Is power more evenly balanced in poor households?

Similar documents
An empirical analysis of disability and household expenditure allocations

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland

Analysing household survey data: Methods and tools

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

Equivalence Scales Based on Collective Household Models

CIE Economics A-level

Estimating Welfare in Insurance Markets using Variation in Prices

Human Capital and Economic Opportunity: A Global Working Group. Working Paper Series. Working Paper No.

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Income distribution orderings based on differences with respect to the minimum acceptable income

Modeling of Price. Ximing Wu Texas A&M University

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Household Bargaining and Portfolio Choice

Recall the idea of diminishing marginal utility of income. Recall the discussion that utility functions are ordinal rather than cardinal.

Rational Choice and Moral Monotonicity. James C. Cox

Welfare Analysis for Public Economics EC426

The Role of the Annuity s Value on the Decision (Not) to Annuitize: Evidence from a Large Policy Change

Characterization of the Optimum

The Capital Asset Pricing Model in the 21st Century. Analytical, Empirical, and Behavioral Perspectives

Master s in Financial Engineering Foundations of Buy-Side Finance: Quantitative Risk and Portfolio Management. > Teaching > Courses

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Are the Poorest Being Left Behind? Reconciling Conflicting Views on Poverty and Growth

According to the life cycle theory, households take. Do wealth inequalities have an impact on consumption? 1

LECTURE 4: JOINT-SEARCH THEORY

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

The Collective Model of Household : Theory and Calibration of an Equilibrium Model

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006

The Share Game. I also plan on making tutorials how to write simple Python scripts for getting data & analyzing it.

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Reviewing Income and Wealth Heterogeneity, Portfolio Choice and Equilibrium Asset Returns by P. Krussell and A. Smith, JPE 1997

Understanding Income Distribution and Poverty

Exploring the Returns to Scale in Food Preparation

The Effects of Income Support Settings on Incentives to Work. Nicolas Hérault, Guyonne Kalb and Justin van de Ven

What is So Bad About Inequality? What Can Be Done to Reduce It? Todaro and Smith, Chapter 5 (11th edition)

THE CHORE WARS Household Bargaining and Leisure Time

Saving During Retirement

Labor Supply and Taxation in Europe

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

Naughty noughties in the UK: Decomposing income changes in the 2000 s

Female Labour Supply, Human Capital and Tax Reform

The Welfare Cost of Asymmetric Information: Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market

INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY. Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta. Institute for Human Development New Delhi

Macroeconomics and finance

A microeconometric model for analysing efficiency and distributional effects of tax reforms A review of results for Italy and Norway

Reflections on capital taxation

THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES

Relative Income and Hours Worked: Empirical Evidence from the US

Industrial Organization II: Markets with Asymmetric Information (SIO13)

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

Financial Risk Management

Unemployment, Consumption Smoothing and the Value of UI

Poverty and Income Distribution

Redistributive Effects of Pension Reform in China

Lecture 2 Consumer theory (continued)

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Accounting for Family Background when Designing Optimal Income Taxes: A Microeconometric Simulation Analysis

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 12. Default Risk, Collateral and Credit Rationing

Economic incentives and gender identity

Employer-mandated complementary health insurance in France: the likely effect on social welfare

Peer Effects in Retirement Decisions

ECON Introductory Econometrics. Seminar 4. Stock and Watson Chapter 8

Staff Paper P93-19 August 1993 STAFF PAPER SERIES

Social Preferences Revealed through Effective Marginal Tax Rates

Inflation at the Household Level

Discussion of Trends in Individual Earnings Variability and Household Incom. the Past 20 Years

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Public Economics. Contact Information

GENDER EQUITY IN THE TAX SYSTEM FOR FISCAL SUSTAINABILITY

Optimal Labor Income Taxation. Thomas Piketty, Paris School of Economics Emmanuel Saez, UC Berkeley PE Handbook Conference, Berkeley December 2011

Accounting for Family Background when Designing Optimal Income Taxes: A Microeconometric Simulation Analysis

Poverty and income inequality

CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL JANUARY 19, 2018

Identification of Random Resource Shares in Collective Households With an Application to Microcredit in Malawi.

