Sectoral Shocks, Mismatch and Monetary Policy

Similar documents
Welfare-based optimal monetary policy with unemployment and sticky prices: A linear-quadratic framework

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Welfare-based optimal monetary policy with unemployment and sticky prices: A linear-quadratic framework

E cient Minimum Wages

A DSGE model with unemployment and the role of institutions

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

Calvo Wages in a Search Unemployment Model

In ation and Labor Market Dynamics Revisited

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Staggered Wages, Sticky Prices, and Labor Market Dynamics in Matching Models. by Janett Neugebauer and Dennis Wesselbaum

Dynamic Macroeconomics

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Monetary Policy and Resource Mobility

Reconciling the Effects of Monetary Policy Actions on Consumption within a Heterogeneous Agent Framework

Fiscal Expansions Can Increase Unemployment: Theory and Evidence from OECD countries

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

INSTITUT UNIVERSITAIRE DE HAUTES ETUDES INTERNATIONALES THE GRADUATE INSTITUTE OF INTERNATIONAL STUDIES, GENEVA. HEI Working Paper No: 01/2008

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Welfare

The Role of Labour Markets for Fiscal Policy Transmission

Simple e ciency-wage model

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Uncertainty Shocks and Monetary Smoothness in a DSGE model

Monetary Policy in the Presence of Informal Labor Markets

Week 8: Fiscal policy in the New Keynesian Model

Unemployment benets, precautionary savings and demand

The Welfare Consequences of Monetary Policy and the Role of the Labor Market: a Tax Interpretation

Welfare-based optimal monetary policy with. unemployment and sticky prices: A. linear-quadratic framework

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Macroeconomics of the Labor Market

Lecture 3: Employment and Unemployment

1 Unemployment Insurance

Unemployment Persistence, Inflation and Monetary Policy, in a Dynamic Stochastic Model of the Natural Rate.

Labor market search, sticky prices, and interest rate policies

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics

Monetary Policy and Unemployment

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Understanding Unemployment through the Lens of Search and Growth Theory:

Quadratic Labor Adjustment Costs and the New-Keynesian Model. by Wolfgang Lechthaler and Dennis Snower

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Labour Market and Monetary Policy

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Positive and Normative Effects of a Minimum Wage

Mismatch shocks and unemployment during the. Great Recession (preliminary)

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

Quantity Rationing of Credit and the Phillips Curve

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

The Role of Real Wage Rigidity and Labor Market Frictions for Inflation Persistence

Optimal Monetary Policy

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

1 A Simple Model of the Term Structure

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Lecture 6 Search and matching theory

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Involuntary (Unlucky) Unemployment and the Business Cycle. Lawrence Christiano Mathias Trabandt Karl Walentin

The Fundamental Surplus in Matching Models. European Summer Symposium in International Macroeconomics, May 2015 Tarragona, Spain

Cost Channel, Interest Rate Pass-Through and Optimal Monetary Policy under Zero Lower Bound

Consumption-Savings Decisions and State Pricing

Monetary Policy and the Financing of Firms

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of

The Role of Physical Capital

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Optimal Unemployment Bene ts Policy and the Firm Productivity Distribution

ECON Micro Foundations

7 Unemployment. 7.1 Introduction. JEM004 Macroeconomics IES, Fall 2017 Lecture Notes Eva Hromádková

In ation Premium and Oil Price Uncertainty

Risk Premiums and Macroeconomic Dynamics in a Heterogeneous Agent Model

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

Monetary Economics Lecture 5 Theory and Practice of Monetary Policy in Normal Times

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Chapters 1 & 2 - MACROECONOMICS, THE DATA

Samba: Stochastic Analytical Model with a Bayesian Approach. DSGE Model Project for Brazil s economy

Monetary Policy, In ation, and the Business Cycle. Chapter 5. Monetary Policy Tradeo s: Discretion vs Commitment Jordi Galí y CREI and UPF August 2007

Firms and Flexibility

Discussion of Unemployment Crisis

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Topics in Modern Macroeconomics

Matching frictions, unemployment dynamics and optimal monetary policy

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MARGINAL JOBS, HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS, & UNEMPLOYMENT FLOWS. Michael W. L. Elsby Ryan Michaels

Unemployment Fiscal Multiplier in a Small Open Economy. with Labor Market Frictions

Asymmetric Labor Market Institutions in the EMU and the Volatility of In ation and Unemployment Di erentials

The Maturity Structure of Debt, Monetary Policy and Expectations Stabilization

Transcription:

Sectoral Shocks, Mismatch and Monetary Policy Tim Bian y and Pedro Gete z October 20. PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE Abstract This paper studies monetary policy in a two sector economy facing sector speci c shocks, search frictions and mismatch between unemployed workers and vacant jobs. We compare the performance of interest rate rules that target the aggregate economy versus interest rate rules that are sector speci c. We show that in an economy hit with sector speci c shocks and labor mismatch there are considerable di erences from taking into account, or not, sectorial considerations in the Taylor rule. For example, for in ation there is a tradeo between the size of the deviations from steady state versus the speed of recovery of the shock. These results con rm concerns recently expressed by policy makers as Kocherlakota (200). We are very grateful to Behzad Diba and Dale Henderson for their comments and encouragement. We also thank Jim Albrecht for useful references. y Email: yb33@georgetown.edu z Email: pg252@georgetown.edu

Introduction Do aggregate or sectoral shocks drive cyclical unemployment? This was a popular question in the 980s as economists discussed if oil shocks and the shift from manufacturing to services could explain the observed high rates of unemployment (see for example Lilien 982 or Hamilton 988). Following the work of Abraham and Katz (986), the question seemed resolved in favor of aggregate shocks. Consequently, all models that have integrated unemployment in the standard New Keynesian (NK) model of monetary policy assume aggregate shocks as the cause of unemployment uctuations. However, the fact that the last three recessions have been "Jobless Recoveries", together with the impressive housing boom and bust of the last decade, and the increasing shift of employment away from manufacturing, have brought back the question to the academic and policy arena. 2 Moreover, in housing boom/bust countries as Spain, the U.K. or the U.S. it is quite popular the view that sectorial shocks came associated with a mismatch in skills or geographical location between unemployed workers and vacant jobs. 34 The support comes from three facts: ) most of the job losses in the recent recession were in housing related sectors and in manufacturing while the newly created jobs were in health care or education. 2) The bust in housing prices prevents households with high mortgages from selling their homes and moving to locations with lower unemployment. 3) The Beveridge curve (the observed negative relationship between the unemployment rate and the vacancy rate) has shifted in a way that is consistent with mismatch. In this paper we analyze the monetary policy implications of sectorial shocks when there is mismatch between workers and vacancies. To do so we setup a two sector NK model where unemployment arises from matching frictions à la Mortensen and Pissarides (994) with exogenous job separations. There is monopolistic competition and adjustment cost on pricing à la Rotemberg (982) that give raise to nonneutral e ects of monetary policy. 5 We start with the simplifying assumption that mismatch is extreme, i.e. workers unemployed in one sector cannot work in other sector. This assumption rules out the labor reallocation channel. We focus on The standard NK model does not feature unemployment, only hours worked per worker vary over the business cycle. However, several papers have incorporated unemployment into the NK framework: Blanchard and Galí (200), Chéron and Langot (2000), Christo el et al. (2009), Faia (2008 and 2009), Gertler et al. (2008), Gertler and Trigari (2009), Krause and Lubik (2007), Krause et al. (2008), Ravenna and Walsh (2008 and 200), Sala et al. (2008), Thomas (2008), Trigari (2009) or Walsh (2005). 2 See for example Aaronson et al. (2004), Groshen and Potter (2003), Phelps (2008), The Economist (200), Valletta and Cleary (2008). 3 For example Elsby et al. (200), Kocherlakota (200), Phelps (2008), Sahin et al (200) 4 quote Phelan-Trejos (2000) 5 For simplicity we do not impose wage rigidities. Hence our model su ers the volatility puzzle pointed out by Shimer (2005) about the search and matching model. 2

the e ects of monetary policy in the economy when it tries to counteract sector speci c shocks via countercyclical demand management policies. First we perform a comparison across di erent monetary policy rules. We compare the performance of interest rate rules that target the aggregate economy versus interest rate rules that are sector speci c. We show that in an economy hit with sector speci c shocks and labor mismatch there are considerable di erences from taking into account, or not, sectorial considerations in the Taylor rule. For example, for in ation there is a trade-o between the size of the deviations from steady state versus the speed of recovery of the shock. These results con rm concerns recently expressed by policy makers as Kocherlakota (200). The paper proceeds as follows. Sections 2 describes the model. Section 3 shows the equilibrium conditions. Section 4 explains the calibration. Section 5 discusses the results and Section 6 concludes. 2 Model The model is based on New Keynesian model with search and matching frictions studied by Faia (2008) and Krause and Lubik (2007), which we augmented to include two sectors and mismatch friction. 6 In the economy, there is one representative household, which is composed of two kinds of workers: type-a workers and type-b workers; There are two industry sectors, A and B, producing di erent nal goods separately. 2. Labor Markets In each sector, there is a labor market with search and matching frictions that prevent some job-seekers from nding a job and some vacancies from being lled. New workers must be hired from the unemployment pool and posting a vacancy involves a xed cost. Wages are determined through Nash bargaining. 7 Each worker can be employed or unemployed. We assume that unemployed workers do not receive any income. The household sends her unemployed workers to search in one sector or another.we denote by L i the quantity of labor force for type-i workers, by N i j;t the type-i workers employed during 6 In these papers the price setting and employment decisions are embedded within the same rm. 7 Shimer (2005) and Hall (2005) noticed that in a matching model a la Mortensen and Pissarides wages are too volatile since little adjustment takes place along the employment margin. They also noticed that the introduction of real wage rigidity helps to resolve some of the puzzling features of the standard matching model. 3

