Real Option Analysis for Adjacent Gas Producers to Choose Optimal Operating Strategy, such as Gas Plant Size, Leasing rate, and Entry Point

Similar documents
Compete or Cooperate? Firms Interactive Investment Decisions

Real Options and Game Theory in Incomplete Markets

Combining Real Options and game theory in incomplete markets.

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

The investment game in incomplete markets.

The investment game in incomplete markets

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

Lecture 8: Asset pricing

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

A Real Options Game: Investment on the Project with Operational Options and Fixed Costs

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

13.3 A Stochastic Production Planning Model

Supply Contracts with Financial Hedging

1 Dynamic programming

Reputation Games in Continuous Time

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

Capacity Expansion Games with Application to Competition in Power May 19, Generation 2017 Investmen 1 / 24

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

Notes for Section: Week 4

2.1 Mean-variance Analysis: Single-period Model

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

QI SHANG: General Equilibrium Analysis of Portfolio Benchmarking

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Implementing an Agent-Based General Equilibrium Model

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

LECTURES ON REAL OPTIONS: PART III SOME APPLICATIONS AND EXTENSIONS

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

PROBLEM SET 7 ANSWERS: Answers to Exercises in Jean Tirole s Theory of Industrial Organization

Consumption- Savings, Portfolio Choice, and Asset Pricing

Working Paper. R&D and market entry timing with incomplete information

Hedging with Life and General Insurance Products

Location, Productivity, and Trade

Guarantee valuation in Notional Defined Contribution pension systems

Real Options and Signaling in Strategic Investment Games

Valuation of Exit Strategy under Decaying Abandonment Value

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 3 : The Ramsey Growth Model

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2015

Optimal stopping problems for a Brownian motion with a disorder on a finite interval

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims FINAL EXAM. β t 1 2 φτ2 t subject to (1)

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Multi-period mean variance asset allocation: Is it bad to win the lottery?

Microeconomics II. CIDE, Spring 2011 List of Problems

The Self-financing Condition: Remembering the Limit Order Book

Market Design for Emission Trading Schemes

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Lecture 7: Bayesian approach to MAB - Gittins index

Sequential Investment, Hold-up, and Strategic Delay

Part 1: q Theory and Irreversible Investment

Singular Stochastic Control Models for Optimal Dynamic Withdrawal Policies in Variable Annuities

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Structural Models of Credit Risk and Some Applications

Optimal Credit Limit Management

Lecture 2 Dynamic Equilibrium Models: Three and More (Finite) Periods

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India October 2012

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30)

Optimal trading strategies under arbitrage

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Game-Theoretic Risk Analysis in Decision-Theoretic Rough Sets

Repeated Games. EC202 Lectures IX & X. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures IX & X Jan / 16

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Optimal Investment for Worst-Case Crash Scenarios

Competing Mechanisms with Limited Commitment

Strategies and Nash Equilibrium. A Whirlwind Tour of Game Theory

Economics 171: Final Exam

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

N-Player Preemption Games

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Aysmmetry in central bank inflation control

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Game Theory Fall 2003

Optimization Models in Financial Mathematics

Exploring Volatility Derivatives: New Advances in Modelling. Bruno Dupire Bloomberg L.P. NY

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

Game-Theoretic Approach to Bank Loan Repayment. Andrzej Paliński

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Chapter 10: Mixed strategies Nash equilibria, reaction curves and the equality of payoffs theorem

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

University of Hong Kong ECON6036 Stephen Chiu. Extensive Games with Perfect Information II. Outline

All Investors are Risk-averse Expected Utility Maximizers. Carole Bernard (UW), Jit Seng Chen (GGY) and Steven Vanduffel (Vrije Universiteit Brussel)

Continuous-Time Option Games: Review of Models and Extensions Part 1: Duopoly under Uncertainty

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 5: Repeated Games

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Transcription:

Real Option Analysis for Adjacent Gas Producers to Choose Optimal Operating Strategy, such as Gas Plant Size, Leasing rate, and Entry Point Gordon A. Sick and Yuanshun Li October 3, 4 Tuesday, October, 4 at :8 Introduction In the oil and gas industry, producers often happen to own adjacent lands in which they may do production in the future. Should their lands are not next to each other, producers decision may become very well simple. Their optimal operating strategy can be achieved by following a classical real option approach, which has been addressed by many of the precedential real option papers. However, it is worth noting that there is some difference when these producers are adjacent. The network effect resulting from the reduced toll rate charged by the pipeline company might motivate the leader(who starts investment and production first) to build a larger gas plant so that the leader can use a reasonable leasing rate to induce the follower to start production earlier without building up its own gas plant. This paper will actually discuss the the dynamics of leasing fee and the network effect and the interaction between these two factors and the optimal entry point for both the leader and the follower under some game theory consideration.

The assumptions of the Model In the model, there are two gas producers A and B. They have purchased two adjacent lands for gas exploration and producing. There are two kinds of uncertainties involved. The first is the technical uncertainty, i.e. the reserve quantity in the land. We denote it as: dq A = µ A (Q A )dt + σ A (Q A )dz A dq B = µ B (Q B )dt + σ B (Q B )dz B where the correlation ρ = corr(dz A, dz B ). More appropriately, we should model the Q t as a martingale since E t [Q t+ ] = Q t. Thus µ A (Q A ) = µ B (Q B ) =. Once starting the production, the reserve quantity will become: dq A = [µ A (Q A ) q A ]dt + σ A (Q A )dz A = q A dt + σ A (Q A )dz A dq B = [µ B (Q B ) q B ]dt + σ B (Q B )dz B = q B dt + σ B (Q B )dz B Model the exponentially declining production volume as q A = α A Q A q B = α B Q B where the production rate is α A, α B. There are two constraints on the production rate. One is the technological constraint α, which is determined by the engineer. The other is the capacity constraint α c = qc, which is determined by the plant size. Therefore, we should restrain the production rate Q α as follows: α α, if α < α c (.) α α c, if α c < α (.) (Notice, all the above variables α, q, Q could have subscripts A or B to stand for producer A or B.) The second uncertainty is the economic uncertainty, i.e. the market price of gas. We denote it as dp = µ(p )dt + σ(p )dz P

where we assume the correlation ρ = corr(dz P, dz A ) = = corr(dz P, dz B ). The cost of constructing a gas plant with capacity of qa c and qc B has fixed and variable components: K A (qa) c = a A + b A qa c K B (q c B) = a B + b B q c B where the parameters a A, b A, a B, b B >. Therefore, if only A (or B) is producing in A s (or B s) plant, q A q c A and q B q c B. 3 The leader and follower strategy Suppose that both producers have no gas processing facility in their land at the initial stage. If their lands are not adjacent, the problem could have been a classical real option problem. The two producers both have a call option on the gas in the land they have purchased and they will start to construct the facility at the first moment that π t equals or exceeds the exercise value. Here, we define the cash flow as π t : R R π t = f(p t, Q t ). This will be discussed in detail in section 3. However, this paper will focus on the strategy of two producers whose lands are adjacent. In this case, one s operating decision might affect on the other s. Basically, there are two factors need to be considered by the two producers. First, the leader could charge the follower a leasing rate if the follower wants to rent the leader s facility to process gas. Of course, the follower could choose either to rent the facility or to build his own gas plant. Second, there is a toll rate charged by the pipeline company. If the leader and the follower are both producing and transporting out gas, the pipeline company will be able to reduce the toll rate because it can distribute its cost and profit over the two customers, i.e, the leader and the follower. Keeping the above two factors in mind, the two producers will follow a symmetric, subgame perfect equilibrium entry strategies in which each producer s exercise strategy is value maximizing, while conditional upon the other s exercise strategy. [] We can have two different exercise models: simultaneous and sequential model. 3