Inequality in developed countries - how good is a good state. Åsa Hansson Lunds universitet

Estimation and Simulation of consumption behavior

Child welfare and intra-household inequality in Albania

THE IMPACT OF FEMALE LABOR SUPPLY ON THE BRAZILIAN INCOME DISTRIBUTION

Contents Part I Descriptive Statistics 1 Introduction and Framework Population, Sample, and Observations Variables Quali

What is Driving The Labour Force Participation Rates for Indigenous Australians? The Importance of Transportation.

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

The Distributional Impact of Public Services in Europe

[D7] PROBABILITY DISTRIBUTION OF OUTSTANDING LIABILITY FROM INDIVIDUAL PAYMENTS DATA Contributed by T S Wright

FormerYugoslav Republic of Macedonia Focusing on the Poor (In Two Volumes) Volume 11: Statistical Annex

A comparison of two methods for imputing missing income from household travel survey data

ECON 256: Poverty, Growth & Inequality. Jack Rossbach

Online Appendix for The Importance of Being. Marginal: Gender Differences in Generosity

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

Economic Growth and Convergence across the OIC Countries 1

31E00700 Labor Economics: Lecture 3

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Econometrics is. The estimation of relationships suggested by economic theory

Expected Utility and Risk Aversion

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

Microenterprises. Gender and Microenterprise Performance. The Experiment. Firms in three zones:

CHAPTER 5 RESULT AND ANALYSIS

Choice under risk and uncertainty

Transcription:

ZEW, 11th September 2008 Is power more evenly balanced in poor households? Hélène Couprie Toulouse School of Economics (GREMAQ) with Eugenio Peluso University of Verona and Alain Trannoy IDEP-GREQAM, University of Aix-Marseille II

Is intra-household power more balanced in poor households? Structure of the talk I. Introduction II. Theory III. Empirics IV. Results

I. Introduction MEASURE OF INEQUALITY AND WELFARE Is the object of a vast literature which propose a theoretical framework essentially based on the measure of individual wellbeing (e.g: using individual consumption) BUT Most of the households are made off several members. The direct observation of individual welfare is impossible in such households WHY? The household forms an «informational screen» (or a black box) to the observation of individual welfare. Consumption, for example, is only observed at a household level and not at an individual level

For the moment, theory does not propose fully satisfying solution to the problem. In practice, Economies of scales due to the household size are controlled, intra-household equality being implicitly assumed. (e.g: equivalence scales such as the OECD one: HH equivalent income=hh income/ n) This article is one of the first to address the question of the incidence of intra-household inequality for the construction of welfare normative criteria.

Welfare comparisons II. Theory of welfare comparisons are usually based on observation of income distributions with different averages. Two different approaches are possible 1/ The Cardinal Criterion Indicator such as: Gini coefficient, Variance, etc. 2/ The Ordinal Criterion Comparing Generalized Lorenz Curves (LG) One income distribution A is better than a distribution B if it is all points of A are above the points of B.

Example: Generalized Lorenz Comparison (Atkinson, Shorrocks) Mean Income Cumulative Densities Income Y A Y B A B A is preferred to B Whatever the shape of the social welfare utility function Under the assumptions: - Equality in needs (homogenous Households) - Inequality aversion 0 1 Interpretation: progressive transfers inter-households Cumulative Densities (population)

And what if the population is made off heterogenous households? Is there a difference in needs that dependents on observed household characteristics? 1) If Cardinal approach Define an Equivalence Scale 2) If Ordinal approach Define an ordering for needs Sequential Dominance Criterion (Atkinson and Bourguignon, 1987) Axioms Required: The social welfare utility increases in case of 1) A progressive transfer intra-group (riche couple->poor couple or rich single->poor single) 2) A progressive transfer inter-groups (from a single to a couple)

Should we consider inequalities inside the household? 1) Cardinal Approach : YES Haddad and Kanbur (EJ 1991) and Lise and Seitz (WP 2007) both papers evaluate Gini indexes at the household and at the individual level (based on consumption data and or time alloc. data) 2) Ordinal Approach:? We propose a theoretical normative answer and an empirical test on french data Difficulty The HH is an informationnal screen (or black box) A lot of consumptions are joint

Should we consider inequalities inside the household? Answering to this question using theoretical normative tools is equivalent to answer the following question: Does a diminution in inter households inequality also lead to a reduction of intra household inequalities? If YES It is worthless to try to focus on inter-individual inequalities for ordinal comparisons If NO One need to control for intra-household Inequalities to implement meaningful ordinal comparisons

