DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Similar documents
1 Unemployment Insurance

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Lecture Notes 1

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Behavioral Finance and Asset Pricing

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Housing Wealth and Consumption

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

E ects of di erences in risk aversion on the. distribution of wealth

Asset Pricing under Information-processing Constraints

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

1 Non-traded goods and the real exchange rate

A Note on the Relation between Risk Aversion, Intertemporal Substitution and Timing of the Resolution of Uncertainty

The Role of Physical Capital

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Risk Aversion and the Variance Decomposition of the Price-Dividend Ratio

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS SEPTEMBER 13, 2010 BASICS. Introduction

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

ECON Micro Foundations

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010

Cash in Advance Models

Tries to understand the prices or values of claims to uncertain payments.

EconS Micro Theory I Recitation #8b - Uncertainty II

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Social Status and the Growth E ect of Money

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

The Dual Nature of Public Goods and Congestion: The Role. of Fiscal Policy Revisited

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Risk aversion and choice under uncertainty

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Solutions to Problem Set # 2

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

The Role of Risk Aversion and Intertemporal Substitution in Dynamic Consumption-Portfolio Choice with Recursive Utility

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Problem Set 3. Consider a closed economy inhabited by an in ntely lived representative agent who maximizes lifetime utility given by. t ln c t.

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Liquidity and Spending Dynamics

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

The E ect of Housing on Portfolio Choice

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Upward pricing pressure of mergers weakening vertical relationships

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

E cient Minimum Wages

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

1 Two Period Production Economy

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Chasing the Gap: Speed Limits and Optimal Monetary Policy

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

MORAL HAZARD AND BACKGROUND RISK IN COMPETITIVE INSURANCE MARKETS: THE DISCRETE EFFORT CASE. James A. Ligon * University of Alabama.

Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations? Comment

Money in OLG Models. Econ602, Spring The central question of monetary economics: Why and when is money valued in equilibrium?

Financial Decisions and Markets: A Course in Asset Pricing. John Y. Campbell. Princeton University Press Princeton and Oxford

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Central bank credibility and the persistence of in ation and in ation expectations

Introducing nominal rigidities.

Consumption and Portfolio Choice under Uncertainty

Simple e ciency-wage model

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Macroeconomics and finance

A Simple Theory of Offshoring and Reshoring

G + V = w wl + a r(assets) + c C + f (firms earnings) where w represents the tax rate on wages. and f represents the tax rate on rms earnings

Optimal Minimum Wage in a Competitive Economy: An Alternative Modelling Approach

Complete nancial markets and consumption risk sharing

WORKING PAPER NO OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY IN A MODEL OF MONEY AND CREDIT. Pedro Gomis-Porqueras Australian National University

The Representative Household Model

Remember the dynamic equation for capital stock _K = F (K; T L) C K C = _ K + K = I

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing

Long-Run Risk through Consumption Smoothing

Borrowing Constraints, Parental Altruism and Welfare

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

The Macroeconomic Consequences of Asset Bubbles and Crashes

Companion Appendix for "Dynamic Adjustment of Fiscal Policy under a Debt Crisis"

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Tax smoothing in a business cycle model with capital-skill complementarity

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Pure Exporter: Theory and Evidence from China

Valuation E ect, Heterogeneous Investors and Home Bias

Transcription:

ISSN 1471-0498 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES HOUSING AND RELATIVE RISK AVERSION Francesco Zanetti Number 693 January 2014 Manor Road Building, Manor Road, Oxford OX1 3UQ

Housing and Relative Risk Aversion Francesco Zanetti University of Oxford January 2014 Abstract This paper derives closed-form and numerical solutions for relative risk aversion in a standard consumption-based model enriched with housing. The presence of housing enables the household to hedge against unexpected shocks and may decrease relative risk aversion. In addition, housing may generate state-dependent, time-varying risk aversion. JEL Classi cation: D81, E21, R21. Keywords: Relative risk aversion, housing. Please address correspondence to: Francesco Zanetti, University of Oxford, Department of Economics, Manor Road, Oxford, OX1 3UQ, UK. Email: francesco.zanetti@economics.ox.ac.uk. I would like to thank Federico Mandelman and an anonymous referee for extremely helpful comments and suggestions.

