Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap

Similar documents
The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

LECTURE 8 Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound. October 19, 2011

The Demand and Supply of Safe Assets (Premilinary)

Sharing the Burden: Monetary and Fiscal Responses to a World Liquidity Trap David Cook and Michael B. Devereux

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

1. Suppose that instead of a lump sum tax the government introduced a proportional income tax such that:

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Equilibrium with Production and Labor Supply

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Dynamic AD and Dynamic AS

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Gehrke: Macroeconomics Winter term 2012/13. Exercises

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

1 Dynamic programming

A model of secular stagnation

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Course information EC2065 Macroeconomics

Monetary Macroeconomics & Central Banking Lecture /

MFE Macroeconomics Week 8 Exercises

Macroeconomics and finance

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Unemployment equilibria in a Monetary Economy

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Asset purchase policy at the effective lower bound for interest rates

Consumption and Investment

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Problem set Fall 2012.

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Interest-rate pegs and central bank asset purchases: Perfect foresight and the reversal puzzle

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Keynesian Matters Source:

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Optimal Asset Division Rules for Dissolving Partnerships

A Model with Costly Enforcement

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Real Business Cycle Theory

Monetary Economics. Lecture 23a: inside and outside liquidity, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014 (not examinable)

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Comments on Michael Woodford, Globalization and Monetary Control

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010

The Zero Lower Bound

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Inside Money, Investment, and Unconventional Monetary Policy

The Effects of Dollarization on Macroeconomic Stability

A simple wealth model

Motivation: Two Basic Facts

Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending Cuts Vs. Tax Hikes

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

R.E.Marks 1997 Recap 1. R.E.Marks 1997 Recap 2

The Static Model. Consumer Assumptions on the preferences: Consumer. A description of the Model Economy

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Low Real Interest Rates and the Zero Lower Bound

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

Fire sales, inefficient banking and liquidity ratios

Econ 3029 Advanced Macro. Lecture 2: The Liquidity Trap

Transcription:

Optimal Negative Interest Rates in the Liquidity Trap Davide Porcellacchia 8 February 2017 Abstract The canonical New Keynesian model features a zero lower bound on the interest rate. In the simple setting of this paper, where agents are subject to idiosyncratic liquidity risk and therefore a banking system emerges to insure such risk as in Diamond and Dybvig (1983), the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates vanishes and thus negative interest rates on bank reserves become a viable policy option. However, negative interest rates come with a new tradeoff for the central bank: between keeping the banking system fully functional by setting a high enough interest rate on reserves and achieving full employment, which requires a strictly negative nominal interest rate when large adverse demand shocks hit the economy. The paper s main finding is that it is always optimal for the central bank to set a strictly negative interest rate on reserves in response to negative demand shocks that push the economy in the liquidity trap. 1 Introduction Banks play an important role in the economy as providers of liquidity-risk insurance. However, this role is abstracted from in the canonical models that are used to analyse optimal monetary policy in the liquidity trap (e.g. Eggertsson and Woodford (2003)). This paper shows that when maturity transformation is explicitly modelled, even in the presence of money as an alternative store of value with zero net nominal return, negative interest rates on reserves are not only possible but optimal in the liquidity trap. As in Krugman (1998), I model the liquidity trap as a systemic increase in agents discount factor in a neoclassical growth model with nominal rigidities. Liquidity risk and the insurance thereof is in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig (1983). Agents are unable to insure each other directly from idiosyncratic liquidity shocks. Thus, banks can make a profit by offering deposit contracts that serve this purpose. The policy tradeoff that this paper analyses is between stimulating demand in the liquidity trap by means of negative interest rates and ensuring that healthy banks can provide valuable liquidity-risk insurance. PhD candidate in the department of Economics of the London School of Economics. 1

1.1 Key assumptions Idiosyncratic liquidity shocks: agents discount factor β i is stochastic. As in Diamond and Dybvig (1983) agents can be early or late consumers. Notice that in this model I assumes that the agents type is publicly observable once it is realised. No commitment: Agents cannot make intertemporal contracts because they cannot commit to honouring them in the following period. Hence, there is a role for banks to pool savings in the form of deposits and then pay high returns to those depositors with higher marginal utility of consumption. Price rigidity: Following Krugman (1998), I assume a price rigidity. For simplicity, I assume the extreme form P 0 = P 1 = 1. 2 Agents 2.1 Consumers There is a unit measure of consumers j [0, 1] who supply labour inelastically and choose a path for consumption (C j0, C j1 ) by investing in capital K j1, money M j1 0, and deposits D j1 in order to maximise The individual s flow budget constraints are u(c j0 ) + E 0 [ βj u(c j1 ) ] (1) K j1 + M j1 + D j1 + C j0 = (1 + r 0 δ) K 0 + W 0 N 0 T 0 (2) C j1 = W 1 N j1 + (1 + r 1 δ) K j1 + (1 + d j ) D j1 + M j1 T 1 (3) The discount factor β j = β ɛ j is a stochastic variable with { ɛ H with probability θ ɛ j = ɛ L with probability 1 θ. (4) ɛ H > ɛ L. The liquidity shock ɛ j is realised for each agent at time one and it is idiosyncratic with E(ɛ j ) = 1. 2.1.1 Key optimality conditions Consumers make their saving decision based on the financial asset offering the best risk-adjusted return, so that u (C 0 ) = max{v K, V D, V M } (5) 2

