The Effect of a Longer Working Horizon on Individual and Family Labour Supply

Similar documents
The Effect of a Longer Working Horizon on Individual and Family Labour Supply

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

1 Payroll Tax Legislation 2. 2 Severance Payments Legislation 3

The impact of the work resumption program of the disability insurance scheme in the Netherlands

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

Long Term Effects of Temporary Labor Demand: Free Trade Zones, Female Education and Marriage Market Outcomes in the Dominican Republic

Closing routes to retirement: how do people respond? Johannes Geyer, Clara Welteke

How Changes in Unemployment Benefit Duration Affect the Inflow into Unemployment

Husband s Unemployment and Wife s Labor Supply The Added Worker Effect across Europe

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance

CAPP Centro di Analisi delle Politiche Pubbliche

In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Effects of working part-time and full-time on physical and mental health in old age in Europe

Firing Costs, Employment and Misallocation

SPOUSAL HEALTH SHOCKS AND LABOR SUPPLY

The Effects of Reducing the Entitlement Period to Unemployment Insurance

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

Family and Work. 1. Labor force participation of married women

SOCIAL SECURITY S EARNINGS TEST PENALTY AND THE EMPLOYMENT RATES OF ELDERLY MEN AGED 65 TO 69

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Economic incentives and gender identity

THE ABOLITION OF THE EARNINGS RULE

THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF RISING THE RETIREMENT AGE: LESSONS FROM THE SEPTEMBER 1993 LAW*

CONVERGENCES IN MEN S AND WOMEN S LIFE PATTERNS: LIFETIME WORK, LIFETIME EARNINGS, AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT $

Labour Force Participation in the Euro Area: A Cohort Based Analysis

The Effect of Income Eligibility Restrictions on Labor Supply: The Case of the Nutritional Assistance Program in Puerto Rico

How exogenous is exogenous income? A longitudinal study of lottery winners in the UK

The Retirement-Consumption Puzzle and the German Pension System - A Regression Discontinuity Approach

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Class Question 15, Part I Incidence of unemployment insurance

Labor or Leisure? Labor supply of older couples and the role of full retirement age

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

Australia. 31 January Draft: please do not cite or quote. Abstract

Labor supply of mothers with young children: Validating a structural model using a natural experiment

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

The Labor Market Consequences of Adverse Financial Shocks

Online Appendix (Not For Publication)

Labor Force Participation Elasticities of Women and Secondary Earners within Married Couples. Rob McClelland* Shannon Mok* Kevin Pierce** May 22, 2014

What happens to the husband s retirement decision when the wife s retirement incentives change?

Discussion of Relationship and Transaction Lending in a Crisis

Effects of Increased Elderly Employment on Other Workers Employment and Elderly s Earnings in Japan. Ayako Kondo Yokohama National University

The Rise of the Added Worker Effect

Adjustment Costs and Incentives to Work: Evidence from a Disability Insurance Program

Mining closures, gender, and employment reallocations: the case of UK coal mines

Electronic Supplementary Material (Appendices A-C)

Added Worker Effect Revisited: The Aubry s Law in France as a Natural Experiment

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

Taxation and Labor Force Participation: The Case of Italy

Late-Career Job Loss and Retirement Behavior of Couples

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

Quasi-Experimental Methods. Technical Track

Graded Security and Labor Market Mobility Clean Evidence from the Italian Jobs Act

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

The Labor Market Consequences of Adverse Financial Shocks

Labor supply responses to health shocks in Senegal

Labor Market Effects of the Early Retirement Age

Individual Heterogeneity and Pension Choices: How to Communicate an Effective Message?