1 Introduction Since the seminal contributions of Arrow (1965) and Pratt (1964), measures of relative risk aversion are obtained from models that abstract from housing. 1 However, recent studies by Iacoviello (2005), Silos (2007), and Rubio (2011) show that housing is an important component for the household s consumption decisions, which can either dampen or magnify the response of macroeconomic aggregates to shocks. These ndings suggest that housing may play a critical role in understanding risk aversion. The goal of this paper is to use an otherwise standard consumption-based model enriched with housing to derive closed-form and numerical solutions of relative risk aversion and to outline the relevance of housing for the household s attitude towards risk. The analysis shows that accounting for housing signi cantly a ects risk aversion. In particular, when uctuations in the housing stock have a milder e ect on utility compared to movements in consumption, housing provides the household with an additional margin to cushion against unexpected shifts in wealth. It therefore reduces relative risk aversion. On the other hand, relative risk aversion remains unchanged if movements in the stock of housing have a stronger e ect on utility than uctuations in consumption. In addition, the analysis shows that accounting for housing may generate state-dependent, timevarying risk aversion. Section 2 of the paper sets up the model. Section 3 shows how to derive analytical, closed-form solutions for relative risk aversion and discusses how they change in the presence of housing. Section 4 provides a quantitative assessment of the results and further discusses the issues. 1 The relationship between housing and risk aversion has been hinted in previous work. For example, Grossman and Laroque (1990) and Flavin and Nakagawa (2008) point out that housing a ects the agents attitude towards risk, despite their analyses do not explicitly focus on risk aversion. 1

2 The Model The theoretical framework is based on the standard consumption-based model that allows for housing investment, as in Iacoviello and Pavan (2013). During each period, t = 0; 1; 2; : : :, the representative household maximizes the von Neumann-Morgenstern expected utility function: W (c t ; h t ) = E 0 1 X t=0 t [U(c t ) + (1 )V (h t )] ; (1) where E 0 is the expectation at period t = 0, c t is consumption, h t is the housing stock, is the discount factor, and 1 are the share of consumption goods and housing stock, respectively. The representative household s end-of-period assets, a t+1, are equal to the beginning-of-period assets, a t, augmented for a gross return (1 + r t ), a net of lump-sum net transfer payments, t, purchases of consumption goods, c t, and investment in the stock of housing, h t. Hence, the household s budget constraint is: a t+1 = a t (1 + r t ) t c t h t + (1 )h t 1 ; (2) where is the depreciation rate of the housing stock. In addition, the non-ponzi scheme 1Q a condition holds: lim T +1 T!1 0: Thus, the household chooses fc (1+r t) t; h t ; a t+1 g 1 t=0 to t=0 maximize its utility (1) subject to the budget constraint (2) for all t = 0; 1; 2; :::. The optimality conditions for this problem are U 0 (c t ) = (1 )V 0 (h t ) + (1 )E t U 0 (c t+1 ) (3) and U 0 (c t ) = E t U 0 (c t+1 )(1 + r t+1 ); (4) where U 0 (c t ) and V 0 (h t ) denote the marginal utility of consumption and housing stock, respectively. Equation (3) states that the marginal utility of consumption equates the direct utility gain from an additional unit of housing stock at time t, plus the discounted gain that the additional unit of housing stock brings into the next period, t + 1, for the 2

remaining fraction (1 ). Equation (4) is the standard Euler equation for consumption that equates the marginal utility of consumption at time t with the expected, discounted, marginal utility of consumption at time t + 1. 3 Relative Risk Aversion with Housing Relative risk aversion, R t, is a measure of the household s willingness to accept risk as a function of the fraction of the household s assets that are exposed to risk. As shown in Swanson (2012), the coe cient of relative risk aversion with respect to the beginning-ofperiod assets, a t, can be derived from the household indirect utility: R t = W 00 (a t ) W 0 (a t ) a t; (5) where W 0 (a t ) and W 00 (a t ) represent the rst and second derivative of the indirect utility function over wealth, W (a t ), with respect to a t, respectively. Equation (5) shows that the value of the coe cient of relative risk aversion crucially depends on the de nition of beginning-of-period assets, a t. We de ne beginning-of-period assets as the present discounted stream of consumption and housing stock, as implied by the household budget constraint (2). Given equation (5), we are able to derive closed-form solutions for relative risk aversion, R t ; by determining explicit functional forms for W 0 (a t ) and W 00 (a t ) from the indirect utility function W (a t ). In particular, use the beginning-of-period assets to express the utility function (1) as: W (a t ) = U fa t r t [h t (a t ) (1 )h t 1 (a t 1 )]g + (1 )V fh t (a t )g : (6) Di erentiating equation (6) with respect to a t and imposing the household s optimal condition with respect to h t, reported in equation (3), yield: W 0 (a t ) = U 0 (c t )r t ; (7) 3