3. Equilibrium under simultaneous exercise: π t π F Define π F : π F = f(p F, Q F ) as the optimal trigger point of the cash flow that maximizes the follower s option value. As discussed by Grenadier (996), in the range where π t π F, if either producer begins construction at a level of π t greater than π F, the other will enter immediately thereafter. In this case, the equilibrium will be reached when one player enters an instant after the other, this strategy is called a simultaneous entry strategy. This simultaneous exercise strategy of two player model has already been discussed in full detail in Steven Grenadier 996 s paper The Strategic Exercise of Options: Development cascades and Overbuilding in Real Estate Markets. We won t put more effort in it. 3. Equilibrium under sequential exercise: π t π F By following the logic of Proposition in Grenadier 996 s paper, we can spell out the optimal strategy of the two producers in the case of π t π F Define π L : π L = f(p L, Q L ) as the optimal trigger point of the cash flow for the leader to maximize his option value. If π t < π L, one producer will wait until the trigger π L is reached. Any entry before π t hits π L will lead to a value strictly less than the optimal value. However, if π t [π L, π F ), each producer will try to build first. The first mover will win the game and start production, and the slower producer is preempted and has to wait until the trigger π F is reached. 4 The leader and the follower s cash flow and expected payoff This paper will focus on the sequential exercise game when π t [π L, π F ), which means the leader has already exists. The follower is preempted from this stage and will wait until π t rises to π F. However, since the leader wants to take the advantage of the network effect N (coming from the reduced toll rate charged by the pipeline company), he wants to induce the follower to start production earlier. Thus, the leader builds a bigger gas plant with excess capacity and try to lease this excess capacity to the follower while charging a leasing rate l. We denote the variable production cost as C L for 4

the leader and C F for the follower. Scenario : π t [π F, ): The leader and the follower build up a gas plant to process their own gas separately. The leader starts at π L, the follower starts at π F, which means the leader s cash flow range is [π L, ), the follower s cash flow range is [π F, ), and π L < π F. Their cash flow will be: π L = P L q L (C L N)q L (4.) π F = P F q F (C F N)q F (4.) The expected payoff to the leader and the follower are: W L(π L ) = Ê and W F (π F ) = Ê e rt π Lt dt K L (q c L) (4.3) e rt π F t dt K F (q c F ) (4.4) where the Ê is the risk-neutral expectations conditional on information available at time. Or we can use a certainty equivalent approach to model the firm value as: W L(π L ) = W F (π F ) = t= t= E (π Lt ) ( + r) λ t E (π F t ) ( + r) λ t t t= n= t t= n= b nl ( + r) t K L(q c L) (4.) b nf ( + r) t K F (q c F ) (4.6) Scenario : π t [π L, π F ) The leader builds up a bigger gas plant and lease the excess processing capacity to the follower while charging a leasing rate l. Thus the construction costs for the leader has to change accordingly in order to build a bigger gas plant which can process the amount q Ω L q L + q F per unit of time. The cash flows for the leader and the follower become: π(l) L = P L q L (C L N)q L + q F l (4.7) π(l) F = P F q F (C F N)q F q F l (4.8) The expected payoff to the leader and the follower are: W L(π(l) L ) = Ê and W F (π(l) F ) = Ê e rt π(l) Lt dt K L (q Ω L) (4.9) e rt π(l) F t dt (4.)

We can also model the payoff using a certainty equivalent approach: W L(π L (l)) = W F (π F (l)) = t= t= E (π(l) Lt ) ( + r) t λ E (π(l) F t ) ( + r) t λ t t= n= t t= n= b nl ( + r) t K L(q Ω L) (4.) b nf ( + r) t (4.) Scenario 3: The leader builds up a gas plant to produce its gas, but because of the leasing rate l and the construction cost K(qF c ) is too high, the follower chooses to wait until π t > π F. Therefore, the leader can not benefit from the network effect. The cash flow to the leader is: The expected payoff to the leader π 3 L = P L q L C L q L (4.3) W 3 L(π L ) = t= E (π L ) t ( + r) λ t t t= n= b nl ( + r) t K L(q c L) (4.4) The game on three decision variables: the gas plant size (i.e. processing capacity), the production volume and the optimal leasing rate The next step for this paper is to consider a complete way of modeling the decision process before both producers initiating their investment. In this model, we assume the gas price is purely competitive, and the reserve quantity is random. Thus, the leader and the follower can only take the gas price as given by the market and have no control on the reserve quantity (If there exists asymmetric information about the reserve quantity, then the leader and the follower can play game on this factor). But they can play games on the gas plant size (i.e., the processing capacity), the production volume. We first consider a simple situation in which the follower has signed a binding contract with the leader. In this contract, the leader and the follower agree that as long as the follower wants to produce, he has to rent the leader s 6

