Thinking Outside the Trade Treaty Box Remarks by Scott Sinclair made to the CLC Industrial Policy Conference September 22, 2004

Similar documents
Event 1. Module 3. Key Elements of IIAs and their impact on domestic reform Session Two: The rules of the game on investment incentives

National Interest Analysis

Investment Liberalization: Some Key Elements and Issues in Today s Negotiating Context

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Preview. Chapter 10. The Political Economy of Trade Policy: international negotiations. International Negotiations of Trade Policy

The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS): objectives, coverage and disciplines

Investment and Sustainable Development: Developing Country Choices for a Better Future

Article 2. National Treatment and Quantitative Restrictions

Trade and Currency. Can WTO Rules Have a Role?

Letter from CELA page 2

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

The Kyoto Protocol and the WTO Seminar Note

Delegations will find attached the partially declassified version of the above-mentioned document.

PROTOCOL ON THE ACCESSION OF THE PEOPLE'S REPUBLIC OF ClDNA. Preamble

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES

Bilateral Agreements in EU trade policy

1of 23. Learning Objectives

Making Sense of the CETA

The Estey Centre Journal of. International Law. and Trade Policy. Technical Annex

Appendix C Border Adjustments under the National Retail Sales Tax or Corporate Activity Tax

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION. ( ) Working Group on the Relationship between Trade and Investment

World Trade Organization: Its Genesis and Functioning. Shashank Priya Professor Centre for WTO Studies Indian Institute of Foreign Trade

NAFTA's Prospects and Preserving its Benefits Views from the US, Mexico and Canada. January

TRADE POLICY REVIEW OF MALAYSIA JULY GATT Council's Evaluation

Anti-dumping and Subsidy Issues in Agricultural Trade. Presentation by G. Tereposky Thomas & Partners CATPRN Workshop 6 March 2005

SYSTEMIC ISSUES IN INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT AGREEMENTS (IIAs)

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES

2019 USCIB Trade and Investment Agenda

Character of the GATS

The Canada-European Union Comprehensive Economic and Trade Agreement (CETA)

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 15 May 1996 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques

ANNEX. to the. Recommendation for a Council Decision. authorising the opening of negotiations for a Free Trade Agreement with New Zealand

Is the EU a Responsible trade partner?

ICC recommendations for completing the Doha Round. Prepared by the Commission on Trade and Investment Policy

1. OVERVIEW OF RULES. (1) Rules of Origin

Economic Impact of Canada s Participation in the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership

CHAPTER 17 EXCEPTIONS

Elements of a Trade and Climate Code

CETA s Legal and Political Implications for the TTIP. David A. Gantz Samuel M. Fegtly Professor

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Opening remarks: Discussion on Investment in TTIP

Agreement on Trade-Related Investment Measures

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific

TRADE-RELATED INVESTMENT MEASURES

INT L TRADE LAW: DOHA & SERVICES LIBERALIZATION. Prof David K. Linnan USC LAW # 665 Unit Ten

Application: International Trade

5 Implications of WTO s agreement for logistics FTZs 29

MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

1.5 The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)

RESEARCH Paper. The Most Favoured-Nation provision in the EC/EAC Economic Partnership Agreement and its implications: Agriculture and Development

NATIONAL TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

GATT Obligations: -Shailja Singh Assistant Professor Centre for WTO Studies, New Delhi

GATT Obligations: Article I (MFN), II (Bound Rates), III (National Treatment), XI (QRs), XX (Exceptions) and XXIV (FTAs) -Shailja Singh

ARE THERE SPECIAL RISKS FROM TRADE AND FINANCE IN THE RECESSION?