which, once di erentiated with respect to a t, yields: W 00 (a t ) = U 00 (c t )r t @c t : (8) We can use the model comprising equations (2), (3), (4), and the non-ponzi scheme condition to obtain an explicit functional form for the derivative @c t = in equation (8). In particular, di erentiating equation (3) with respect to a t yields: U 00 (c t ) @c t = (1 )V 00 (h t ) @h t + (1 )E t U 00 (c t+1 ) @c t+1 ; (9) and di erentiating equation (4) with respect to a t yields: U 00 (c t ) @c t = E t U 00 (c t+1 )(1 + r t+1 ) @c t+1 ; which, by imposing the steady state condition, = 1=(1 + r), implies: @c t = @c t+1 : (10) Equation (10) holds for each period t = 0; 1; 2; : : :, implying that, in the steady state, changes in the current household s consumption are the same across any future change in consumption. Imposing equation (10) into the long-run equilibrium of equation (9) yields: U 00 (c) [1 (1 )] @c @a = (1 In steady state, equation (9) must hold, such that V 0 (h) U 0 (c) and inserting equation (12) into equation (11) yields: )V 00 (h) @h @a : (11) (1 )] = [1 ; (12) (1 ) @c @a = @h @a ; (13) where = cu 00 (c)=u 0 (c) is the the elasticity of U 0 (c) with respect to c, and = hv 00 (h)=v 0 (h) is the elasticity of V 0 (h) with respect to h. We now can di erentiate the 4

household s budget constraint (2) with respect to a t and evaluate it at the steady state to obtain: r = @c @a + @h @a : (14) Hence, using equation (13) to solve for @h=@a and substituting the outcome into equation (14), yields: @c @a = r 1 + : (15) h c Equation (15) shows that consumption increases in response to a unitary increase in the assets. In particular, consumption rises by the extra asset income r, but it decreases by the amount, 1 + h, that accounts for the e ect of housing. We can now derive a c closed-form solution for the long-run coe cient of relative risk aversion, R. Proposition 1 The long-run coe cient of relative risk aversion is: R = U 00 (c)c U 0 (c) 1 1 + h c 1 + h : (16) c Proof. Inserting the steady state, beginning-of-period wealth equation, a = (c + h) (1=r), into equation (5) together with the expressions for W 0 (a) and W 00 (a), as outlined in equations (7) and (8), respectively, and using equation (15) to substitute for @c=@a in equation (8) yield to equation (16). Proposition 1 shows that including housing in the model has important implications for risk aversion. In particular, relative risk aversion depends on the concavity of both arguments c and h in the utility function, as expressed by the ratio =. Therefore preferences over consumption as well as the stock of housing are relevant for the household s attitude towards risk. This result di ers from the standard Arrow-Pratt measure of risk aversion that identi es the curvature of the utility function with respect to consumption as the relevant measure to quantify risk aversion. Therefore, the conventional Arrow-Pratt approach to derive measure of relative risk aversion may lead to inaccurate readings of the household s attitude towards risk if the analysis abstracts from housing. 5

In addition, housing makes the measure of relative risk aversion dependent on the ratio between the stock of housing and consumption, whereas it is constant and equal to in the standard consumption-based model. Since consumption and the stock of housing uctuate over the business cycle, relative risk aversion becomes state-dependent and time-varying, which is a robust stylized fact. 2 4 Quantitative Assessment and Discussion To quantitatively assess the implications of proposition 1, suppose that during each period, t = 0; 1; 2; : : :, the representative household maximizes the Epstein and Zin (1991) P h i utility function, W (c t ; h t ) = E 1 0 t=0 t c1 t + (1 ) h1 t. Using equation (16), the 1 1 associated long-run measure of relative risk aversion is: 1 R = 1 + h c 1 + h c : (17) Figure 1 shows measures of relative risk aversion for values of the elasticity of the marginal utility of consumption with respect to consumption () between 0 and 4, and each line is associated with values of the elasticity of the marginal utility of housing with respect to housing (), which equals 0, 1, 2, 3, and 4 respectively. 3 The entries show that the values of and are critical to determine measures of relative risk aversion. When, the coe cient of relative risk aversion is constant and equal to U 00 (c)c=u 0 (c) =, the same value as the standard Arrow-Pratt measure of relative risk aversion. For instance, when is equal to 2, for values of 2, the coe cient of relative risk aversion remains equal to 2. However, when the household s preference has a higher elasticity to consumption than the stock of housing (i.e. > ), the coe cient of relative risk 2 Guiso et al. (2013) and Ouysse and Quin (2013) provide an extensive empirical support to timevarying risk aversion. Brunnermeier and Nagel (2008) show that time-varying relative risk aversion linked to individuals responses to changes in household assets is supported by the data. 3 Note that in this application the steady-state value of h=c is set equal to 0.066 to match the ratio between real consumption and real residential xed investment from the BEA data. 6

