Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

Similar documents
Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness 1

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Financial Market Feedback and Disclosure

Incentives for Information Production in Markets where Prices Affect Real Investment 1

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Financial Market Feedback:

Incentives for Information Production in Markets where Prices Affect Real Investment 1

Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Feedback E ects and the Limits to Arbitrage

Doing Battle with Short Sellers: The Role of Blockholders in Bear Raids. Naveen Khanna and Richmond D. Mathews. September 24, 2010

BEAR RAIDS AND SHORT SALE BANS: IS GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION JUSTIFIABLE? Naveen Khanna and Richmond D. Mathews. October 30, 2009

Optimal Disclosure and Fight for Attention

Short Selling, Earnings Management, and Firm Value

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE LIMITATIONS OF STOCK MARKET EFFICIENCY: PRICE INFORMATIVENESS AND CEO TURNOVER. Gary B. Gorton Lixin Huang Qiang Kang

The Limitations of Stock Market Efficiency: Price Informativeness and CEO Turnover *

Strategic Information Revelation and Capital Allocation

Market Efficiency and Real Efficiency: The Connect and Disconnect via Feedback Effects

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Strategic Information Revelation and Capital Allocation

Irrational Exuberance or Value Creation: Feedback Effect of Stock Currency on Fundamental Values

Liquidity-Solvency Nexus: A Stress Testing Tool

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

Do Managers Learn from Short Sellers?

The Effects of The Target s Learning on M&A Negotiations

Where do securities come from

Trading Frenzies and Their Impact on Real Investment

Alternative sources of information-based trade

FIN CORPORATE FINANCE Spring Office: CBA 6.246, Phone: ,

POSTURING IN VENTURE CAPITAL. Naveen Khanna and Richmond D. Mathews. February 25, 2013

Market-Based Corrective Actions

Tradeoffs in Disclosure of Supervisory Information

Using Managerial Attributes to Identify Market Feedback Effects: The Case of Mutual Fund Fire Sales

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

The Effects of High Frequency Trading in a Multi-Asset Model

The Role of Stock Liquidity and Stock Return Volatility in Executive Compensation: Risk versus Information

Contagious Adverse Selection

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness

Good Cop, Bad Cop: Complementarities between Debt and Equity in Disciplining Management

Internet Appendix for Back-Running: Seeking and Hiding Fundamental Information in Order Flows

China s Model of Managing the Financial System

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Johnson School Research Paper Series # The Exchange of Flow Toxicity

Feedback E ects and the Limits to Arbitrage

Executive Compensation and Short-Termism

Corporate savings and price informativeness *

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

Dynamic Capital Structure Choice

A Theory of the Size and Investment Duration of Venture Capital Funds

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

Volatility of FDI and Portfolio Investments: The Role of Information, Liquidation Shocks and Transparency

International Journal of Asian Social Science OVERINVESTMENT, UNDERINVESTMENT, EFFICIENT INVESTMENT DECREASE, AND EFFICIENT INVESTMENT INCREASE

The Effect of Speculative Monitoring on Shareholder Activism

Information Acquisition in Financial Markets: a Correction

Learning whether other Traders are Informed

Concentrating on reason 1, we re back where we started with applied economics of information

Corrigendum to Prospect Theory and market quality Journal of Economic Theory 149 (2014),

Information-Based Stock Trading, Executive Incentives, and the Principal-Agent Problem

Learning from Peers Stock Prices and Corporate Investment

SUMMARY OF THEORIES IN CAPITAL STRUCTURE DECISIONS

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

Trading Frenzies and Their Impact on Real Investment

(Some theoretical aspects of) Corporate Finance

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Liquidity, Asset Price, and Welfare

(In)Efficient Asset Trade and a rationale for a Tobin Tax

Informational Feedback Effect, Adverse Selection, and the Optimal Disclosure Policy

1 Appendix A: Definition of equilibrium

Dividend Changes and Stock Price Informativeness

Chapter 10. Liquidity, Price Discovery and Corporate Policies

PROBLEM SET 6 ANSWERS

Liquidity and Asset Prices in Rational Expectations Equilibrium with Ambiguous Information

Informational Feedback, Adverse Selection, and Optimal Disclosure Policy

Options Trading Activity and Firm Valuation. Richard Roll, Eduardo Schwartz, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam. August 18, Abstract

For on-line Publication Only ON-LINE APPENDIX FOR. Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market. June 2017