The Distributive Impact of Reforms in Credit Enforcement: Evidence from Indian Debt Recovery Tribunals

The Impact of Shareholder Taxation on Merger and Acquisition Behavior

Unequal Burden of Retirement Reform: Evidence from Australia

the working day: Understanding Work Across the Life Course introduction issue brief 21 may 2009 issue brief 21 may 2009

Social Security's Earnings Test Penalty and the Employment Rates of Elderly Men Aged 65 to 69

Indian Households Finance: An analysis of Stocks vs. Flows- Extended Abstract

Egyptian Married Women Don t desire to Work or Simply Can t? A Duration Analysis. Rana Hendy. March 15th, 2010

Labor Market Effects of the Early Retirement Age

Evaluating Search Periods for Welfare Applicants: Evidence from a Social Experiment

Investment and Employment Responses to State Adoption of Federal Accelerated Depreciation Policies

Credit Constraints and Search Frictions in Consumer Credit Markets

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

Labor Migration and Wage Growth in Malaysia

Large-scale social transfer and labor market outcomes: The case of the South African pension program

Economists and Time Use Data

Examining the Household Responses to the Recession Wealth Shocks:

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

Exam. ECON 4624 Empirical Public Economics. (a) Consider the budget contraint in Figure 1 below. What are the expected effects on

The impact of increased conditionality for out-of-work lone parents Evidence from the UK Labour Force Survey

Scarcity effects of QE: A transaction-level analysis in the Bund market

Online Robustness Appendix to Are Household Surveys Like Tax Forms: Evidence from the Self Employed

T-DYMM: Background and Challenges

How Income Changes During Unemployment: Evidence from Tax Return Data

A New Look at Technical Progress and Early Retirement

Paul Bingley SFI Copenhagen. Lorenzo Cappellari. Niels Westergaard Nielsen CCP Aarhus and IZA

Unemployment Insurance and Reservation Wages: Evidence from Administrative Data

Access to Retirement Savings and its Effects on Labor Supply Decisions

Long-term care reform and the labor supply of household members Evidence from a quasi-experiment

Pension expectations and reality. What do Italian workers know about their future public pension benefits?

Data and Methods in FMLA Research Evidence

Explaining Consumption Excess Sensitivity with Near-Rationality:

Marriage, Wealth, and Unemployment Duration: A Gender Asymmetry Puzzle

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

Discussion of: Banks Incentives and Quality of Internal Risk Models

Ministry of Health, Labour and Welfare Statistics and Information Department

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

Migration Responses to Household Income Shocks: Evidence from Kyrgyzstan

The Role of the Annuity s Value on the Decision (Not) to Annuitize: Evidence from a Large Policy Change

School-to-Work Transition and Youth Unemployment in Turkey

Does Expanding Health Insurance Beyond Formal-Sector Workers Encourage Informality? Measuring the Impact of Mexico s Seguro Popular

econstor Make Your Publications Visible.

Transcription:

The Effect of a Longer Working Horizon on Individual and Family Labour Supply Francesca Carta Marta De Philippis Bank of Italy December 1, 2017 Paris, ASME BdF Labour Market Conference

Motivation: delaying MRA Aging is one of the major challenges faced by developed economies in this century Many countries reacted by implementing reforms to delay the minimum retirement age (MRA) It allows both reducing the number of pension recipients and enlarging the tax base Through (in principle) positive labour supply effects, since people should work more years

The effect on individuals who lose eligibility Mechanical effects around the pension eligibility threshold on individuals who lose their eligibility Rather extensively analyzed (Arpaia et al. 2009, Staubli and Zweimuller 2013, Geyer and Welteke 2017) Mixed findings Program substitution: unemployment or disability benefits Private pension schemes Weak labour demand Positive employment effect but small Fiscal efficacy of delaying MRA?