aversion is lower than the standard Arrow-Pratt measure. In this case, the contribution of an additional unit of housing stock to the household s marginal utility is lower than the contribution of an additional unit of consumption. For instance, when is equal to 2, for any value of < 2, relative risk aversion is lower than 2, the standard Arrow- Pratt value. The intuition for this result is straightforward. When movements in the stock of housing have a more limited e ect on utility than uctuations in consumption, the housing stock provides the household with an additional margin to cushion against unexpected shocks and therefore reduces relative risk aversion. Equation (17) also shows that relative risk aversion crucially depends on movements in the housing-consumption stock, which uctuate over the business cycle. Thus, relative risk aversion becomes state-dependent and time varying if the model is enriched with housing, whereas it is constant in a standard model consumption-based model. In summary, this analysis shows that housing may signi cantly a ect relative risk aversion. Furthermore, uctuations in relative risk aversion are tightly linked with movements in consumption and the housing stock. The ndings in this paper call for two interesting extensions. First, the analysis assumes that the housing-consumption ratio, h=c, remains constant over variations in and. It would be interesting to establish whether the quantitative result continues to hold in a general equilibrium model, where the long-run values of consumption and housing stock also depend on the curvature of the utility function with respect to and. In principle, if the contribution of an additional unit of housing to the marginal utility () is higher than the contribution of an additional unit of consumption goods (), changes in the housing stock generate strong movements in utility, making it optimal for the household to hold a high housing stock and thus dampen the e ect of marginal movements in housing on the stock of household. Such a mechanism would increase the h=c ratio and therefore potentially increase risk aversion. Second, the analysis has focused on the longrun properties of relative risk aversion, but the underlining theoretical framework can 7

Figure 1: y-axis: relative risk aversion, R. x-axis: values of the elasticity of utility with respect to the stock of housing,. The gure shows values of the coe cient of relative risk aversion in the function of, for values of equal to 0, 1, 2, 3, and 4. be used to investigate to what extent housing a ects the dynamic properties of relative risk aversion. Such an extension would be particularly interesting since the analysis shows that uctuations in relative risk aversion are related tightly with movements in the housing-consumption ratio. These investigations are open for future research. References Arrow, K.J., 1965. Aspects of the theory of risk-bearing, in: Yrjoĺ Jahnsson lectures. Essays in the theory of risk bearing. Brunnermeier, M.K., Nagel, S., 2008. Do wealth uctuations generate time-varying risk aversion? Micro-evidence on individuals. American Economic Review 98, 713 36. Epstein, L.G., Zin, S.E., 1991. Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: An empirical analysis. Journal of Political Economy 99, 263 86. 8

Flavin, M., Nakagawa, S., 2008. A model of housing in the presence of adjustment costs: A structural interpretation of habit persistence. American Economic Review 98, 474 95. Grossman, S.J., Laroque, G., 1990. Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica 58, 25 51. Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., Zingales, L., 2013. Time varying risk aversion. Chicago Booth Research Paper 13-64. Iacoviello, M., 2005. House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. American Economic Review 95, 739 764. Iacoviello, M., Pavan, M., 2013. Housing and debt over the life cycle and over the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 60, 221 238. Ouysse, R., Quin, M., 2013. New evidence on the time-varying risk aversion from a dynamic multinominal-logit augmented consumption CAPM. University of New South Wales. Pratt, J., 1964. Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32, 122 136. Rubio, M., 2011. Fixed and variable-rate mortgages, business cycles and monetary policy. Journal of Money Credit and Banking 43, 657 688. Silos, P., 2007. Housing, portfolio choice and the macroeconomy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31, 2774 2801. Swanson, E.T., 2012. Risk aversion and the labor margin in dynamic equilibrium models. American Economic Review 102, 1663 91. 9