extra capacity, but the leasing rate is negotiable. The decision variables are the plant size: ql Ω, qc F, which determine the construction costs K L(qL Ω), K F (qf c ) and the production volume: q L, q F. (Remember that q L = α L Q L, q F = α F Q F and the subscript L and F stands for the leader and the follower respectively.) The parameters are the gas price: P and reserve quantity: Q L, Q F. The leader s production volume is defined as q L (ql c, α L, Q L, P ). ql c is the leader s capacity which is determined by the leader s plant size. α L is the leader s production rate which is decided by the technician based on the leader s reserve quality. Since we have assumed that the leader and the follower have signed a binding leasing contract in which the leader promises to offer the follower the processing capacity q F,L. Thus, the follower s production volume can not exceed this offered amount, i.e. q F q F,L. Based on above discussion, we have the following relationships: q F,L = q c L q L (.) q L = α L Q L (.) q L q L = α L Q L, if q L < q c L (.3) o q L q c L, if q c L < q L (.4) However, we have assumed that the leader is going to build a larger enough gas plant to process both his and the follower s gas. The leader will estimate both producers need and build a gas plant with capacity q Ω L qc L. Therefore, the above relationship can be simplified as: q F,L = q Ω L q L (.) q L = α L Q L (.6) q L q L, because q L < q Ω L (.7) In addition, both the leader and the follower will have to consider the effect of leasing rate, l charged by the leader and the reduced toll rate (network effect, N) charged by the pipeline company. Assume that the follower will use up all the capacity from the lease, i.e. q F = q F,L, we can solve for the optimal trigger price for the follower in terms of q F, denoted as P F (q F, l). The leader s objective will be to maximize the 7

leasing rate. Whilst, if the leader and the follower s combined production volume reaches a certain level, the pipeline company will charge them a lower toll rate, which will reduce both producers variable production cost due to the network effect N. On the other hand, the follower also has the choice between renting the processing capacity from the leader and start producing later. This means that the leader also does not want to drive away the follower because if the follower is not producing, the pipeline company will charge a relatively higher toll rate. Therefore, the leader wants to charge the follower the highest leasing rate up to the point where the follower will start to delay its production. In other word, the leader s task is to find an optimal solution for the leasing rate l, such that it can induce the follower to start production by renting the leader s gas plant at the same time when PF (q F, l) = PL in order to take the advantage of the network effect N. This will give an upper bound for the leasing rate, denoted as l. Suppose that the leader knows the follower s reserve quantity and production rate Q F and α F. The leader, therefore, builds a bigger gas plant which can process the amount q Ω L q L + q F per unit of time. It turns out to be convenient to model present value of the leasing fee as the follower s exercise cost. K = P V (q F l) (.8) For the lease to happen at the same time when the leader start production, the gas price P t must exceed the follower s exercise hurdle PF (q F, l), i.e. P t PF (q F, l). For any certain level of l, we can calculate the a critical price or exercise hurdle PF (q F, l). If PF (q F, l) > PL, indicates l is too high; if PF (q F, l) < PL, indicates l is too low; Only when P F (q F, l) = PL, l is optimal value l for the leader. The value of the follower s option is the net proceeds from exercising: W (P F ) t = P F,t K (.9) which is the famous value matching and smooth-pasting conditions. The solution of the critical value for the follower is given as: P F = γ + γ + K (.) 8