The Rise Of Regionalism In The Multilateral System And Features Of Preferential Trade Agreements In Asia And The Pacific

How to Methodically Research WTO Law

Chapter 2 The General Agreement on Trade in Services

How CETA Will Benefit the

GATT Council's Evaluation

NAFTA Negotiations. Business Council of Canada Submission

Border Measures: Legal Issues in International Trade

World Trade Law. Text, Materials and Commentary. Simon Lester and Bryan Mercurio with Arwel Davies and Kara Leitner

LOCAL CONTENT. Kazakhstan- Mining & Petroleum

T h e l e g a l i t y o f t h e p r o p o s e d U. S. b o r d e r a d j u s t m e n t t a x " u n d e r W T O l a w

Dr. Nikolaos Theodorakis - Lecturer and Fellow, University of Oxford

An Analysis of "Buy America" Provisions In ADF Group Inc. v. United States under Chapter 11 of the NAFTA. Rahna Epting, IELP Law Clerk August 25, 2005

Introduction to the GATS

Currency Manipulation: The IMF and WTO

LOCAL CONTENT. Tanzania - Petroleum

CARIBBEAN REGIONAL NEGOTIATING MACHINERY SPECIAL AND DIFFERENTIAL TREATMENT PROVISIONS IN THE CARIFORUM-EC ECONOMIC PARTNERSHIP AGREEMENT

international law of contemporary media session 7: the law of the world trade organization (part 2)

Some Ways Forward with Trade Barriers

CHAPTER 2 NATIONAL TREATMENT AND MARKET ACCESS FOR GOODS ARTICLE 2.1. Objective

The Case Against More Corporate Tax Cuts By Andrew Jackson

CARIBBEAN REGIONAL NEGOTIATING MACHINERY THE TREATMENT OF PROFESSIONAL SERVICES IN THE EPA

10 Commitments China made when it joined the WTO and has not respected

Brussels, 28 February 2003 Ref. 116/03 OECD ; Negotiation on Shipbuilding - Definition of Support Measures

PART I CHAPTER 1 MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

OCR Economics A-level

TAXATION AND TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER: KEY ISSUES

Draft Cancun Ministerial Text

MOST-FAVOURED-NATION TREATMENT PRINCIPLE

The euro: Its economic implications and its lessons for Canada

ILLUSTRATIVE MOCK EXAMPLES

Mr Thiessen discusses the euro: its economic implications and its lessons for Canada

The EU s approach to Free Trade Agreements Investment

A. Provisions Relating to Tariff Negotiations

TiSA: Analysis of the EU s Dispute Settlement text July 2016

FROM A CANADIAN PERSPECTIVE. 61 st Annual EDCO Conference Toronto February 7, 2018

Why and What S & D Treatment for LDCs in the WTO?

Uruguay Round. The GATT. A Negotiating History ( ) KLUWER LAW INTERNATIONAL TERENCE P. STEWART, EDITOR VOLUME IV: THE END GAME (PART I)

European Parliament resolution of 6 April 2011 on the future European international investment policy (2010/2203(INI))

Unit 4: Global Economic Concepts

No. WP/ECO/DTL/08/01. Regional Trade Arrangements, Generalized System of Preferences and Dispute Settlement in the WTO.

CONSULTATION ON TRADE NEGOTIATIONS WITH THE UNITED STATES

CONVENTION ESTABLISHING THE EUROPEAN FREE TRADE ASSOCIATION. Consolidated version, last amended on 20 September 2010

THE GENERAL AGREEMENT

Comments in Response to Executive Order Regarding Trade Agreements Violations and Abuses Docket No. USTR

AGREEMENT BETWEEN THE EUROPEAN ECONOMIC COMMUNITY AND TUNISIA. Draft Report of the Working Party

Transcription:

Volume 5 Number 3 November 2004 Thinking Outside the Trade Treaty Box Remarks by Scott Sinclair made to the CLC Industrial Policy Conference September 22, 2004 While trade treaties have limited many of the traditional tools of industrial and economic development policy, there is still room for manoeuvre. Canadians should take advantage of existing flexibilities and push the boundaries where it is in our interest (just as others do). The old tools of Canadian industrial strategy tariff exemptions linked to various performance conditions are no longer viable within today s trade and investment treaty strictures. The June 2000 WTO Auto Pact ruling underlined this and was certainly not an encouraging decision for these who favour more active Canadian industrial policies. 1 Nonetheless, the underlying goals of successful industrial strategies such as the Auto Pact to encourage investment and to achieve employment, industrial and economic benefits within Canada can arguably still be pursued through a mix of infrastructure, subsidy and other initiatives. I want to emphasise that more active economic development policies do not mean policies designed to restrict trade. It means policies designed (like the Auto Pact) both to encourage trade and investment and to ensure that Canadian workers and communities share equitably in the benefits of increased trade and integrated production. I also want to caution that while my focus today is on flexibility, that there are key aspects of the latest generation of so-called trade treaties that are unjustifiable and need to be changed or discarded. Moreover, trade treaty obligations do not stand still. Existing flexibilities can disappear in the next round of negotiations and sometimes even without negotiations. 2 Infrastructure Support for hard infrastructure (such as roads, rail, mass transit, ports, power, and water and sewer systems) is vital for the economy (including any form of manufacturing) and, if generally available, should not pose a problem under trade treaties. That is, so long as subsidies for public investment in infrastructure are based on objective criteria or conditions governing eligibility, eligibility is automatic, and the criteria and conditions are strictly adhered to, they should be trade-treaty consistent. 3 Recent studies from Statistics Canada show a big economic payoff for every dollar invested in hard public infrastructure (an estimated 17 per cent per year benefit to the business sector). 4 Public provision of social infrastructure (such as training, education, health care and childcare) can also result in increased productivity and significant competitive advantages. Savings from public health insurance, in the auto sector for example, amount to several dollars per hour of labour worked for employers otherwise faced with the cost of equivalent private health insurance. 5 national office bureau national 410 75 rue Albert Street Ottawa, ON K1P 5E7 tel: 613-563-1341 fax: 613-233-1458 info@policyalternatives.ca www.policyalternatives.ca

The most recent generation of trade treaties have intruded into many non-trade areas. One thrust has been towards commercialization of public and not-for-profit services. For example, both NAFTA s investment chapter and the GATS codify (in different ways) the objectionable idea that foreign commercial service exporters and investors should be compensated when public services are created or expanded. There is a clear risk that this and certain other aspects of trade treaties (NAFTA s investment chapter, intellectual property rules, and the GATS) could erode existing public services and interfere with their evolution. This could, among other negative consequences, impose significant costs on employers and undermine the attractiveness of Canada as a site for new investment, as the Canadian Autoworkers and the Big Three automakers pointed out in a joint letter on publicly funded health care. 6 This is an aspect of the new trade treaty agenda that needs to be beaten back. In the meantime, Canadians should not be deterred from enhancing public services by the prospect of trade treaty challenges. 7 As the Romanow Report concluded in its consideration of trade treaty obstacles to medicare expansion: Rather than conclude, then, that Canada is hemmed in to the current [trade treaty] system and cannot change, the more reasonable conclusion is that if we want to expand the range of services in the public system, it is better to do it now while there still is very little foreign presence in health care in Canada and the potential costs of compensation are low. 8 Subsidies, grants and other advantages One obvious option if Canada wants to encourage manufacturing investment is to provide subsidies (in one form or another.) I want to address whether, from a trade treaty perspective, Canadian governments can still attach legally enforceable conditions to ensure that public subsidies result in demonstrable employment, industrial and other benefits to Canadians. In fact, the capability to demonstrate such benefits is probably essential to gaining public support for significant spending initiatives in the first place. There are certain subsidy practices that trade treaties clearly prohibit. Most notably, the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (the SCM Agreement) bans subsidies contingent on export performance (Article 3.1(a)) or on the use of domestic goods over imported goods (Article 3.1(b)). But, arguably, subsidies or investment incentives can still be linked (at a minimum) to legally enforceable commitments to create jobs in Canada (or to achieve Canadian value-added targets through direct labour costs). For example, to qualify for support, an investor would have to 1) have a manufacturing presence in Canada and 2) a company s direct labour costs would have to meet or exceed a certain proportion of its sales (or economic activity) in Canada. Such incentives would reward investors who create jobs in Canada commensurate with their sales here. A careful reading of the WTO Auto Pact decision supports that such a policy would very likely be consistent with the WTO SCM agreement. It should be pointed out that the non-discrimination rules of both the GATT and the NAFTA do not apply to subsidies and grants (see, for example, GATT Article III:8(b) and NAFTA Articles 1108.7(b) and 1201.2(d)). Governments remain free to give preference to Canadian firms or firms located in Canada when they provide subsidies. 9 Without going into too much detail, certain GATS issues also need to be flagged. The GATS nondiscrimination rules, unlike those in the NAFTA and the GATT, do apply to subsidies in service sectors that Canada has committed (there are certain exemptions in Canada s GATS schedule that preserve flesibility for example regarding R&D subsidies). Obviously any future mode 4 (temporary movement of natural persons ) commitments, for example applying to the skilled trades, would undermine incentive programs linked to employment creation in Canada. 2