Assumption We define the individualized income (y) of a poor individual (p) living in a household (i) : y ip g( Y i ) f p ( Y * i ) Private expenditures of the couple 1, 1 2 Public expenditures Private expenditures Of the poor individual Theoretical Result Given a population of couples or single-living people g If and f are concaves p Then a Sequential Lorenz comparison is preserved when we go from an income distribution at the household level to the individual level. Intuition?...>

How to define individual incomes? What are the links between our approach and a structural analysis? In general: We assume y ip = h(f g, f p, Y i ) y ir = h(f g, f r, Y i ) y p = f g (Y)+ f p (y*) y p = f g (Y)+ f p (y*) Idea: flexibility of individual preferences

An example 2 goods: a Hicksian good z (price 1) and a public good g (price p) A couple chooses the amount of public good g 0 in an efficient way, that is respecting Lindhal conditions. At the same time, the private consumption of each individual is decided. Here we focus on one individual, which receives z 0 for private consumption.

The individual equivalent income z E(p, U (G 0, z 0 )) E(p, U (G 0, z 0 )) (G 1, z 1 ) (G 0, z 0 ) U (G 0, z 0 ) G

The individual income case alpha=1 z pg 0 + z 0 E(p, U (G0, z0)) pg 0 + z 0 (G 0, z 0 ) U (G 0, z 0 ) G

l z z pg 0 + z 0 pg 0 + z 0 E(p, U (G 0, z 0 )) U (G 0, z 0 ) E(p,U (G 0, z 0 )) (G 1, z 1 ) (G 0, z 0 ) U (G 0, z 0 ) (G 0, z 0 ) U (G 0, z 0 ) U (G 0, z 0 ) (G 1, z 1 ) a G b G pg 0 + z 0 = Max (E(p, Us (G 0, z 0 )), for any Us quasi-concave

Assumption We define the individualized income (y) of a poor individual (p) living in a household (i) : y ip g( Y i ) f p ( Y * i ) Private expenditures of the couple 1, 1 2 Public expenditures Private expenditures Of the poor individual Theoretical Result Given a population of couples or single-living people g If and f are concaves p Then a Sequential Lorenz comparison is preserved when we go from an income distribution at the household level to the individual level. Intuition?...>

Effect of a progressive transfer between HH on inequality within HH If the fonctions g and f p are linear The shares of public and private consumptions do not vary with income; there is no effect on the share of individualized income g f If is concave and p is linear Poor HH tend to spend a higher part of their income in public good than rich HH, this will lead to lower inequalities within the HH for poor HH then for rich ones g If is linear and f p is concave Poor HH tend to spend a higher share of private expenditures in favour of the poor individual within the HH (than rich HH), this tends to reduce intra-household inequalities

III. Empirics The concavity test requires to use non-parametric methods. WHY? Because parametric specifications of the utility functions lead to parametric restrictions on the sharing rule (e.g. CARA Utility functions linear sharing rule) (see Peluso and Trannoy, 2004) For the «public sharing» function => no real difficulty we implement various test based on various definitions and controls for public expenditures. For the «private sharing» function => observation problem for individual private expenditures

Public sharing function 2 Ethical rules NEEDS: No control Public good Expenditures G g( Y ) i i i Total HH Expenditures MERITS: Control W min( w f, wm ) log1 max( w, ) f wm G i g( Y ) W i i i

Endogeneity Control G g( Y ) i i i Assumption: i v i with and Public sharing function u i with E( u i / Y i ) Y i ' i 0 v i Estimate expectancy of G given Y (i), evaluate v by ols, estimate expect of v given Y (ii) Ols residuals (i) on residuals (ii) -> correction term

Individual Private Expenditures Simulation Method in a few words 1) Non-parametric observation of the relationship between expenditures of an assignable good (clothes) and total expenditures at the individual level 2) Assumption of identical income effects accross family status 3) Prediction of individualized incomes for men and women living in a couple by inverting the relation observed for singles 4) Simulation of a cloud of point using the residual at the HH level

Predicting the «private sharing function» Clothes expenditures for single living women C f c f ( Y * f ) X f f, E( f f / Y * f ) 0 Specificities The approach is non-parametric (kernel smoothing) The estimation is monotonicity-constrained Demographic controls (-> parametric) Endogeneity control for HH private expenditures Same estimation for single living men (-> parametric)