where (V K, V D, V M ), the time-0 marginal value of respectively capital, deposits, and money, are V K = β (1 + r 1 δ) ɛ H u (C H1 ) X (6) Define V D = β [(1 + i D H) θ ɛ H u (C H1 ) + (1 + i D L ) (1 θ) ɛ L u (C L1 ) ] (7) V M = β ɛ H u (C H1 ) X (8) X = θ + (1 θ) ɛl u (C L1 ) ɛ H u (C H1 ) the index of liquidity-risk insurance. X is increasing with the extent of liquidity insurance, with X = 1 indicating perfect insurance. 2.2 Monti-Klein Banks Banks that collect deposits, invest, and pay back to deposit-holders on the basis of their type emerge naturally in this framework. I assume no barriers to entry, and therefore a competitive banking market. Banks emerge because agents are unable to insure each other against liquidity shocks because of their inability to commit. Pooling savings in a bank in the form of deposits is a commitment device that allows a transfer in the future period from depositors hit by a low liquidity shock to depositors hit by a high liquidity shock. Banks are of the Monti-Klein type. They choose their asset portfolio among capital K B1, money M B1 0, and reserves R 1 and finance these asset holdings with deposits (I do not consider bank equity), as according to the budget constraint (9) K B1 + M B1 + R = D (10) There is a reserve requirement on banks proportional to their deposits R ρ D 1, ρ (0, 1] (11) and, since agents are unable to commit to paying into the bank in period one if they turn out to be L-type, then the deposit contract must have 1 + d j 0, j {H, L} (12) Subject to the above constraints, banks maximise profits Π B1, defined as [ ] Π B1 = (1 + r 1 δ) K B1 + M B1 + (1 + i) R 1 θ (1 + d H ) + (1 θ) (1 + d L ) D (13) If profits are less than zero, banks shut down. 3

2.2.1 Key optimality and equilibrium conditions Given this paper s focus on negative interest rates on reserves (that penalise financial intermediation), I consider a banking system of minimum size to achieve the equilibrium level of liquidity insurance. The main implication of this is that equation 12 with j = L is binding in equilibrium, so that 1 + d L = 0 (14) This means that the deposit contract provides the maximum level of liquidity insurance per unit of deposit, consistent with the lack of a commitment device for consumers. In fact, banks pay all the returns of their investments to agents that become H-types and pay nothing to L-types. Notice that this is a contract that agents faced with idiosyncratic liquidity risk will be happy to enter ex ante. 2.3 Firms Firms are standard. In each period, they produce output Y with labour N and capital K according to constant-returns-to-scale production function Subject to equation 15, firms statically maximise their profits Y = f(k, N) (15) Π F = Y W N r K (16) I assume that firms operate in a perfectly competitive market. 2.3.1 Key optimality and equilibrium conditions As is standard, in equilibrium firms equate marginal product and marginal cost of the factors of production so that f 1 (K, N) = r (17) f 2 (K, N) = W (18) As is usual in the literature, in this model the liquidity trap is a rationing equilibrium. In such equilibrium, competition continues to make firms pay factors of production at their marginal product. However, firms will not hire and rent all workers and capital supplied, because they find it impossible to sell their production beyond a certain level. 2.4 Government The government issues money M and reserves R and carries out monetary policy by setting the nominal interest rate on reserves i. 4