The distance to retirement labour supply effect Possible effects also on younger individuals, not eligible to retire even with the pre-increase rules When search is costly and in the presence of search frictions, the expected duration of a job increases its value and participation because search effort The effect on employment/unemployment are ambiguous: search effort employment reservation wage (greater benefits of an additional period of search) may unemployment Used to explain low participation at the end of working life (Hairault et al. 2010, Seater 1977, Ljungqvist and Sargent 2008, Cheron 2011)

Research question The direct effect of a longer working horizon on individual labour supply search behaviour of individuals not eligible to retire even before the increase in MRA, whose working horizon increases The indirect effects on the spouses generated by within-family interactions through leisure complementarities or income effects We use a two pension reforms implemented in Italy in 2011 and 2012 sizeable increase in MRA (4 years on average) well-understood (inflamed public debate) increased MRA heterogeneously depending on observable dimensions (gender, age and continuity of previous working life)

This Paper We estimate a diff-in-diff model, comparing over time the labour supply of individuals (and their partners) most or least exposed to the pension reforms induced increase in MRA We find: positive effects on labour supply in all age classes (45+) for women, not for men effects on the husbands labour supply but not on the wives When evaluating the labour supply effect of policies increasing MRA, we should take into account the effect of a longer working horizon on individuals and their partners

Related literature and contribution On the direct effect of a longer working horizon: only Hairault et al. (2010): look at French reform, postponed RA by about 1 year, only men 57+. Positive but not significant effects (small sample) we look at younger individuals, also women, also their partners because very large and well-understood increase in MRA in Italy On within partner effects: comprehensive estimate of labour supply effects increasing quasi-experimental literature on joint labour supply and retirement decisions within the family [Coile 2004, Hospido Zamarro 2014, Bloemen et al. 2015, Lalive Perrotta 2017]

Graphical evidence: the Italian case Raise in labour force participation in 2012 (first year of implementation of the pension reform) Figure: Men Figure: Women LFPR -.05 0.05.1.15.2 2005 2010 2015 anno 61 62 63 64 65 MRA LFPR -.05 0.05.1.15 2005 2010 2015 anno 60 62 64 66 MRA 55-64 45-54 MRA (rhs axis) 55-64 45-54 MRA (rhs axis) Source: SHIW (Bank of Italy) for distance to retirement; Italian Labour Force Survey (Istat) for labour market indicators

The Treatment and The Data

Exogenous variation in MRA Before the reforms: 1. old age pension: RA 60 for women and 65 for men 2. seniority pension: the quota system (at least 35 years and minimum age requirements 58 or at least 40 years of contribution) After the reforms: 1. old age pension: RA 67 for women and for men 2. seniority pension: quota system abolished, at least 42 contribution years. Exceptions for women rules Example Most exposed women: those with more fragmented working lives; most exposed men: those with less fragmented working lives

RA under the old and and seniority system RA for women (men) increases more under the old age (seniority) pension regime Women Men 60 62 64 66 68 70 60 62 64 66 68 70 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 anno anno ret age seniority ret age old age ret age seniority ret age old age Source: SHIW, 2008-2010-2012-2014.

Most and least exposed individuals We define cells (q) based on the full interaction of the characteristics used to determine MRA: age, accrued years of contribution, gender, private/public, employee/self-employed Time invariant measure of exposure to the reform at the cell q level: Those which experience a larger increase in MRA due to the 2011-2012 pension reforms T q = MRA 2012 q MRA 2008 q

Distribution of the shock T q, by gender Women Men Freq. 0.1.2.3.4 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Freq. 0.1.2.3.4 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Source: SHIW, 2012-2014. Note: women (men) aged between 45 and 59 (45-64), with at least 10 (20) accrued years of contribution, eligible to retire neither before nor after the reform. Data are at the individual level. Men: most exposed (expect to retire under seniority regime) Women: most exposed (expect to retire under old age regime)

Data For now: the Italian Survey of Household Income and Wealth (SHIW) from 2004 to 2014 biannual survey on 8,000 households per wave information on accrued years of contribution information on partners (family level analysis) information on expected retirement age and benefits Now working on running the analysis with administrative social security data administrative data panel structure (previous employment status) information on absences and type of firms and jobs

