A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax

Similar documents
THE BOADWAY PARADOX REVISITED

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

INDIVIDUAL AND HOUSEHOLD WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR PUBLIC GOODS JOHN QUIGGIN

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring Lecture notes 03 Applications of Revealed Preferences

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

ECONOMICS. Paper 3: Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 5: Applications of Indifference curve

A note on how to undertake a cost-benefit analysis in monetary and environmental units

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Optimal education policies and comparative advantage

FISCAL FEDERALISM WITH A SINGLE INSTRUMENT TO FINANCE GOVERNMENT. Carlos Maravall Rodríguez 1

Midterm #1 EconS 527 Wednesday, September 28th, 2016 ANSWER KEY

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Midterm Exam No. 2 - Answers. July 30, 2003

Winners and Losers from Price-Level Volatility: Money Taxation and Information Frictions

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

Discussion Paper Series. Short Sales, Destruction of Resources, Welfare. Nikos Kokonas and Herakles Polemarchakis

Utility Maximization and Choice

Chapter 33: Public Goods

Introductory Economics of Taxation. Lecture 1: The definition of taxes, types of taxes and tax rules, types of progressivity of taxes

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Lecture 1: Tax avoidance and excess burden

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

UTILITY THEORY AND WELFARE ECONOMICS

Envy-free and efficient minimal rights: recursive. no-envy

Income Tax Evasion and the Penalty Structure. Abstract

Lectures on Externalities

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Hedonic Equilibrium. December 1, 2011

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Chapter 7 Economic Growth and International Trade

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Supplementary Material to: Peer Effects, Teacher Incentives, and the Impact of Tracking: Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation in Kenya

Expenditure minimization

When Was Coase Right?

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Professor Bee Roberts. Economics 302 Practice Exam. Part I: Multiple Choice (14 questions)

Benefit-Cost Analysis: Introduction and Overview

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

Optimal Progressivity

Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis

Final Exam Economic 210A, Fall 2009 Answer any 7 questions.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Course Handouts - Introduction ECON 8704 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS. Jan Werner. University of Minnesota

Do Government Subsidies Increase the Private Supply of Public Goods?

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Lecture 15 - General Equilibrium with Production

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Chapter 2: Gains from Trade. August 14, 2008

ECON Micro Foundations

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1. Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301. General Equilibrium V: Public Goods

An Enhancement of Modern Free Trade Area Theory. Earl L. Grinols Peri Silva. October 2003

Nonsubstitution Theorems for a Small Trading Country

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 3 Solutions

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

This assignment is due on Tuesday, September 15, at the beginning of class (or sooner).

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

Problems. units of good b. Consumers consume a. The new budget line is depicted in the figure below. The economy continues to produce at point ( a1, b

GE in production economies

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Comparative statics of monopoly pricing

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

Full file at Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach (with and without Calculus) Chapter 2

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Transcription:

A simple proof of the efficiency of the poll tax Michael Smart Department of Economics University of Toronto June 30, 1998 Abstract This note reviews the problems inherent in using the sum of compensating variations to measure the efficiency effects of tax reforms. Contrary to a recently published assertion, excise taxation never constitutes a potential Pareto improvement over poll taxation, even if the aggregate compensating variation is positive. Keywords: willingness-to-pay, potential Pareto improvement, poll tax JEL Classification: H21 Forthcoming, Journal of Public Economics. 140 St. George St.,Toronto ON M5S 3G6 Canada, e-mail: msmart@chass.utoronto.ca 1