where, γ +, = + δ r ( ± σ + δ r ) r + (.) σ σ To make the discussion clearer, we list the functional relationship between variables as follows (the superscript and stands for the scenario and in section 3 respectively) : π L = π L(P, q L ) (.) W L = W L(π L, q c L) = W L(P, q L, q c L) (.3) π L = π L(P, q L, q F, l) (.4) W L = W L(π L, q Ω L) = W L(P, q L, q F, l, q Ω L) (.) π F = π F (P, q F ) (.6) W F = W F (π F, q c F ) = W F (P, q F, q c F ) (.7) π F = π L(P, q F, l) (.8) W F = W F (π F ) = W F (P, q F, l) (.9) The key step is the leader s decision on ql Ω, and l. Once the two variables are decided, we can solve for the rest. The actual results of the bargaining game will depend on the amount information either the leader or the follower occupies. We will discuss more in this aspect in next version of this paper. 6 One player model for the leader The leader chooses the optimal time point to invest and start producing, suspend or resume the operation depending on the market price P and remaining reserve quantity Q. Define that V (P, Q, m) = the leader s firm value where, m =, if not investing m =, if producing m =, if suspending 9

Then the free boundary conditions that L s value must satisfy when he starting the investment, suspending and resuming the production are: V (P, Q, ) = V (P, Q, ) K(q) V (P, Q, ) = V (P, Q, ) K s V (P, Q, ) = V (P, Q, ) K r where, K s = suspend cost K r = resume cost Assume the dividend yield on the underlying asset is δ(p, t) therefore, µ(p, t) λβ(p ) = rp δ(p, t) where β(p ) = cov(dp, df) var(dp )var(df) and r is the risk free interest rate. Similarly, the risk-neutral drift of Q is: µ(q) q(m) λ Q β(q) = µ(q) q(m) where β(q) = cov(dq, df) var(dq)var(df) = if m = or, q(m) = = q() = q() if m =, q() = q when producing at less than full capacity or = q max when producing at full capacity If we assuming the P and Q are not correlated, the firm value must also satisfy the following two dimensional PDEs: when m = [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] +V Q (P, Q, ) [µ(q) q() λ Q β(q)] +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t = rv (P, Q, )

when m = [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] + V Q (P, Q, )µ(q) +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t = rv (P, Q, ) (6.) [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] + V Q (P, Q, ) [µ(q) q()] +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t + π = rv (P, Q, ) (6.) [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] + V Q (P, Q, ) [µ(q) q()] +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t + π(l) = rv (P, Q, ) (6.3) [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] + V Q (P, Q, ) [µ(q) q()] when m = +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t + π 3 = rv 3 (P, Q, ) (6.4) [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] +V Q (P, Q, ) [µ(q) q() λ Q β(q)] +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t = rv (P, Q, ) [ σ (Q)V QQ (P, Q, ) + σ (P )V P P (P, Q, ) ] + V Q (P, Q, ) [µ(q) q()] +V P (P, Q, ) [µ P (P ) λ P β P (P )] + V t = rv (P, Q, ) (6.)

7 Solve the one player model We use explicit finite difference method, Euler methods and symmetric difference. We assume simple log-normal process for both P and Q, which is: dp = µ P dt + σ P P dz P (7.) dq = µ Q dt + σ Q Qdz Q (7.) Also, assume a constant dividend yield rate δ which makes δ(p, t) = δ P. Thus, Discretize µ(p ) λβ(p ) = µ P P δ P = rp δ P (7.3) µ(q) = µ Q Q (7.4) σ (P ) = σ P P (7.) σ (Q) = σ QQ (7.6) V t = V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) t V P = V (P i+, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) P V Q = V (P i, Q j+, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) Q (7.7) (7.8) (7.9) V P P = V (P i+, Q j, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) ( P ) (7.) V QQ = V (P i, Q j+, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) ( Q) (7.) Then, equation. becomes σ Qj ( Q) V (P i, Q j+, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) ( Q) + σ P i ( P ) V (P i+, Q j, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) ( P ) +µ Q j Q V (P i, Q j+, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) Q