period t in sector j; by U i j;t the type-i workers who are unemployed and make decision at period t on which sector j to apply to next period. Thus, U i A;t + U i B;t = U i t = L i (N i A;t + N i B;t) () u i t = U t i L i (2) N j;t = Nj;t A + Nj;t B (3) where u i t is the unemployment rate for type-i workers, and N j;t is the total employment in sector j. Here i = fa; Bg and j = fa; Bg. We assume exogenous job separations at rate, and that workers laid o at period t cannot start looking for a job until next period. When unemployed workers look for jobs, there is a mismatch friction if a certain type workers search in the sector requiring di erent skills: fraction of them cannot nd a job. This can be interpreted as if they have to devote a number of hours to learn the skill required in the other sector. Thus, if rms post vacancies V j;t in sector j s labor market, the amount of new hires in that sector is given by the following Cobb Douglas matching functions m(ua;t A + ( )UA;t B ; V A;t ) = m A (UA;t A + ( )UA;t B ) (V A;t ) (4) m(( )UB;t A + UB;t B ; V B;t ) = m B (( )UB;t A + UB;t B ) (V B;t ) (5) Among the newly matched workers in sector j we assume there is a same probability they have the skill A or B: In other words, the fraction of newly matched workers that are of type A is just the fraction of type A unemployed workers looking for a job in that sector. Also assuming that workers hired at period t can produce immediately, the law of motion for employment of type-a workers are U A A;t NA;t A = ( )NA;t A + UA;t A + ( )U m A;t B A (UA;t A + ( )UA;t B ; V A;t ) (6) ( )U NB;t A = ( )NB;t A B;t A + ( )UB;t A + U m B;t B B (( )UB;t A + UB;t B ; V B;t ) (7) 4

We de ne the market tightness for each sector as A;t = B;t = V A;t U A A;t + ( )U B A;t V B;t ( )U A B;t + U B B;t (8) (9) The probability that an unemployed worker is hired in each sector is p( A;t ) m(u A;t A + ( )U A;t B ; V A;t) UA;t A + ( )U A;t B p( B;t ) m(( )U B;t A + U B;t B ; V B;t) ( )UB;t A + U B;t B (0) () and the probability that a vacancy is lled in each sector is q( A;t ) m(u A A;t + ( )U B A;t ; V A;t) V A;t (2) q( B;t ) m(( )U A B;t + U B B;t ; V B;t) V B;t (3) Using these new variables we can rewrite (6) and (7) as N A A;t = ( )N A A;t + p( A;t )U A A;t (4) N A B;t = ( )N A B;t + p( B;t )( )U A B;t (5) Samely, the law of motion for employment of type-b workers are N B A;t = ( )N B A;t + p( A;t )( )U B A;t (6) N B B;t = ( )N B B;t + p( B;t )U B B;t (7) And the total employment in each sector evolves as N A;t = ( )N A;t + q( A;t )V A;t (8) N B;t = ( )N B;t + q( B;t )V B;t (9) 5

2.2 Household The household is composed of type-a and type-b workers. We follow the literature that incorporates unemployment into New Keynesian models and assume that workers are able to insure against idiosyncratic consumption risk. 8 The household has CRRA time additively separable preferences, with discount factor and intertemporal elasticity of substitution X E 0 t u(c t ) (20) t=0 u(c t ) = (C t) Within each period she consumes goods from the two sectors according to CES preferences (2) C t = [ A;t (c A;t ) " " + B;t (c B;t ) " " ] " " (22) where " is the intratemporal elasticity of substitution, and j;t is a demand preference for good j. We assume that demand preference A;t follow AR() process log A;t A = log A;t A + " A;t (23) " A;t N(0; A 2) (24) where " A;t is a shock speci c to sector A. The household s problem is to decide consumption of each type of good, her savings in nominal risk free bonds (B t ) subject to her budget constraint, and the number of unemployed workers to look for jobs in each sector (UA;t A ; U B;t A ; U A;t B ; U B;t B ) subject to law of motion for employment. If we denote by p A;t the price in dollars of one good A, and by p B;t the price of one good B, then preference (22) implies that the price ( ) of one unit of aggregate consumption (C t ) is = ( A;t ) " (p A;t ) " + ( B;t ) " (p B;t ) " " (25) 8 Andolfatto (996) models an institutional structure that allows workers to insure themselves against earning uncertainty and unemployment. Basically the wage earnings have to be interpreted as net of insurance costs. 6