1 Introduction In tax policy analysis, it is common to use the aggregate compensating variation to measure the efficiency effects of a proposed reform. The typical justification for this procedure is that, when the sum of consumers willingnesses to pay (i.e. compensating variations) is positive, then winners could compensate losers for the reform, and a potential Pareto improvement (ppi) exists. This argument is intuitively appealing, but unfortunately it is fallacious. The problem was first pointed out by Boadway (1974), who established that the sum of compensating variations for a move between two Pareto-efficient allocations is non-negative, and is generally positive. Thus the aggregate compensating variation cannot serve as a consistent index of efficiency change. While this result has long been established, it has had little impact on the practice of economic policy analysis. In one recent contribution, for example, Peck (1998) asserts that imposition of an excise tax may constitute a potential Pareto improvement over an equal-yield uniform lump-sum tax (or poll tax). Professor Peck argues that, when the sum of taxpayers compensating variations for a movement to excise taxation is positive, those who prefer the excise tax can compensate those who prefer the uniform lump-sum tax. Therefore imposing an equal yield lump-sum tax in place of an excise tax on an entire economy may actually reduce aggregate welfare. (Peck, 1998, p. 243) Since an allocation with a lump-sum tax is Pareto efficient, whereas an allocation with an excise tax generally is not, it would be surprising indeed if winners could compensate losers for a move to the latter. In this note, I show that the result is merely an instance of the difficulties in using the sum of compensating variations for policy evaluation, which says nothing about the inefficiency of poll taxes. The results I present are not new indeed most are simple corollaries of results found in Blackorby and Donaldson (1990), for example but are often overlooked in policy analysis. Analogous to the Boadway paradox, a movement from an efficient to an inefficient allocation, as in the excise tax case, can also lead to a positive aggregate compensating variation, as long as the distortion in demands is not too great. In what follows I show that, if preferences are convex, imposition of an equal-yield excise tax never constitutes a true potential Pareto improvement (ppi) over lump-sum taxation. That is, compensation for a move to excise taxation is never possible, and the Hicks Kaldor compensation test fails. If Scitovsky indifference curves cross and compensation is restricted to transfers of produced commodities rather than endowments, however, then the 2

converse may also hold. Lump-sum taxation need not constitute a ppi over excise taxation, and winners could not compensate losers for a move in the opposite direction. This possibility is, however, independent of the sign of the sum of compensating variations for the policy change. 2 Results Consider an economy consisting of two commodities, x and z, and H consumers. Commodities are produced under constant returns to scale at exogenous producer prices (p, 1). Consumer i has exogenous lump-sum income y i, measured in units of the numeraire, and preferences for consumption represented by a continuous, monotone, quasi-concave utility function U i (x i, z i ). If the consumer prices of (x, z) are (q, 1), the associated indirect utility and expenditure functions are denoted V i (q, y i ) and E i (q, u i ). Let Y = i yi be aggregate income and (X, Z) = ( i xi, i zi ) be aggregate demands. The government revenue requirement is R units of the numeraire, to be raised through imposition of an excise tax on x at rate t, or a uniform lump-sum tax T = R/H on all consumers. Let (X E, Z E ) denote aggregate demands when the excise tax is imposed, and (X L, Z L ) denote aggregate demands under the lump-sum tax. If the allocations are feasible given revenue requirements, then px i + Z i = Y R (i = E, L). (1) Consider a move from lump-sum taxation to excise taxation. An consumer s compensating variation c i for the change is the amount of income the consumer would be willing to pay to have the change implemented; thus 1 or, letting u i E = V i (p + t, y i ), V i (p + t, y i c i ) = V i (p, y i T ) u i L, c i = y i E i (p + t, u i L) = E i (p + t, u i E) E i (p + t, u i L). (2) When c A = i ci > 0, the net amount consumers would pay to move to excise taxation is positive, suggesting that aggregate consumer surplus has been generated by the switch. Peck (1998) demonstrates that c A > 0 is 1 In Peck (1998), this defines c i. I have followed most other authors in reversing the sign of the measure. 3