Empirical Strategy and Results at the Individual Level

Main regression equation, individual level analysis Separately for men and women by age groups in 2004-2014: Y iqt = β 1 T q post2011 t + β 2 W iqt + α t + α q + ɛ iqt Y iqt is a dummy equal to 1 if the individual i in cell q is active at t T q is the time invariant measure of exposure to the policy post2011 t is a dummy that indicates the post reform period α q are the fixed effects for: age*years of contribution; α t are year-fixed effects W iqt are controls (marital status, region, sector) ɛ iqt is an error term standard errors clustered at the q level for individuals not eligible to retire even before the reform but reasonably close to retirement Descriptive statistics

Three identifying assumptions 1. Variations in MRA proxy variations in actual retirement age Individuals retire as soon as they become eligible Figure: Prob. of retiring and distance to MRA Men Women Pr. retired 0.5 1 Graphs by female -10 0 10 20-10 0 10 20 Distance to retirement Source: SHIW, 2008-2010-2012-2014. Note: Distance to retirement measures distance to minimum retirement age, depending on the time varying pension rules.

Three identifying assumptions 2. Expected retirement age changes according to the rules Expected RA increases more for treated individuals, women (men) with less (more) continuous working life Figure: Expected RA by continuity of previous working life Women Men Expected retirement age 60 62 64 66 68 70 Expected retirement age 60 62 64 66 68 70 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 Year Year less cont. working lives more cont. working lives less cont. working lives more cont. working lives Source: SHIW, 2008-2010-2012-2014. Note: continuity of one s working life depends on the amount of contribution years by age. No changes in expected benefits Expected RR

Three identifying assumptions 3. Parallel trends in the outcome, women Evolution of the difference in the probability of being active between more and less exposed individuals, women Y iqt = 2014 r=2004 γ r (T q δ r ) + γw iqt + δ q + δ t + η iqt Note: The graphs plots the coefficients γ r and the corresponding 5% confidence intervals.

Three identifying assumptions 3. Parallel trends in the outcome, men Evolution of the difference in the probability of being active between more and less exposed individuals, men Note: The graphs plots the coefficients γ r and the corresponding 5% confidence intervals.

Positive effects on female participation at all ages Women Men 55-59 50-54 45-49 55-64 50-54 45-49 [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] Dep. Var: 1=active T*post2011 0.026*** 0.015*** 0.008* 0.003-0.005 0.006 (0.006) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.004) Dep. Var: 1=unemployed T*post2011 0.009* 0.008** 0.010*** 0.000-0.008 0.013 (0.005) (0.004) (0.003) (0.008) (0.007) (0.012) Dep. Var: 1=employed T*post2011 0.016** 0.007-0.002 0.002 0.002-0.007 (0.007) (0.004) (0.005) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) N 1728 2751 2620 2668 3302 2789 Notes: Additional controls: year and cell q fixed effects, region and sector fixed effects, time fixed effects, marital status. Only individuals with at least 10 (20) accrued years of contribution, not eligible to retire even with pre-reform rules. Robust standard errors clustered at the cell q level in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Demand or supply?

Results Intensive margin of employment: all women are more likely to find employment in full time jobs, either moving from part-time to full-time (younger women) or moving from non-employment (older women). type Heterogeneity by education: effects concentrated on individuals with lower education levels (less than high school), because their marginal benefits from working and searching more are greater. education

Empirical Strategy and Results at the Household Level

Main regression equation, family level analysis We estimate the following equation for husbands and wives in 2004-2014: Y s jq s t = β s 1T qs post2011 t + β s 2W jt + α s q s + αs q s + α s t + u s jq s t Y s jq s t is a dummy that indicates the labour force status of spouse s in household j, where partner s belongs to age-contribution cell q s T qs is the time invariant indicator of the cells more exposed to the policy based on the observable characteristics of partner s α s q s and α s q s are fixed effects for the cell q s and q s; α s t are year-fixed effects W jt is a vector of controls at the individual and household level including changes in distance to retirement of spouse s (if different from s ) u s jq s t is an error term Partner s not eligible to retire even with pre-reform rules; partner s no restrictions Descriptive statistics

Evolution of the difference in the spouse s probability of being active between more and less exposed individuals Figure: Husbands, wife treated Figure: Wives, husbands treated Source: SHIW, from 2004 to 2014. Note The graphs test the parallel trend assumption by plotting the coefficients ζr s and the corresponding 5% confidence interval obtained from estimating equation Yiq s s t = ( ) 2014 r=2004 ζs r T qs αs r + β s W iqs t + α s q s + αs t + αs qs t + us iqt. Pre reform years: 2004-2006-2008-2010, post-reform years: 2012-2014.

