standard deviation o this variable) is associated with a 2.1 pp increase in the probability to own stocks directly. The above eects are net o various demographics, household resources, and country wide dierences and are economically important given that the average participation rate in our sample does not exceed 13%. Based on speciication 4 that allows or an interaction between our trust and sociability indicators we have also calculated the marginal eect o sociability within low and high trust regions. 23 In low trust regions sociability increases by 5.1 pp (s.e..01) the probability to invest in stocks, while in high trust regions by 3.4 pp (s.e..007). This suggests that sociability can partly balance the negative eects on stockholding that are associated with living in a low trust region. Yet, the relative contribution o trust and sociability will be examined in detail in the next section where we investigate the stockholding choices across speciic groups o countries and households. The estimated eects o other covariates (education, health, inancial resources, recall ability) display the expected signs and are in line with indings rom existing literature on determinants o stockholding behavior. With reerence to country dummies, estimated marginal eects are sizeable and consistent with patterns o stockholding rates across countries suggested by the raw statistics. 24 In Table 2 we present marginal eects rom various probit regressions in order to examine the sensitivity o our indings on trust and sociability. To ease comparisons 21 Brambor, Clark and Golder (2005) point to requent problems in empirical literature due to misspeciication o models that include interaction terms and to the calculation o meaningless marginal eects. We ollow their approach in calculating marginal eects or the two indicators o interest. 22 The sample correlation o the two indicators is roughly 0.2. 23 We deine as low (high) trust regions those where the raction o people who trust the others is below (above) 24% (37%). These roughly correspond to the bottom and the top quartile o the distribution o regional trust rates. 24 Country marginal eects are in comparison to Germany. 19