indeed possible and concludes that, in such cases, excise taxation constitutes a ppi over lump-sum taxation. But the existence of aggregate consumer surplus for the change does not imply that winners could actually provide lump-sum compensation to losers and generate a Pareto improvement. To see this, for any vector of utilities u = (u 1,..., u H ) define the Scitovsky set B(u) as the set of aggregate consumption vectors which can be distributed to taxpayers in a way which yields each one a utility level at least as great as his or her utility level in u. Formally, { ( B(u) = x i, } z i) : U i (x i, z i ) u i, i = 1,..., H. (3) i i Note that B(u) is merely the set summation of individual no-worse-than sets and so is convex. Let E(q, u) = min{qx + Z : (X, Z) B(u)} be the support function for B(u). Note that E(q, u) = i Ei (q, u i ). The allocation (x E, z E ) is a potential Pareto improvement over the allocation (x L, z L ) if it possible to construct lump-sum transfers of commodities among taxpayers such that all are at least as well off after the transfers as at (x L, z L ), and at least one taxpayer is strictly better off. Equivalently, excise taxation constitutes a ppi over lump-sum taxation if (X E, Z E ) int B(u L ). It is easy to see, however, that this can never be the case. 2 Proposition 1 An allocation with excise taxation of good x cannot constitute a potential Pareto improvement of an allocation with an equal-yield poll tax. Proof. Since E(p, u L ) = px L + Z L = Y R, and B(u L ) is a convex set, the boundary of the feasible set {( X, Z) : p X + Z = Y R} is a supporting hyperplane for B(u L ) at (X L, Z L ). Thus (X E, Z E ) int B(u L ) = px E + Z E > Y R which contradicts the feasibility condition (1) for (X E, Z E ). (PLACE FIGURE 1 ABOUT HERE.) 2 The following argument can be applied without change to analyze excise taxation of multiple commodities. 4

A simple, graphical version of the argument can be seen by inspecting Fig. 1. The boundary of B(u L ) is tangent to the production possibility frontier, which is labelled AY R, at the aggregate demand vector (X L, Z L ), which is labelled L. If (X E, Z E ) is feasible given the revenue requirement R, it must also lie on this line. Hence (X E, Z E ) cannot lie on the interior of B(u L ). Nevertheless, the sum of compensating variations for the change may be positive. Summing compensating variations in (2) gives c A = Y E(p + t, u L ) = E(p + t, u E ) E(p + t, u L ) (4) In Fig. 1, c A is therefore the horizontal distance from the actual budget line for the excise tax to the line with slope 1/(p + t) which is tangent to the boundary of B(u L ) at point C. In the figure, the aggregate demand vector (X E, Z E ), which is labelled E, has been drawn such that c A > 0, despite the fact that no ppi exists for a move to excise taxation. The difficulty with the measure is that, if the income transfers envisaged were actually paid, then income effects would lead to a change in government revenue that would render the allocation infeasible. Since E(p, u L ) = Y R, (4) can be expressed as c A = E(p, u L ) E(p + t, u L ) + R = [E(p, u L ) E(p + t, u L ) + tx(p + t, u L )] + t [X(p + t, u E ) X(p + t, u L )]. (5) Since E is concave in price and E q (p + t, u L ) = X(p + t, u L ), the first term in brackets in (5) is non-positive, a measure of the distortionary effect of excise taxation. The second term in brackets may be positive, leading to c A > 0, if income effects from compensation induce a sufficiently large fall in aggregate demand for the taxed commodity. While lump-sum compensation for a move to excise taxation is never possible, one may ask conversely whether, beginning from the excise tax allocation, winners may compensate losers for a move to the poll tax. 3 It is perhaps surprising to note that this need not be the case. If the boundaries of the Scitovsky sets for the two allocations intersect, then it is possible that (X L, Z L ) B(u E ), and compensation for a move from excise to poll taxation is infeasible, despite the fact that the latter allocation is Pareto efficient and the former is not. Does the sign of c A therefore indicate whether lump-sum 3 This is the version of the compensation test proposed by Hicks, in contrast to the usual version, associated with Kaldor. See Boadway and Bruce (1984) for a discussion. 5