and the in ation rates are Moreover, household s demand for goods j satis es t = (26) j;t = p j;t, p j;t j = A; B (27) " c j;t = ( j;t ) " pj;t C t (28) The household s budget constraint in units of aggregate consumption is B t + C t R t B t + w A;t (N A A;t + N B A;t) + w B;t (N A B;t + N B B;t) + A;t + B;t (29) where j;t are the pro ts of the rm in sector j; w j;t are wages and R t rate between period t and t. is the nominal interest 2.3 Firms In each sector j there is a representative rm that takes wages as given and behaves as a monopolist in the good that it produces. It chooses prices (p j;t ) ; employment (N j;t ) and vacancies (V j;t ) to maximize the discounted value of its pro ts " X p j;t p j;t E 0 0;t y j;t w j;t N j;t V j;t t=0 2 p j;t pj;t y j;t# 2 p j;t (30) where 2 pj;t p j;t 2 yj;t is the cost of adjusting prices and is the sluggishness in the price adjustment process. The variable 0;t is the household s stochastic discount factor to be de ned in next section. The parameter is the cost of posting a job vacancy. If the search process is successful, the rm produces according to a technology that is linear in labor where z j = is a productivity scale parameter for sector j. y j;t = z j;t N j;t (3) The rm s problem in sector j is to maximize (30) subject to law of motion (8) (or equation 7

(9)); (3), and the equation that internalizes the pricing power of the rm " y j;t = ( j;t ) " pj;t C t (32) 2.4 Wage determination Wages are obtained through Nash Bargaining, i.e., in sector j the wages solve where is the worker s bargaining power. 9 max w j;t (J j;t ) (W j;t T t ) (33) In general form, J j;t is the value of an additional worker for the rm in sector j. W j;t is the value of an additinal worker being employed in sector j. T t is the value of an additinal worker being unemployed. The next equations de ne these values in detail. For the rm in sector j: J j;t = j;t z j;t w j;t + E t t;t+ f( )(J j;t+ )g (34) where j;t denotes the Lagrange Multiplier associated with constraint (32) : Free entry implies that the value of an additional vacancy for the rm must be zero. For type-a and type-b workers employed in sector j: W A j;t = w j;t + E t t;t+ ( W B j;t = w j;t + E t t;t+ ( )W A j;t+ + T A t+ (35) )W B j;t+ + T B t+ (36) For unemployed workers, they make decision on which sector to search in, T A t T B t = max = max E t t;t+ p(a;t+ )WA;t+ A + [ p( A;t+)]Tt+ A ; E t t;t+ p(b;t+ )( )WB;t+ A + [ p( B;t+)( )]Tt+ A E t t;t+ fp( A;t+ )( )WA;t+ B + [ p( A;t+)( )]Tt+g; B E t t;t+ fp( B;t+ )WB;t+ B + [ p( B;t+)]T B t+g!! (37) (38) Given our negative demand shock in sector A, type-a workers will look for jobs in both sec- 9 We will assume that the rm s bargaining power is equal to the elasticity of the matching function with respect to vacancies ( = ). This is Hosios (990) condition for rms to internalize the congestions that they create in the labor market in a way that leads them to post the e cient number of vacancies. 8

tors(they are indi erent to either sector), while type-b workers only prefer to search in sector B. Then the above two equations (37) and (38) can be rewritten as E t t;t+ p(a;t+ )(W A A;t+ T A t+) = E t t;t+ p(b;t+ )( )(W A B;t+ T A t+) (39) T B t = E t t;t+ fp( B;t+ )W B B;t+ + [ p( B;t+)]T B t+g (40) So wages in sector A (w A;t ) is obtained through which implies that in sector A, there are only type-a workers. While wages in sector B (w B;t ) is obtained through max w B;t (J B;t ) " max w A;t (J A;t ) (W A A;t T A t ) (4) N A B;t N A B;t + N B B;t (W A B;t T A t ) + N B B;t N A B;t + N B B;t which implies that in sector B, there are both type-a and type-b workers. (W B B;t T B t )# (42) 2.5 Monetary Policy Rules Interest targeting rules are widely employed in New Keynesian models because such rules are thought to provide both a good positive description of, and a normative prescription for, monetary policy (Ang et al. 2007, Clarida et al. 2000, Taylor 993, Taylor and Williams 200, Woodford 200). We investigate the performance of two alternative types of nominal interest rate rules: R t = R r t ) Rules focused on aggregate variables: " t # u r R u t (43) u t = t (44) X u t = u t i=a;b U i t X (45) L i i=a;b 9