Notice that, regardless of the interest rate, banks hold reserves because of the reserve requirement. Nonetheless, monetary policy affects the amount of wealth that agents are willing to hold in intermediated finance and therefore the general attractiveness of saving vs. consuming. I assume that in each period the government balances its budget by means of lumpsum taxes T imposed equally on all consumers, regardless of their type. The government s budget constraints therefore are 0 = M 1 + M B1 + R 1 + T 0 (19) M 1 + M B1 + (1 + i) R 1 = T 1 (20) 3 Autarchy Before discussing the equilibrium concept more carefully in the next section, here I study the equilibrium allocation that would prevail if banks were not allowed to operate. Proposition 1: Without banks agents cannot diversify their liquidity risk, so that X aut = θ + (1 θ) ɛl ɛ H < 1 (21) Notice that in this model banks do not operate if i is set too low. 4 Equilibrium with banking: market-clearing vs. rationing Equilibrium is defined as the vector of all endogenous quantities and prices such that Consumers maximise utility taking prices as given subject to budget constraints, Banks maximise profits in a perfectly competitive market, Firms maximise profits in a perfectly competitive market. In this section, I determine the equilibrium value of endogenous variables that are of interest for the optimal monetary policy problem: ( C 0, C H1, C L1, K 1 K 1 +K B1, K 0, Ñ0, X ). The total level of capital available for production in period 1 is denoted K 1. K0 and Ñ0 are the quantities of capital and labour employed in production in period zero, which in a rationing equilibrium may be smaller than capital and labour supplied. Proposition 2: There exists a threshold ˆβ > 1 such that if β > ˆβ, then the equilibrium features rationing (i.e. at least one of K 0 < K 0 and Ñ0 < 1 is true). I call this liquidity 5

trap. In the case of this model, β is simply a parameter. So, this is a simple comparative statics exercise. However, a high level of β > ˆβ > 1 represents a systemic shock that increases consumers propensity to save. 4.1 Market-clearing equilibrium In the standard market-clearing equilibrium, money is an inferior asset in terms of returns and hence consumers do not hold any. Consumers hold capital and therefore save according to u (C 0 ) = β [1 + f 1 ( K 1, 1) δ ] ɛ H u (C H1 ) X (22) where X is the index of liquidity-risk insurance defined as X = θ + (1 θ) ɛl u (C L1 ) ɛ H u (C H1 ) In equilibrium, the extent of liquidity-risk insurance is determined by X = max {1 ρ[ f 1 ( K 1, 1) δ i ] } 1 + f 1 ( K 1, 1) δ, Xaut with one indicating full liquidity insurance and the degree of liquidity insurance decreasing as the value of X decreases. It is clear that setting the interest rate on reserves i equal to the net rate of return on capital f 1 ( K 1, 1) δ gives full liquidity insurance in equilibrium while lower levels of i implement partial liquidity insurance as agents invest their wealth directly rather than investing in intermediated finance that is effectively taxed. The resource constraints that hold in equilibrium are (23) (24) K 1 + C 0 = (1 δ) K 0 + f(k 0, 1) (25) θ C H1 + (1 θ) C L1 = (1 δ) K 1 + f( K 1, 1) (26) Notice that in the market-clearing equilibrium, which takes place when β < ˆβ, there is full employment of the factors of production, so that K 0 = K 0 (27) where K 0 is the exogenous initial quantity of capital in the economy, and Ñ 0 = 1 (28) 6

4.2 Liquidity-trap equilibrium As according to proposition 2, if β > ˆβ, the economy enters the liquidity trap which is a rationing equilibrium. Consumers find it optimal to hold money as a financial investment. Thus, they save according to u (C 0 ) = β ɛ H u (C H1 ) X (29) where X is the index of liquidity-risk insurance defined as X = θ + (1 θ) ɛl u (C L1 ) ɛ H u (C H1 ) (30) In equilibrium, the extent of liquidity-risk insurance is determined by 1 { X = max 1 + ρ i, X aut} (31) with one indicating full liquidity insurance and the degree of liquidity insurance decreasing as the value of X decreases. The equation shows that if the government sets a nominal interest rate on reserves of zero, then there is full liquidity-risk insurance in the economy. Lower levels of insurance are associated with lower levels of the interest rate i. Also, if i < 1 Xaut ρ, then the economy reverts to autarchy as consumers shun deposits altogether. In equilibrium, it must be that for anyone in the economy to hold capital. The resource constraints that hold in equilibrium are f 1 ( K 1, 1) = δ (32) K 1 + C 0 = (1 δ) K 0 + f( K 0, Ñ0) (33) θ C H1 + (1 θ) C L1 = (1 δ) K 1 + f( K 1, 1) (34) Notice that, under the scenario where β is higher than the threshold ˆβ, there is rationing in equilibrium. This means that at least one of the following inequalities holds strictly: In equilibrium, ( K 0, Ñ0) are not determined individually. K 0 K 0 (35) Ñ 0 1 (36) 1 Figure 1 in the appendix provides a graphical analysis of the determination of X in equilibrium. 7