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

Endogenous Information Acquisition with Sequential Trade

Cross-Listing, Investment Sensitivity to Stock Price and the Learning. Hypothesis

Measuring the Amount of Asymmetric Information in the Foreign Exchange Market

Alon Brav and Richmond D. Mathews. October 17, 2007

Economics and Finance

Optimal Penalty Level, Manipulation, and Investment Efficiency

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

Global Games and Financial Fragility:

Making Money out of Publicly Available Information

Sequential Financial Market Trading: The Role of Endogenous Timing

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness

Making Derivative Warrants Market in Hong Kong

Voluntary Disclosure and Strategic Stock Repurchases

Asymmetric Information, Debt Capacity, And Capital Structure *

Informational Feedback Effect, Adverse Selection, and. the Optimal Disclosure Policy

Uberrimae Fidei and Adverse Selection: the equitable legal judgment of Insurance Contracts

Essays on Information Asymmetry in Financial Market

Runs and Fragility in the Financial System

Transcription:

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness James Dow Itay Goldstein Alexander Guembel London Business University of University of Oxford School Pennsylvania European Central Bank, 15-16 May, 2006 1

The Feedback Effect Prices in financial markets affect resource allocation. Justification: Markets aggregate information from many participants and thus provide new information to decision makers (managers, providers of capital). Related Evidence: Ability of markets to generate predictions: Roll (1984), Wolfers and Zitzewitz (2004). Managers learning from prices: Luo (2005), Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2006). Feedback effect via capital constraints: Baker, Stein, and Wurgler (2003). Theoretical Implication: Prices affect and reflect firm value at the same time. 2

Theoretical Literature There is a small literature analyzing the theoretical implications of the feedback effect from prices to the real economy. Early Contributions: Emphasize the increase in efficiency: Leland (1992), Khanna, Slezak, and Bradley (1994), Dow and Gorton (1997), and Subrahmanyam and Titman (1999). Recent Contributions: Goldstein and Guembel (2005): Feedback generates manipulation of stock price. Bond, Goldstein, and Prescott (2006): Feedback leads to no equilibrium/multiple equilibria. Bond and Eraslan (2006): Feedback creates a motive for trade. 3

In this Paper: We study the incentives to collect information in the presence of feedback, and identify a limitation inherent in the allocational role. Suppose that previously announced investments are always cancelled when prices suggest they have slightly negative NPVs. The value of the security becomes insensitive to information about investments fundamentals. Speculators don t acquire the information, and the allocational role of prices breaks down. 4

Two Main Implications More information collected during booms than during busts. o This amplifies shocks to fundamentals. o Consistent with analysts activities in the business cycle. Firms may optimally commit to overinvest i.e., invest when, according to information in the price, projects have slightly negative NPVs. o Cancellation fee (break-up fee in M&A). o Leave financial slack in the firm to allow empire-building managers to make interim inefficient investments. 5

The model Dates t {1, 2} Investment Opportunity (Decision at t=2): - Requires investment I; yields uncertain payoff R ω. - ω {l, h} with equal probability; R h > I > R l 1 - Unconditional expected payoff is: R 2 ( R l + R h ) 6

Financial Market (t=1): - One speculator who can learn ω at cost c. - Noise trade is either -n or n with equal probability. - The speculator, if informed, submits orders -n or n. - A market maker observes the set of orders but not the identity of the traders who submit them. He then sets the price equal to the expected firm value contingent on the information contained in the order flow. - Modification of Kyle (1985): price both reflects and affects firm value Feedback Effect. 7

Prices Two buy orders (probability 0.25): market maker infers that the speculator traded on positive news and sets a price p bb. Buy and a sell order (probability 0.5): MM cannot tell whether the speculator bought and the liquidity trader sold, or vice versa, and sets a price p sb. Two sell orders (probability 0.25): MM infers that the speculator traded on negative news and sets a price p ss. 8

Investment Policies Consider investment policies that are monotone in the order flow. Never Invest (NPV = 0) Type I Conditional Investment (Reject unless Certain) Invest when price is p bb and don t invest when price is p sb or p ss. Type II Conditional Investment (Accept unless Certain) Invest when price is p bb or p sb and don t invest when price is p ss. Always Invest (NPV < 0 by assumption) 9

Interim Efficient Investment Policy Investing when p=p bb is always good; Investing when p=p ss is always bad. When ex-ante NPV is negative, I > R, it is interim efficient not to invest when p=p sb. Type I Conditional Investment is interim efficient. When ex-ante NPV is positive, I < R, it is interim efficient to invest when p=p sb. Type II Conditional Investment is interim efficient. 10