taxation is a ppi over excise taxation? The answer again is no. Observe that c A is minus the sum of equivalent variations for a change from excise to lumpsum taxation. Blackorby and Donaldson (1990) have demonstrated that a negative aggregate equivalent variation is neither necessary nor sufficient for a true potential Pareto improvement. 4 An alternative explanation for the failure of the sum of compensating variations to accord with the compensation principle is that, given (4), c A is a sum of money metrics for individual utility changes, measured at the distorted price p+t. It is then perhaps not surprising that c A overweights utilities at the distorted allocation u E, and indicates a potential efficiency gain where none exists. One might therefore expect that the sum of equivalent variations, which weights utility changes by undistorted prices, is an exact index for ppis in both directions. But this is also not the case. The equivalent variation e i of taxpayer i for a move to excise taxation solves V i (p + t, y i ) = u i E = V i (p, y i T + e i ), so that e A = i e i = E(p, u E ) E(p, u L ). (6) This leads to the following result. Proposition 2 The aggregate equivalent variation for a move to excess taxation is non-positive, regardless of whether poll taxation constitutes a ppi over excise taxation. Proof. Using the feasibility condition (1), (6) can be expressed as e A = E(p, u E ) E(p + t, u E ) + tx E. (7) Since E(q, u) is concave in q and E q (p + t, u E ) = X E, it follows e A 0. Finally, if the income effects of the hypothetical transfers are restricted, then these anomalies cannot arise. It is clear from Fig. 1 that if the two Scitovsky indifference curves do not cross then c A 0. Similarly, Peck (1998) notes that, when taxpayers preferences are identical and homothetic, c A 0. More generally, suppose that preferences satisfy E i (q, u i ) = f(q)φ i (u i ) + g i (q) (8) 4 In making this argument, I have restricted attention to compensation effected by lump-sum transfers of the aggregate production vector (X L, Z L). Lump-sum taxation always constitutes a ppi if endowments rather than commodities are redistributed, and the aggregate production vector moves elsewhere on the production possibility frontier. But such compensation would be equivalent to imposing a personalized lump-sum tax system rather than a poll tax, which is another issue entirely. 6

so that all consumers have parallel, linear Engel curves. Gorman (1955) showed that (8) is necessary and sufficient for Scitovsky indifference curves never to cross and hence, given the foregoing discussion, is sufficient for c A 0. This may be verified directly by noting that under (8), using (4) and (6), c A = f(p + t) i ( φ i (u i E) φ i (u i L) ) = f(p + t) e A 0. f(p) This establishes the following. Proposition 3 If all consumers have parallel, linear Engel curves then c A 0. When preferences have the Gorman form (8), lump-sum redistributions leave aggregate demand for the taxed commodity unchanged. In this case, the allocation with poll taxation is unambiguously a ppi over the allocation with excise taxation (viz. both the Hicks and Kaldor criteria are satisfied), and use of c A to measure the efficiency gain gives sensible results. References [Blackorby and Donaldson(1990)] Blackorby, C. and D. Donaldson, 1990, A review article: The case against the use of the sum of compensating variations in cost benefit analysis, Canadian Journal of Economics 23, 471 494. [Boadway(1974)] Boadway, R. W., 1974, The welfare foundations of cost benefit analysis, Economic Journal 84, 426 439. [Boadway and Bruce(1984)] Boadway, R. W. and N. Bruce, 1984, Welfare Economics (Blackwell, Oxford). [Gorman(1955)] Gorman, W., 1955, The intransitivity of certain criteria used in welfare economics, Oxford Economic Papers 7, 25 35. [Peck(1998)] Peck, R. M., 1998, The inefficiency of the poll tax, Journal of Public Economics 67, 241 252. 7

X A B(u ) L L E C Y-R Y Z Figure 1: No potential Pareto improvements from the lump-sum tax. 8