+(r δ )i P V (P i+, Q j, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) P + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) = rv (P i, Q j, t k ) (7.) t σ Qj [V (P i, Q j+, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k )] + σ P i [V (P i+, Q j, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k )] + µ Qj [V (P i, Q j+, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k )] + (ri δ i) [V (P i+, Q j, t k ) + V (P i, Q j, t k )] + V (P i, Q j, t k ) V (P i, Q j, t k ) t Finally, we get the recursive formula: = rv (P i, Q j, t k ) (7.3) ( σ Qj t σ P i t r t)v (P i, Q j, t k )+( σ Qj t+ µ Qj t)v (P i, Q j+, t k ) ( σ Qj t ( µ Qj t)v (P i, Q j, t k )+ σ P i t + ) (ri δ i) t V (P i+, Q j, t k ) ( σ P i t ) (ri δ i) t V (P i, Q j, t k ) = rv (P i, Q j, t k ) (7.4) There are three conditions for the input variables to ensure the stability of the solution to the PDEs, for i and j within the recursive formula ( σ Qj t σ P i t r t) ( σ Qj t µ Qj t) σ P i t + (ri δ i) t σ P i t (ri δ i) t 3

t r σ P i max + σ Qj max (7.) j min µ Q (7.6) σq r δ (7.7) i min r δ σ P 8 Numerically search the solution (7.8) Since it is hard to explicitly solve the PDEs which contain two stochastic variables. We use the numerical method to solve the systems of equations in Section 6 and Section 7. The solutions are displayed in the following graphs. [] [6] [] [] [8] [9] [] [3] [7] [4] References [Figure about here.] [Figure about here.] [Figure 3 about here.] [] Michael J. Brennan and Eduardo S. Schwartz. Evaluating natural resource investments. The Journal of Business, volume 8(Issue ):3 7, April 98. [] Dennis R. Capozza and Gordon Sick. Valuing long-term leases: The option to redevelop. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, volume 4(Issue ):9 3, June 99. [3] Drew Fudenberg and Jean Tirole. Sequential bargaining with incomplete information. The Review of Economic Studies, volume (No.): 47, 983. [4] Drew Fudenberg and Jean Tirole. Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology. The Review of Economic Studies, Volume (No.3):383 4, 98. 4

[] Steven R. Grenadier. The strategic exercise of options: Development cascades and overbuilding in real estate markets. The Journal of Finance, volume (No.):63 679, December 996. [6] David C. Mauer and Alexander J. Triantis. Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions: A dynamic framework. Journal of Finance, volume 49(Issue 4):3 77, September 994. [7] Jennifer F. Reinganum. Techonology adoption under imperfect information. The Bell Journal of Economics, Volume 4(No.):7 69, 983. [8] Gordon Sick. Capital Budgeting with Real Options. Faculty of Management, University of Calgary, 989. Monograph 989-3, Series in Finance and Economics, Salomon Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, New York University. [9] Gordon Sick. Handbooks in Operations Research and Managemen Science, volume Volume 9, chapter Chapter. Elsevier North Holland, 99. [] Paul Wilmott. Derivatives, The theory and practice of financial engineering, pages 66 669. John wiley and Sons Ltd., 998. Chapter 48.

List of Figures American Call......................... 7 American Call......................... 8 3 American Call3......................... 9 6

American call Value at time T x 4 3.... 3 Gas Price Reserve Quantity Figure : American Call 7

American call Value at time T 4 x 4 4 3 3 Gas Price Reserve Quantity Figure : American Call 8

American call value at initial time x 4 6 4 3 3 Gas Price Reserve Quantity Figure 3: American Call3 9

American call Value at time T x 4 3.... 3 Gas Price Reserve Quantity

American call Value at time T 4 x 4 4 3 3 Gas Price Reserve Quantity

American call value at initial time x 4 6 4 3 3 Gas Price Reserve Quantity