Feasibility of Type I Conditional Investment Policy Suppose the firm does not invest except when there are two buy orders. Then, the speculator does not acquire costly information in equilibrium and the firm therefore never invests. Intuition Suppose the speculator acquires information, and then buys on good news and sells on bad news. We will go through each possibility for order flow and price to see if he can make a profit that justifies acquiring the information. 11

Intuition cont d In case of two buy orders or two sell orders, there is no uncertainty about the project. The price fully reveals the information, and the speculator makes no profit. This is a standard feature of traditional market microstructure models. In case of two opposite orders, there is uncertainty about the project, which is the source of profit in traditional market microstructure models. However, the speculator cannot profit on his information in this case, because the firm does not invest, and thus its value is no longer sensitive to the private information acquired by the speculator. 12

Implications If interim efficient rule is followed, information will be collected if and only if the ex ante NPV of the investment is positive. This amplifies shocks to fundamentals: o When NPV is negative, there is no collection of information, and as a result, efficiency of investment decisions is harmed, and amount of investments decreases. This seems consistent with patterns of analysts activities. The firm may want to commit to overinvest. 13

Ex-Ante Efficient Investment Policy Suppose that the investment has ex ante negative NPV: R < I, but has positive NPV if the real option is accounted for: 1 1 ( I ) + ( R I ) > 0 n assume that c ( V V ) h l 4 R h 2. Also, 4 (the cost of producing information is sufficiently low). Then, Type II Conditional Investment is ex-ante most efficient. This policy is interim inefficient, as it entails investment when p=p sb, and thus the NPV is slightly negative. However, it enables production of information, and thus is ex-ante efficient. It requires commitment to overinvestment. 14

Commitment Managerial Learning Suppose that managers interests are aligned with those of shareholders. Also, managers have enough capital to finance the investment. Managers learn from the price before they make the investment decision. Managers can commit by setting a cancellation fee F to be paid out when the investment is cancelled: Break-up fee in mergers and acquisitions. n When c 4 ( R R ) and 1 3 ( I ) + ( R I ) > 0 h l 4 R h 4, then it is optimal for the firm to commit to a fee F = I R when it rejects the investment project. Otherwise it is optimal for the firm never to invest. 15

Commitment Financial Slack Suppose that managers are empire builders and want to invest as much as possible (Jensen (1986)). Shareholders can design the financial structure of the firm in a way to allow investment when p=p sb, but not when p=p ss. Let E denote the initial cash holdings in the firm. In order to invest, the firm needs to raise external finance max{0,i-e} from uninformed investors, who learn from the price about the expectation that the project succeeds. The firm must offer a competitive return (assumed zero) to the investors. 16

Commitment Financial Slack Cont d For E < I R, the firm is unable to raise external finance and never undertakes the investment project. n When c 4 ( Rh Rl ) c E [ I R +, I R ) n l, the shareholders will choose retained earnings 2. The speculator will produce information and the n investment policy is type II conditional investment. If c ( R R ) shareholders will choose E < I R and the firm will never invest. > 4, the Our point on the optimality of retained earnings is related to Myers and Majluf (1984). Interestingly, the underling mechanism is almost opposite. h l 17

Empirical Implications Commitment Commitment occurs when the economy is in an intermediate state. Firms that can learn more from the market are more likely to use commitment devices such as break-up fees or financial slack. o One would expect speculators to have information about demand factors / strategic factors, not on technological factors. Firms with commitment devices will exhibit informative prices. Two measures of informativeness are used in Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2005): o Price non-synchronicity: Durnev, Morck, and Yeung (2004). o Probability of informed trading: Easley, Kiefer, and O Hara (1996). 18

Investment Frequency Bust Intermediate Boom Interim Efficient Plan Equilibrium Investment When different from interim efficient Frequency=0.75 (Type II Investment policy) Frequency=0.25 (Type I Investment policy) 0 * R h I ** R h R h 19

Conclusions Prices perform important role affecting real investment decisions. When investments are cancelled too often following negative information in the price, securities become insensitive to information about investment fundamentals. As a result, speculators will not produce information. Mechanism amplifies shocks to fundamentals. Firms may decide to commit to overinvest, in order to encourage information production. Possible commitment devices are: cancellation fee, financial slack, etc. 20