Cross elasticities among partners shock to wife MRA shock to husb MRA on wife on husband on husband on wife [1] [2] [3] [4] Dep var. 1=active T wife*post2011 0.013** 0.014** (0.006) (0.007) T husb*post2011 0.000 0.006 (0.004) (0.007) Dep var. 1=unemployed T wife*post2011 0.010** 0.010*** (0.005) (0.004) T husb*post2011-0.005 0.006 (0.006) (0.004) Dep var. 1=employed T wife*post2011 0.003 0.002 (0.007) (0.007) T husb*post2011 0.004-0.001 (0.007) (0.007) N 3633 3633 3220 3220 Notes: Additional controls: year and cell q s and q s fixed effects, region and sector fixed effects, age difference across partners (also squared) and difference in distance to retirement across partners, partner s change in distance to retirement. The sample in columns 1 and 2 (3 and 4) consists of couples where the wives (husbands) are not eligible for a public pension either before and after the reform and have accrued more than 9 (19) and less than 40 years of contribution. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Results Husbands respond to their wives shock, the contrary does not hold no effect on husbands in the first place men belonging to couples in which the wife is treated are less likely to participate (already eligible to retire) the effect comes from men who postpone retirement some evidence men are very responsive to partner s behaviour (asymetric preferences joint leisure, hh production) [Zweimuller et al. 1996, Coile 2004, Bingley and Lanot 2007] Heterogeneity by education: low educated individuals are the ones who respond the most to changes in their spouse s working horizon, given the higher marginal utility from income education

Conclusion The effects of delaying MRA on labour supply go beyond those individuals who lose eligibility, it affects younger individuals whose working horizon increases Positive effects on women participation at different age, not on men; in particular on women less attached to the labour market (low educated) The effect has spillovers on their husbands participation Extensions: use administrative data and look at previous employment status and at differences on job quality and type obtain some information on reservation wages to explore the mechanisms

Thank you marta.dephilippis@bancaditalia.it

Seniority/early pension eligibility Private & Public Self-employed Year A, C, Q only C A, C, Q only C Before Fornero reform 2007 57, 35 39 58, 35 40 2008 58, 35 40 59, 35 40 2009-2010 59, 35, 95 40 60, 35, 96 40 2011 60, 35, 96 40 61, 35 97 40 2011-2012 60, 35, 96 40 61, 35, 97 40 2013 onwards 61, 35, 97 40 62, 35, 98 40 After Fornero reform 2012- (men) 43 43 2012- (women) 42 42 Women s option (only for women) 2008-57, 35 58, 35 Notes: A stands for age, C for number of years of contribution, Q = A + C is the so-called quota, the sum of age and years of contribution must be larger or equal than Q to have retirement eligibility. Independently from actual age, retirement eligibility is also granted when the number of years of contribution is sufficiently high (39 in 2007, 40 in the following years).

Examples of treated and control group Employees in the private sector Pre-2012 Post-2012 Delta distance Seniority Old Seniority Old (Post - Pre) Women, 58 years old Maria, C = 35 58 60 58 67 0 Antonia, C = 26 67 60 67 67 7 Men, 58 years old Mario, C = 35 58 65 66 67 8 Valerio, C = 26 67 65 75 67 2 Notes: Mandated retirement age by type of pension benefit for individuals working as employees in the private sector. C is the number of accrued years of contribution. Delta distance is the difference between the minimum retirement age (the minimum between the mandated retirement age for old age and seniority regime) after and before the reform that took place in 2012.