Predicting individual private expenditures Identical income effects - identifying assumption Browning, Chiappori et Lewbel (2006), Lise et Seitz (2007), Couprie (EJ 2007) They use the same kind of assumption in different contexts Parametric, Linear sharing rule, Demographic controls are quite numerous and allow to take into account difference in preferences accross family status Here, the approach in non-parametric, the sharing rule can be non-linear As a counterpart, controls for difference in preferences between individuals living single or in-couple are weak. Controls: city size, wage differences

Predicting individual private expenditures Prediction (under A) of private expenditures of women in couple (Ycf) NEEDS Y cf MERITS * c f 1 ( h cf ( Y * )) To avoid support pbms, we use the smoothed expenditure function rather than the observed clothe expenditures Couple private expenditures * 1 Y cf c f h cf ( Y * ) W f W f W m

from the residual at the HH level The same method is applied for men. Normally, the sum of predicted expenditures of females and males within the couple should be equal to observed expenditures at the HH level: Y * cm Y * cf Y * Prediction errors at the HH level are used to impute prediction errors at the individual level in order to simulate individual expenditures. The simulated share of the poor individual within the HH is then deduced by using the following relation: Min Y ~ Y ~ cm, cf Simulation of a cloud of point where Y ~ cf Is the simulated value of private expenditures for females living in a couple

Concavity Test Abrevaya and Jiang: principle The tets statistic is built at a local level, by counting the number of combinations of tripets which satisfy Jensen inequality. Two ethical rules are used Approach «Needs»: without any control variable Approach «Merits»: in this one income differences are controled Three possible defintions of public expenditures Déf1: minimum: Accomodation (imputed rents), water, electricity. Déf2: Intermédiaire: includes also furnitures. Déf3: Extensive definition: includes also cars expenditures.

DATA All Couples Variables 2876 obs. Household before tax income ( /year) 29873.85 (19950.89) Female s individual income ( /year) 8661.79 (8308.92) Male s individual income ( /year) 17989.39 (12967.32) Household s total expenditures 27353.82 (incl. imputations) (14281.75) Public 1: Housing, water, electricity 7140.68 (2717.86) Public 2: Public1 + furnitures, HH services 9297.91 (4881.20) Public 3: Public2 + Car-related expenditures 13668.72 (8310.27) Women s clothes 435.59 (1559.80) Men s clothes 536.31 (703.39) Unassignable clothes* 370.41 (683.99) Age of household s head 58.40 (16.26) Education level (1 to 5) 2.84 (1.31) Home Ownership 0.70 (0.46) Big city 0.11 (0.31) Medium city 0.62 (0.49) Countryside 0.27 (0.44) Share of Public 1 (% of household expenditures) 29.54 (11.33) Share of Public 2 (% of household expenditures) 36.56 (12.13) Share of Public 3 (% of household expenditures) 50.22 (12.99) Assignable clothes 4.02 (4.84) Couples, consuming clothes and aged 65 or less 886 34570.40 (21792.89) 11005.14 (9071.78) 19946.34 (16008.22) 31758.95 (15487.12)) 7331.53 (2745.38) 9859.14 (5084.55) 15879.38 (8723.92) 804.56 (799.11) 783.50 (907.00) 650.88 (2039.35) 45.70 (13.95) 3.20 (1.37) 0.58 (0.49) 0.13 (0.33) 0.64 (0.48) 0.23 (0.42) 25.53 (9.42) 32.86 (11.02) 48.71 (12.96) 6.75 (5.38) Single women, consuming clothes and aged 65 or less 674 16445.69 (9919.13) 17549.69 (9919.13) 5902.26 (2441.50) 7021.92 (3149.26) 9028.23 4944.64)( 855.95 (931.50) 228.77 (540.34) 42.04 (14.90) 3.44 (1.48) 0.36 (0.48) 0.17 (0.38) 0.70 (0.46) 0.12 (0.33) 36.56 (13.12) 42.47 (13.33) 52.01 (13.14) 6.24 (5.44) Single men consuming clothes and aged 65 or less 497 18681.39 (13287.72) 17728.17 (8487.49) 5388.97 (2342.36) 6272.23 (2924.33) 8918.23 (4939.84) 855.27 (1151.92) 114.60 (570.19) 39.31 (12.21) 3.24 (1.56) 0.32 (0.12) 0.17 (0.38) 0.69 (0.46) 0.13 (0.34) 34.60 (13.57) 39.55 (14.26) 52.73 (14.28) 5.40 (5.16)