2) Rules adjusted for sectorial shocks: t = f A;t ; B;t g (46) u t = u A t ; u B t (47) where u t and u i t are respectively the aggregate and worker type speci c unemployment rates. Variables with asterisk denote steady-state values. The parameter r is the degree of policy rate smoothing, and u are non-negative policy coe cients on aggregate or sectorial in ation and unemployment rates. 3 Calibration We calibrate the model following Faia (2008(Faia 2008)). We set a period to be a quarter. There are three sets of parameters to choose: - Preferences: We set the discount factor = 0:99; which implies an annual interest rate of 4%. As in most of the real business cycle literature we assume = 0:5; which under CRRA preferences implies a value for risk aversion of 2. Concerning the intratemporal elasticity of substitution between goods in two sectors (") ; we assume " = :7. A number in the ballpark of those assigned to the elasticity of substitution between housing and other goods. 0 At rst we assume the same share of consumption in each good (the steady state A = B = ), but 2 later give more weight to the consumption of good B ( A = 0:4; B = 0:6). We assume the persistence of the demand shock = 0:95. - Technology: As discussed in Krause and Lubik (2003), the choice for the value of price adjustment cost ranges from 20 to 05: We choose an intermediate value = 40: - Labor Market: We assume there are type-a and type-b workers with the same amount of labor force L A = L B =. We assume the bargaining power of the workers to be = 0:5: To satisfy the Hosios condition we set the elasticity of the unemployed in the matching function to = 0:5. The exogenous job separation rate is assumed 0:0. These last values are standard in the literature (Faia 2008). The scale parameters of the matching function (m A ; m B ) and the cost of posting a vacancy () are calibrated, to match a steady-state unemployment rate of 0% in each sector and a steady-state probability that a vacancy is lled q() = 0:9. For comparison purpose, we let the mismatch friction to range from 0 to. 0 See Gete (200) for references 0

Table summarizes our parameter choices Insert Table here 4 Results 4. Mismatch Friction This section examines the dynamic of variables in response to an increasing mismatch friction, both under steady-state conditions and facing a negative demand shock. We set parameters A = 0:4 and B = 0:6 (the household prefers consumption of good B), so that a fraction of type-a workers look for jobs in sector B (and incur mismatch frictions), while type-b workers never look for jobs in sector A. Figure shows the change in selected variable values under steady-state condition, when the parameter for mismatch friction () ranges from 0 to the value at which there is no crosssector job search. Facing an increasing, unemployed type-a workers are less willing to look for jobs in sector B, and fewer of them manage to enter sector B s labor market so that the proportion of type-a workers employed in sector B keeps decreasing. In turn, unemployed type-a workers are more willing to search in sector A, and more of them get employed. On the other hand, total number of unemployed workers (type-a and type-b combined) searching in sector B decreases, then there are fewer employed workers in sector B. The production and consumption of good A increases while the production and consumption of good B decreases, causing aggregate consumption to decrease. The aggregate unemployment rate displays an "inverse U" shape, which means the total number of unemployed rst increases along with mismatch friction () until a maximum level, then starts to decrease with mismatch friction. This is mainly due to the number of unemployed type-a workers who fail to reach sector B s labor market ( UAB, those who get unemployed due to mismatch). This number also displays an "inverse U" shape: rst goes up along with an increasing, later decreases due to a shrinking UAB. Insert Figure here Figure 2 shows impulse responses of selected variables to a negative demand shock in sector A, under di erent mismatch frictions ( = 0: v.s. = 0:4). Here monetary policy targets

aggregate variables ( t and u t ). As shown, unemployment uctuation is larger, and interest rate adjustment is larger, for higher value of. This implies that when mismatch friction is large, facing a negative demand shock to sector A, there are more unemployment in type-a workers when they decide to search for jobs in sector B. And the monetary authority has to adjust their interest rate more facing a higher unemployment. Insert Figure 2 here 4.2 Monetary Policy This section examines the impulse responses of several key variables to a negative demand shock in sector A, under di erent monetary policy rules. There are three monetary policy rules that respond to in ation and unemployment: ) Targeting aggregate in ation ( t ) and aggregate unemployment (u t ) ; 2) Targeting in ation in sector A (t A ) and unemployment rate of type-a workers (u A t ):3) Targeting in ation in sector B (t B ) and unemployment rate of type-b workers (u B t ): All rules assume = :5, u = 0:5 and interest rate smoothing weight r = 0:9. Mismatch friction = 0:. In Figure 3, after a negative demand shock in sector A, rms in sector A lower good A s price. They also cut o their production and vacancy posting, so the unemployment rate for type-a workers increases. As consumers shift their relative demand to goods B, rms in sector B increase their production, post more vacancies and hire more workers. The unemployment rate of type-b worker decreases. For the whole economy, aggregate price decreases, which causes a negative change in in ation rate. This leads the central bank to lower the nominal interest rate. Comparing three di erent monetary rules, we notice that policy rule 3 which focus on B t and u B t causes the least deviation from steady state, while policy rule 2 which focus on A t and u A t causes the largest deviation. The policy targeting aggregate variables falls in the middle. Insert Figure 3 here Figure 4 displays the Phillips curves corresponding to three monetary policy rules. We can conclude that the policy rule 3 which targeting B t and u B t is better than the rest two, since with the same unemployment rate, this rule will cause the least in ation. Insert Figure 4 here 2