There is a need for a cautious approach to the GATS and particularly to negotiations to deepen Canadian GATS commitments. (Remember that the WTO ruled that the Auto Pact violated the GATS in addition to the WTO rules on goods.) But the GATS would not, at this point, frustrate incentives linked to direct labour costs. 10 To sum up, it is still possible to attach legally enforceable conditions to invest and to create employment within Canada to grants and subsidies, and to link eligibility to overall sales in Canada. This could be a component of new auto-pact-type sectoral policies. Other elements for example, support for research and development performed in Canada could complement it. Natural resource policies In certain sectors there is a disconnect between the black-letter law of trade agreements and the way business is actually done. This is especially true in the resource sector. A maximal interpretation of the NAFTA investment chapter would prohibit attaching most types of conditions (e.g. technology transfer, local processing, local purchasing) to resource licensing and approvals. 11 The NAFTA even prohibits governments from attaching performance requirements to projects by domestic investors and those from non- NAFTA countries. The reality is rather different. Most natural resources in Canada are publicly owned. If governments are not satisfied with the economic spin-offs or the environmental sustainability of a resource development, then it likely won t proceed. Competent governments choose the investment proposal that provides the greatest economic benefits and least environmental costs. Most investors in the resource sector, understanding this, shape their proposals accordingly. There is a lot of room for negotiation, and leverage on both sides whatever the letter of trade law says. While NAFTA disallows export taxes, and enforces proportional sharing with the U.S. during shortages, governments still retain the latitude to set royalties. Royalties from non-renewable energy reserves, for example, could be an important source of revenues to fund conservation and renewable energy strategies. (I d like to commend the CLC for the leadership it has shown in strongly supporting Canada s implementation of the Kyoto Protocol. The widespread public desire for a transition to a greener industrial strategy is perhaps the most convincing argument to rally popular support for significant public investment in a more active economic development strategy.) There is little doubt that unbalanced provisions such as those in the NAFTA investment chapter increase corporations bargaining leverage in the resource sector. But communities and governments still have some cards of their own to play. In my view, international trade rules that clash so clearly with accepted practice, public expectations, and democratic accountability are not sustainable. Government procurement The majority of government procurement in Canada is not covered by international trade agreements. For now, neither the NAFTA nor the WTO procurement rules apply to provincial or local government purchasing. The U.S. makes extensive use of Buy America provisions and small-business and minority setasides (not to mention national security exemptions). It was careful to exempt these programs from trade treaties and continues to use them at the federal and state levels. Canadian governments, by contrast, have largely renounced the use of government procurement as an economic development tool. But this has happened unilaterally, through the non-binding Agreement on Internal Trade (AIT), not directly as a result of international trade rules. 3