5 Optimal monetary policy In this section, I study the optimal monetary policy problem. The government s policy instrument is the nominal interest rate on bank reserves and the government aims to maximise agents aggregate welfare. 5.1 Market-clearing equilibrium Proposition 3: If β ˆβ, then optimal monetary policy sets i = f 1 ( K 1, 1) δ. This implements the first-best efficient allocation. In the market-clearing equilibrium, the government should pay the market rate of return on capital on bank reserves. 5.2 Liquidity trap 5.2.1 Optimisation problem The government chooses a value for its policy instrument i to maximise aggregate welfare defined as the sum of all consumers utility functions (for simplicity, I adopt a CES specification for utility) C 1 γ 0 1 + β 1 γ [θ ɛ H C1 γ H1 Optimisation is subject to the Euler equation where X is an index of liquidity-risk insurance ] 1 γ + (1 θ) ɛ L C1 γ L1 1 γ (37) C γ 0 = β ɛ H C γ H1 X (38) X = θ + (1 θ) ɛl ɛ H ( CH1 C L1 ) γ (39) Furthermore, it is subject to the following equation that holds because people hold deposits too (unless they are better off in autarchy) and subject to the resource constraint X = max { 1 + ρ i, X aut} (40) θ C H1 + (1 θ) C L1 = (1 δ) K 1 + f( K 1, 1) (41) Notice that, by equation 40, the government can directly determine the degree of liquidity-risk insurance by choosing to pay interest on reserves at the market rate (i.e. i = 0) or to pay a negative interest rate on reserves. 8

5.2.2 Result Proposition 4: If β > ˆβ and therefore the economy is in the liquidity trap, it is optimal for the government to set a strictly negative nominal interest rate on bank reserves. The resulting allocation is second best, with partial liquidity-risk insurance.. The policy tradeoff in the model s liquidity trap is between having more consumption (i.e. less rationing) at time zero and ensuring that banks provide valuable liquidityrisk insurance. In fact, by taxing the banking system with a negative interest rate on reserves, the government discourages consumers from saving excessively. However, harming financial intermediaries is undesirable too, as banks provide valuable liquidityrisk insurance. In the relevant (C 0, X) space, the government can pick a point that belongs to the feasibility curve, defined as the combination of the Euler equation (equation 38), the definition of X (equation 39), and the resource constraint (equation 41).The slope of the feasibility curve is dx u (C 0 ) ɛ L u (C L1 ) [θ C H1 + (1 θ) C L1 ] = dc 0 β θ ɛ H u (C H1 ) [ɛ H u (C H1 ) C L1 ɛ L u (C L1 ) C H1 ] (42) which is weakly negative if X θ+(1 θ) ( ɛ L ɛh ) 1 γ+1 > X aut and strictly positive otherwise. The government s preferences can be represented by an indifference map in the (C 0, X) space. The indifference curves are obtained by combining aggregate welfare (equation 37) with the definition of X (equation 39), and the resource constraint (equation 41). It can be shown that the slope of the indifference curves is given by dx γ u (C 0 ) ɛ L u (C L1 ) [θ C H1 + (1 θ) C L1 ] = dc 0 β θ ɛ H u (C H1 ) C H1 C L1 [ɛ H u (C H1 ) ɛ L u (C L1 )] < 0 (43) At the optimum, the government will pick the combination (C 0, X ) where the feasibility curve and an indifference curve are tangent. It can be shown that this point has X < 1, which implies a negative interest rate on reserves. 2 6 Conclusion I study the liquidity trap in a neoclassical growth model with nominal rigidities, as in Krugman (1998), and with idiosyncratic liquidity shocks, in the spirit of Diamond and Dybvig (1983). The model is simple and tractable. Nominal rigidities create a role for 2 Figure 2 in the appendix provides a graphical analysis of the optimal monetary policy problem. 9

monetary policy and the liquidity shocks give a role to maturity transformation performed by a banking sector. The banking sector is subject to a reserve requirement and policymakers set the interest rate on reserves. I find that, even in the absence of costs to holding wealth in money, in this simple economy there is no zero lower bound on the policy interest rate. Moreover, when the economy is hit by a large adverse demand shock, it is unambiguously optimal for the central bank to set a strictly negative nominal rate on reserves. When the economy is not in a liquidity-trap state, it is optimal to set the policy interest rate equal to the (weakly) positive net rate of return on capital prevailing in the economy. 10

7 Appendix V K = V M u C 0 V D (i < 0) X aut X i < 0 1 X Figure 1: Equilibrium determination of X X 1 X Feasibility Indifference θ + 1 θ ε L ε H 1 γ+1 X aut = θ + 1 θ ε L ε H C 0 C 0 Figure 2: The optimal monetary policy problem 11

References [1] Diamond, Douglas W & Dybvig, Philip H, 1983. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity. Journal of Political Economy [2] Eggertsson, Gauti, & Michael Woodford, 2003. The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity [3] Krugman, Paul, 1998. It s Baaack: Japan s Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 12