5 Conclusions To be added 3

6 Tables and Figures Parameters Table : Benchmark calibration Value Discount factor: 0:99 Intratemporal Elasticity of Substitution: " :7 Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution: 2 Demand for good A: A 2 Demand for good B: B 2 Labor force: L A = L B Scale parameter for matching function: m A ; m A 0:9 Elasticity of unemployed in matching function: 2 Job separation rate: 0:0 Vacancy posting cost: 0:28 Worker s bargaining power: 2 Sluggishness in price adjustment process: 40 Autoregressive coe cient demand shock: z 0:95 Mismatch friction: [0; ] Notes: This table shows the parameters used to numerically solve the model and construct the gures of Section 5. The parameter values are discussed in page 9. 4

% 0.6 Aggregate Unemployment rate 6 x 0 3Type A worker unemployed due to mismatch friction 0.4 5 0.2 0. 4 0.08 3 0.06 2 0.04 0.02 0 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0.05 Unemployed type A workers in sector A 0.25 Unemployed workers (A and B) in sector B 0. 0.2 0.095 0.5 0.09 0. 0.085 0.08 0.05 0.075 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0. 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0.2 Proportion of type A workers employed in sector B 0.95 Aggregate Consumption 0.8 0.6 0.9 0.4 0.905 0.2 0. 0.9 0.08 0.06 0.895 0.04 0.89 0.02 0 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0.885 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0.9 Consumption of good A. Consumption of good B 0.85.05 0.8 0.75 0.95 0.7 0.9 0.65 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction 0.85 0 0.05 0. 0.5 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 mismatch friction Figure : Steady-state conditions with increasing mismatch friction 5

% Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS 2 3 Demand Shock to Sector A 45 40 Unemployment Rate tau = 0. tau = 0.4 4 35 5 30 6 25 7 20 8 9 tau = 0. tau = 0.4 5 0 20 5 2 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0.2 0.3 Aggregate Inflation 0. 0 Interest rate tau = 0. tau = 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.5 0.3 0.6 0.4 0.7 0.5 0.8 0.6 0.9 0.7 tau = 0. tau = 0.4. 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0.8 0.9 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock Figure 2: Impulse responses to negative demand shock in sector A for di erent mismatch frictions 6

% Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS % Deviation from SS 2 Demand Shock to Sector A 0.2 Nominal Interest Rate 3 0 4 0.2 5 6 0.4 7 0.6 8 0.8 9 20 2 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after Shock.2 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0 Aggregate Inflation 40 Aggregate Unemployment 0.2 35 30 0.4 25 0.6 20 0.8 5 0.2 5.4 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0 Inflation in Sector A 40 Unemployed type A workers 0.5 20 00.5 80 60 2 40 2.5 20 3 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 0 Inflation in Sector B 20 Unemployed type B workers 0.2 0 0 0.4 0 0.6 20 0.8 30 40 50.2 60.4 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock 70 0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Number of Periods after shock Figure 3: Impulse responses to negative demand shock in sector A for Taylor Rules. The solid, dashed, and dotted line correspond to Taylor rules that target aggregate variables, Sector A & type-a worker variables and Sector B & type-b worker variables, respectively. 7

Figure 4: Phillips Curve for di erent monetary policy rules. 8

References Aaronson, D., Rissman, E. and Sullivan, D.: 2004, Can sectoral reallocation explain the jobless recovery?, Economic Perspectives-Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 28, 36 49. Blanchard, O. and Gali, J.: 200, Labor markets and monetary policy: A New Keynesian model with unemployment, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(2), 30. Chéron, A. and Langot, F.: 2000, The Phillips and Beveridge curves revisited, Economics Letters 69(3), 37 376. Christo el, K., Kuester, K. and Linzert, T.: 2009, The role of labor markets for euro area monetary policy, European Economic Review 53(8), 908 936. Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M.: 2000, Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory, Quarterly journal of economics 5(), 47 80. Elsby, M., Hobijn, B. and Şahin, A.: 200, The labor market in the great recession, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 200(), 48. Faia, E.: 2008, Optimal monetary policy rules with labor market frictions, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32(5), 600 62. Faia, E.: 2009, Ramsey monetary policy with labor market frictions, Journal of Monetary Economics 56(4), 570 58. Gertler, M., Sala, L. and Trigari, A.: 2008, An estimated monetary DSGE model with unemployment and staggered nominal wage bargaining, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40(8), 73 764. Gertler, M. and Trigari, A.: 2009, Unemployment Fluctuations with Staggered Nash Wage Bargaining, Journal of Political Economy 7(). Gete, P.: n.d., Housing Markets and Current Account Dynamics. Groshen, E. and Potter, S.: 2003, Has structural change contributed to a jobless recovery?, Current Issues in Economics and Finance 9(8), 7. Hamilton, J.: 988, A neoclassical model of unemployment and the business cycle, The Journal of Political Economy 96(3), 593 67. Hosios, A.: 990, On the e ciency of matching and related models of search and unemployment, The Review of Economic Studies 57(2), 279 298. 9