In my opinion, one reason the federal government has pushed the AIT is because it wants to use provincial and local purchasing as a bargaining chip to persuade the U.S. to give up its preferential procurement policies. But the U.S. has shown little interest in this and, if anything, state and federal governments are expanding the use of active procurement programs, which they believe are successful economic development tools. Perhaps Canadian governments should consider following the U.S. example by making more creative use of procurement for economic development purposes. Conclusion This presentation has focussed on the policy space that still exists, even in the current trade treaty context, for more targetted policies to encourage economic development and job creation. Again, I want to stress that labour needs to continue to take an active role to prevent ongoing trade negotiations such as the WTO Doha round from further shrinking this policy space for alternatives. It s undoubtedly true that Canada s future lies in its ability to attract high-quality investment and to succeed globally in the knowledge-based and services economy. But it does not follow that every new trade rule concocted by trade lawyers, corporate lobbyists, and government negotiators will serve Canadian interests. John Crosbie may still not have read the text of the Canada-U.S. FTA, but the terms of so-called trade treaties have come a long way in scope and complexity since the mid-1980s and the devil is in the details. Excessive intellectual property protection can hamper economic innovation, while denying the needy life-saving drugs. Generating wealth to expand public services (at home and abroad) should be a goal of greater international trade, but instead trade treaties such as the GATS throw up obstacles to the creation and expansion of public services. NAFTA s investor-state procedures and copycat provisions in bilateral investment treaties have become tools for foreign corporations to attack a wide range of public interest measures. Trade and investment treaties have pushed too far into non-trade areas, becoming external constitutions that privilege commercial over other legitimate interests. They need to be scaled back. For this to occur, and for economic development policy space to be preserved and enhanced, Canada s trade policy needs to change. The current global conjuncture is favourable to efforts to rebalance Canada s foreign economic policy and realign our strategic alliances. There is strong interest in emerging industrial and developing economies in preserving policy space for heterodox economic and industrial policies. There is also support in some quarters (in the north and the south) for more fully protecting the ability to preserve and expand public services. There are exciting international initiatives to promote and protect cultural diversity in the face of commercialising pressures. There is a genuine opportunity for Canadians, and the labour movement, to take a leadership role in a new progressive internationalism that acknowledges Canada s interests in global trade, but not to the exclusion of other values and interests. My presentation has tried to suggest ways to take advantage of existing policy flexibilities, to contest certain trade treaty limits, and to encourage a new foreign economic policy that aims at achieving more balanced rules and greater policy space. I hope that this conference can help restore a sense that Canadians and their governments can do more to shape our economic destiny, even in the context of globalization and trade treaties. It is vital that Canadians, and Canadian policy-makers, begin to think outside the trade treaty box. Scott Sinclair is a Senior Research Fellow with the CCPA. 4

Endnotes 1 But as Canadian tariff rates fell in the post-war era, the effectiveness of import duty exemptions as an investment incentive was already diminishing even before the WTO Auto Pact decision declared them inconsistent with Canada s WTO obligations. 2 For example, the green light category of nonactionable regional development and environmental subsidies, negotiated during the Uruguay round, was designed to expire automatically after 5 years unless the WTO subsidies committee agreed to continue it. The U.S. opposed its continuation and the green light category expired after the failed Seattle Ministerial. 3 See Article 2 of the WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures which sets out the criteria for determining if a subsidy is generally available or specific. 4 CLC, Economy, Winter 2003-4. Statistics Canada studies available at www.statscan.ca. 5 Publicly funded health care thus accounts for a significant portion of Canada s overall labour cost advantage in auto assembly, versus the U.S., which in turn has been a significant factor in maintaining and attracting new auto investment to Canada. CAW, General Motors, Ford, Daimler Chrysler, Joint Letter on Publicly Funded Health Care, September 2002, available at http://www.caw.ca/ campaigns&issues/ongoingcampaigns/ save_medicare.asp. 6 Ibid. 7 For a full discussion see Matthew Sanger and Scott Sinclair, Putting Health First: Canadian Health Care Reform, Trade Treaties and Foreign Policy. Final report prepared by the CCPA Consortium on Globalization and Health for the Commission on the Future of Health Care in Canada, October, 2002 (available at www.policyalternatives.ca). 8 Commission on the Future of Health Care in Canada (Ottawa, November 2002), Building on Values: The Future of Health Care in Canada, p. 238. 9 The NAFTA investment chapter (Article 1106) does, however, prohibit attaching certain performance requirements to investment. But it also provides some flexibility in the case of subsidies, grants and other so-called advantages. Performance requirements linked to employment creation and labour costs are almost certainly allowable. 10 Even the most zealous interpretation of the GATS national treatment rule could not compel governments to subsidise economic activity or job creation undertaken outside their own territories. The legally non-binding scheduling guidelines for the GATS state that: There is no obligation in the GATS which requires a Member to take measures outside its territorial jurisdiction. It therefore follows that the national treatment obligation in Article XVII does not require a Member to extend such treatment to a service supplier located in the territory of another Member. See World Trade Organization, Committee On Specific Commitments, Revision Of Scheduling Guidelines, Note by the Secretariat, 5 March 1999. (S/CSC/W/19), p. 11. The logic of the GATS itself, however, contradicts this proviso. See Scott Sinclair, GATS, Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives, 2000, pp. 87 ff. 11 There are certain NAFTA reservations, or exceptions, to these rules - for example for aboriginal affairs (Annex II-C-1) and for existing, nonconforming provincial measures in place as of January 1, 1994 (Annex I). 5