Descriptive statistics Women Men Control Treated Control Treated T q < 7 T q 7 T q < 4 T q 4 [1] [2] [3] [4] continuity w.l. 0.515 0.304 0.538 0.557 Age 51.110 51.193 54.859 50.301 (3.903) (4.386) (4.056) (3.947) Y. contrib 26.349 15.598 29.508 27.986 (6.314) (4.178) (6.573) (4.005) 1=married 0.727 0.736 0.847 0.851 1=sec. edu 0.640 0.502 0.423 0.585 1=children 0.269 0.347 0.353 0.194 1=active 0.916 0.741 0.955 0.992 1=unemployed 0.031 0.086 0.070 0.035 1=part time 0.127 0.174 0.021 0.013 1=perm. contr 0.700 0.433 0.623 0.709 log(wage net) 9.626 9.266 9.785 9.864 (0.487) (0.687) (0.459) (0.414) Observations 5711 1904 3306 5806 Notes: Men and women with at least 35 year old and 8 years of accrued contributions. Women (men) are treated if experienced a shock to distance to minimum retirement of >= 7 (>= 4) years after 2012 reform. Years 2004 and 2010. Continuity w.l.=y. contrib/age. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Characterizing the treatment: changes in expected benefits Source: SHIW, question on expected replacement rate. Note: The Figure shows that the replacement rate (the ratio between the monthly pension benefit and the last earned monthly wage) lowered around the reform (2012), but not in a different way across individuals with different continuity of the working life.

Results: demand or supply? women women women men men men 55-59 50-54 45-49 55-64 50-54 45-49 [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] Dep. Var: 1=active T*post2011 0.039*** 0.016** 0.002-0.012-0.009 0.004 (0.010) (0.007) (0.008) (0.010) (0.006) (0.003) T*post2011*low vacancy -0.023-0.013 0.011 0.028** 0.008-0.001 (0.015) (0.010) (0.011) (0.014) (0.009) (0.005) Dep. Var: 1=unemployed T*post2011 0.013 0.010* 0.003-0.011-0.006 0.016 (0.009) (0.005) (0.005) (0.014) (0.012) (0.010) T*post2011*low vacancy -0.016-0.001 0.011 0.019-0.022-0.018 (0.011) (0.008) (0.008) (0.016) (0.017) (0.023) Dep. Var: 1=employed T*post2011 0.026** 0.006-0.001-0.002-0.004-0.013 (0.013) (0.008) (0.008) (0.016) (0.014) (0.010) T*post2011*low vacancy -0.007-0.012 0.000 0.010 0.025 0.018 (0.017) (0.014) (0.011) (0.019) (0.021) (0.023) N 1355 2185 2158 2109 2710 2346 Notes: Additional controls: year and cell q fixed effects, region and sector fixed effects, time fixed effects, marital status. Only individuals with at least 10 and less than 40 accrued years of contribution. Robust standard errors clustered at the cell q level in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Results: type of employment women women women men men men 55-59 50-54 45-49 55-64 50-54 45-49 [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] Dep. Var: 1=employed full time T*post2011 0.013* 0.019*** 0.007-0.002 0.011-0.018 (0.007) (0.005) (0.006) (0.008) (0.010) (0.019) Dep. Var: 1=employed part-time T*post2011 0.005-0.011** -0.010* 0.000-0.002 0.011 (0.006) (0.005) (0.006) (0.004) (0.006) (0.009) N 1728 2751 2620 2668 3302 2789 Notes: Additional controls: year and cell q fixed effects, region and sector fixed effects, time fixed effects, marital status. Only individuals with at least 10 and less than 40 accrued years of contribution. Robust standard errors clustered at the cell q level in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Results: heterogeneity by education women women women men men men 55-59 50-54 45-49 55-64 50-54 45-49 [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] Dep. Var: 1=active T*post2011 0.028*** 0.022*** 0.008-0.003-0.004 0.003 (0.009) (0.007) (0.009) (0.008) (0.004) (0.007) T*post2011*high edu -0.012-0.016* 0.001 0.014 0.002 0.006 (0.010) (0.009) (0.011) (0.010) (0.006) (0.009) Dep. Var: 1=unemployed T*post2011 0.015* 0.020*** 0.020*** -0.010-0.006 0.002 (0.008) (0.007) (0.006) (0.016) (0.014) (0.020) T*post2011*high edu -0.013** -0.012** -0.010-0.018 0.014 0.007 (0.006) (0.005) (0.008) (0.013) (0.013) (0.015) Dep. Var: 1=employed T*post2011 0.013 0.002-0.013 0.009-0.001 0.001 (0.011) (0.009) (0.011) (0.016) (0.014) (0.024) T*post2011*high edu -0.009-0.017** -0.014** 0.018-0.001 0.018 (0.009) (0.007) (0.007) (0.018) (0.016) (0.020) N 1728 2751 2620 2668 3302 2789 Notes: Additional controls: year and cell q fixed effects, region and sector fixed effects, time fixed effects, marital status. Only individuals with at least 10 and less than 40 accrued years of contribution. High edu is a dummy equal to 1 if individuals obtained at least the secondary school degree. Robust standard errors clustered at the cell q level in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.