Kocherlakota, N.: 200, Inside the FOMC, Speech delivered August. Krause, M., Lopez-Salido, D. and Lubik, T.: 2008, In ation dynamics with search frictions: A structural econometric analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics 55(5), 892 96. Krause, M. and Lubik, T.: 2007, The (ir) relevance of real wage rigidity in the new Keynesian model with search frictions, Journal of Monetary Economics 54(3), 706 727. Lilien, D.: 982, Sectoral shifts and cyclical unemployment, The Journal of Political Economy 90(4), 777 793. Mortensen, D. and Pissarides, C.: 994, Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment, The Review of Economic Studies 6(3), 397 45. Phelps, E.: 2008, US Monetary Policy and the Prospective Structural Slump, Speech to the 7th Annual BIS Conference on Monetary Policy, Luzern, Switzerland. Ravenna, F. and Walsh, C.: 2008, Vacancies, unemployment, and the Phillips curve, European Economic Review 52(8), 494 52. Ravenna, F. and Walsh, C.: 200, Welfare-based optimal monetary policy with unemployment and sticky prices: A linear-quadratic framework, AEJ Macro. Rotemberg, J.: 982, Monopolistic price adjustment and aggregate output, The Review of Economic Studies 49(4), 57 53. Sahin, A., Song, J., Topa, G. and Violante, G.: 200, Mismatch in the Labor Market: Evidence from the UK and the US. Sala, L., Soderstrom, U. and Trigari, A.: 2008, Monetary policy under uncertainty in an estimated model with labor market frictions, Journal of Monetary Economics 55(5), 983 006. Shimer, R.: 2005, The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies, American economic review 95(), 25 49. Taylor, J.: 993, Discretion versus policy rules in practice, Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy, Vol. 39, Elsevier, pp. 95 24. The Economist: Aug 26th 200, There is more to America s stubbornly high unemployment rate than just weak demand. Thomas, C.: 2008, Search and matching frictions and optimal monetary policy, Journal of Monetary Economics 55(5), 936 956. 20

Trigari, A.: 2009, Equilibrium unemployment, job ows, and in ation dynamics, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 4(), 33. Valletta, R. and Cleary, A.: 2008, Sectoral reallocation and unemployment, FRBSF Economic Letter (Oct 7). Walsh, C.: 2005, Labor market search, sticky prices, and interest rate policies, Review of Economic Dynamics 8(4), 829 849. Woodford, M.: 200, The Taylor rule and optimal monetary policy, American Economic Review 9(2), 232 237. 2

7 Appendix 7. Equilibrium conditions In the competitive equilibrium, household and rms optimize, the Central Bank follows the policy rule (43) and markets clear. Household s optimal consumption and savings are determined by (28), the Euler equation and the budget constraints u 0 Pt (C t ) = R t E t u 0 (C t+ ) + (48) C t = w A;t (N A A;t + N B A;t) + w B;t (N A B;t + N B B;t) + A;t + B;t (49) From our CRRA assumption (2) we can de ne the household s stochastic discount factor t;t+ = Ct+ C t (50) Given our negative demand shock in sector A, the household s optimal choices on the number of unemployed workers to apply to each sector are determined by the following three equations: mc A t = E t m A ( A;t+ ) [U 0 (C t+ )w A;t+ mc A t+] (5) mc A t = E t m B ( B;t+ ) ( ) U 0 (C t+ )w B;t+ mc A t+ (52) mc B t = E t m B ( B;t+ ) [U 0 (C t+ )w B;t+ mc B t+] (53) UA;t B = 0 (54) where mc i t denotes the Lagrange Multiplier associated with labor force constraint (), and is the utility value from an additional type-i worker. The optimal choice of vacancies and prices for a rm in sector j is given by p j;t q( j;t ) = pj;t+ j;tz j;t w j;t + ( )E t t;t+ + q( j;t+ ) " ( j;t ) " Ct ( p j;t ) " V j;t ( j;t ) j;t ( ") ( 2 j;t ) 2 h " i pj;t + j;t " + Et t;t+ ( j;t+ ) ( j;t+ ) 2 " ( t ) " j;t+ Ct+ j;t C t = 0 (55) (56) 22