Descriptive statistics at the family level Treated Wives Treated Husbands Control Treated Control Treated Tq w < 7 T q w 7 T q h < 4 T q h 4 [1] [2] [3] [4] Cont. w.l. w 0.516 0.304 0.300 0.308 Cont. w.l. h 0.579 0.544 0.542 0.556 Age w 51.154 51.292 51.512 47.143 (3.972) (4.452) (4.943) (5.032) Age h 54.046 53.822 54.784 50.204 (5.383) (6.136) (4.047) (3.939) Y. contrib w 26.412 15.568 15.468 14.499 (6.468) (4.208) (13.362) (11.507) Y. contrib h 31.321 29.306 29.701 27.918 (8.238) (10.447) (6.512) (4.011) 1=children 0.280 0.336 0.343 0.163 1=active w 0.907 0.691 0.544 0.632 1=active h 0.831 0.799 0.961 0.993 1=unempl w 0.033 0.109 0.040 0.046 1=unempl h 0.036 0.058 0.075 0.028 Observations 3103 1066 2074 3485 Notes panel a: Sample of cohabiting women aged 45-59, with at least 10 years of contr, not eligible to retire with pre-2012 rules. Notes panel b: Sample married men aged 45-64, with at least 20 years of contr, not eligible to retire with pre-2012 rules.

Results: heterogeneity by education shock to wife MRA shock to husb MRA on wife on husband on husband on wife [1] [2] [3] [4] T s *post2011 0.020** 0.019** 0.003 0.002 (0.008) (0.009) (0.007) (0.010) T s *post 2011*edu s -0.015* -0.004-0.004 0.009 (0.008) (0.008) (0.008) (0.014) Dep var. 1=unemployed T s *post2011 0.019*** 0.013** -0.018 0.002 (0.007) (0.005) (0.011) (0.007) T s *post 2011*edu s -0.015** -0.004 0.021 0.005 (0.006) (0.005) (0.014) (0.008) Dep var. 1=employed T s *post2011 0.001 0.004 0.021* -0.000 (0.009) (0.009) (0.012) (0.010) T s *post 2011*edu s -0.001-0.001-0.026* 0.005 (0.009) (0.008) (0.015) (0.014) N 3633 3633 3220 3220 Notes: Additional controls: year and cell q s and q s fixed effects, region and sector fixed effects, age difference across partners (also squared) and difference in distance to retirement across partners, partner s change in distance to retirement. The sample in columns 1 and 2 (3 and 4) consists of couples where the wives (husbands) are not eligible for a public pension either before and after the reform and have accrued more than 9 (19) and less than 40 years of contribution. High edu is a dummy equal to 1 at least the secondary school degree. Robust standard errors. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.