where we have used (28) to get rid of the sectoral consumption variables. Equation (55) implies that in equilibrium the cost of posting a vacancy must equate the discounted expected return of a lled vacancy. The solution to the Nash Bargaining problem in sector A (4) gives the wage w A;t = ( A;t z A;t + E t t;t+ p A;t+ + A;t+ ) (57) and the solution to the Nash Bargaining problem in sector B (42) determines the wage through following equations: pb;t m B ( B;t = ( ) [ ) t SA t + ( t ) SB t ] (58) [ t SA t + ( t ) SB t ] = w B;t + t E t t;t+ mb ( B;t+ ) ( ) SA t+ +( t ) E t t;t+ mb ( B;t+ ) SB t+ (59) p E t A;t+ t;t+ + A;t+ = E t t;t+ ( )m B ( B;t+ ) SA t+ (60) t = N A B;t N A B;t +N B B;t (6) where SA t = WB;t A Tt A and SB t = WB;t B Tt B are the di erence in value from an additional employed worker in sector B, compared to an additional unemployed worker. Market Clearing in the sector j is that production equals consumption plus the resources wasted in the search and matching process and the cost of adjusting prices 2 pj;t y j;t = c j;t + V j;t + y j;t (62) 2 p j;t Concerning the bond market we assume that they are in zero net supply. As already noticed in Krause and Lubik (2007) in a new Keynesian model with matching frictions the marginal cost of rms is given by the marginal productivity of each single employee, and by the future value of current employees. Since posting vacancy is costly a successful match today is valuable as it reduces future search costs. The future value of current employees depends on the evolution of unemployment: if the number of searching workers increases, the probability of lling a future vacancy increases and the future value of current employees decreases. 23

7.2 System of Equations 7.2. Labor Markets Labor force = employed + unemployed: Market tightness: L A = U A A;t + U A B;t + N A A;t + N A B;t (63) L B = U B A;t + U B B;t + N B A;t + N B B;t (64) A;t = B;t = V A;t U A A;t + ( )U B A;t V B;t ( )U A B;t + U B B;t (65) (66) Law of Motion for employment: NA;t A = ( )NA;t A + m A ( A;t ) UA;t A (67) NB;t A = ( )NB;t A + ( )m B ( B;t ) UB;t A (68) NA;t B = ( )NA;t B + ( )m A ( A;t ) UA;t B (69) NB;t B = ( )NB;t B + m B ( B;t ) UB;t B (70) 7.2.2 Household Euler Equation: U 0 Pt (C t ) = R t E t U 0 (C t+ ) + Unemployed workers choice on which sectors to apply to: (7) mc A t = E t m A ( A;t+ ) [U 0 (C t+ )w A;t+ mc A t+] (72) UB;t A = 0 or mc A t = E t m B ( B;t+ ) ( ) U 0 (C t+ )w B;t+ mc A t+ UA;t B = 0 (73) (74) 24

Demands for good A and B: " c A;t = ( A;t ) " pa;t C t (75) " c B;t = ( B;t ) " pb;t C t (76) Aggregate Price: = ( A;t ) " (p A;t ) " + ( B;t ) " (p B;t ) " " (77) In ations: t = (78) p A;t A;t = p A;t (79) B;t = p B;t p B;t (80) 7.2.3 Firms Optimal choice for vacancies: p A;t p B;t m A ( A;t ) = pa;t+ A;tz A;t w A;t + ( )E t t;t+ m B ( B;t ) = B;tz B;t w B;t + ( )E t t;t+ + pb;t+ + m A ( A;t+ ) m B ( B;t+ ) (8) (82) Optimal choice for prices: " ( A;t ) " ( p A;t ) " V A;t (C t ) ( A;t ) A;t ( ") ( 2 A;t ) 2 h " i pa;t + A;t " + Et t;t+ ( A;t+ ) ( A;t+ ) 2 " ( t+ ) " A;t+ Ct+ A;t C t = 0 " ( B;t ) " ( p B;t ) " V B;t (C t ) ( B;t ) B;t ( ") ( 2 B;t ) 2 h " i pb;t + B;t " + Et t;t+ ( B;t+ ) ( B;t+ ) 2 " ( t+ ) " B;t+ Ct+ B;t C t = 0 (83) (84) Production Technology: y A;t = z A;t (N A A;t + N B A;t) (85) y B;t = z B;t (N A B;t + N B B;t) (86) 25

7.2.4 Wage Determination Wages in sector A: w A;t = ( A;t z A;t + E t t;t+ p A;t+ + A;t+ ) (87) Wages in sector B is determined by the following four equations: pb;t m B ( B;t = ( ) [ ) t SA t + ( t ) SB t ] (88) [ t SA t + ( t ) SB t ] = w B;t + t E t t;t+ mb ( B;t+ ) ( ) SA t+ + ( t ) E t t;t+ mb ( B;t+ ) SB t+ E t t;t+ p A;t+ + A;t+ = E t t;t+ ( )m B ( B;t+ ) SA t+ (89) (90) t = N A B;t N A B;t +N B B;t (9) 7.2.5 Interest Rules R t = R r t " t # u r R u t (92) u 7.2.6 Shock to demands log A;t A = log A;t A + " A;t (93) 7.2.7 Market clearing condition 2 pa;t y A;t = c A;t + V A;t + y A;t (94) 2 p A;t 2 pb;t y B;t = c B;t + V B;t + y B;t (95) 2 p B;t 26