Housing Results: public expenditures(g) b/ Public2, full sample n=2876 24000 18000 LINEAR Whathever the Definition of public And whatever the Ethical rule used 12000 6000 0 Household Expenditures 0 14000 28000 42000 56000 70000 Premier concours national d'agrégation de l enseignement supérieur Hélène Couprie

Housing Housing Housing a/ Public1, full sample n=2876 b/ Public2, full sample n=2876 24000 12000 18000 9000 6000 12000 3000 6000 0 Household Expenditures 0 14000 28000 42000 56000 70000 0 Household Expenditures 0 14000 28000 42000 56000 70000 c/ Public3, full sample n=2876 36000 30000 24000 Parameter Std err. T-stat a -0.044710 0.004368-10.23464 b -0.046593 0.007016-6.641392 c 0.065165 0.008481 7.683934 18000 12000 6000 0 Household Expenditures 0 14000 28000 42000 56000 70000 Endogeneity Correction Coefficient (ρ) Effect of Inequality in individual incomes (γ Parameter Std err. T-stat a -2536.082 429.1858-5.90905 b -3170.676 1511.035-2.09835 c 1761.189 836.4001 2.10568

Public expenditures concavity test Needs Public 1 M-stat S-stat P-value (concavit y) P-value (linearit y) Merit M-stat S-stat P-value (concavit y) P-value (linearit y) [0-70000+[ 2.0488 2.1946 0.3789 0.4846 1.9838 2.4984 0.4287 0.2676 [15000-42000[ 1.8835 1.8835 0.2998 0.5097 1.7799 1.7799 0.3606 0.5911 Public 2 [0-70000+[ 1.5608 2.4540 0.7986 0.2937 1.9853 1.9939 0.4275 0.6644 [15000-42000[ 1.5608 1.5608 0.5145 0.7643 1.9853 1.9853 0.2481 0.4347 Public 3 [0-70000+[ 2.0819 2.0819 0.3551 0.5841 1.5141 1.9714 0.8346 0.6849 [15000-42000[ 1.5760 1.5760 0.5028 0.7528 1.3080 1.5337 0.7154 0.7842

Clothes c) Single females, monotonic 4000 2000 0 Private Expenditures 0 15000 30000

Engel curves partial effects Endogeneity correction term (ρ) Parameter Std Error T-stat Single Females (Figures 3a, 3c) -0.000070 0.010639-0.00658 Single males (Figures 3b, 3d) -0.004880 0.011590-0.42102 Without controlling for individual incomes Couples Females (Figure 4a) -0.018614 0.003717-5.00797 Couples Males (Figure 4b) -0.017891 0.004159-4.30190 Controling for individual incomes Couples Females (Figure 4c) -0.019809 0.003844-5.15374 Couples Males (Figure 4d) -0.018695 0.004306-4.34148 Big city Single Females (Figures 3a, 3c) 352.6543 90.52687 3.89558 Single males (Figures 3b, 3d) 401.5580 120.1803 3.34130 Without controlling for individual incomes Couples Females (Figure 3e) 248.9634 73.56489 3.38427 Couples Males (Figure ) 375.3277 82.31385 4.55971 Controling for individual incomes Couples Females (Figure 4c) 249.9099 73.65475 3.39299 Couples Males (Figure 4d) 373.9847 82.51472 4.53234 Share of individual income in HH income Couples Females (Figure 4c) -24.54546 49.61205-0.49475 Couples Males (Figure 4d) -12.83123 55.57991-0.23086

Female's private expenditures Prediction of female s share (A) Female's share 30000 20000 Egalitarian Sharing 10000 0 Household Private Expenditures 0 20000 40000 60000

Prediction of Private expenditures of individuals living in a couple (def2) Predicted Female Private Expenditures (A) Predicted Male Private Expenditures (B) Sum of Predicted Private Expenditures HH Private Expenditures (observed) mean stderr 9179.60 4882.58 9544.51 4722.69 18724.1 9510.67 20073.0 8114.20 Prediction Errors (C) 1348.91 2180.42 Private Expenditures of the dominated (D) Number of observations 785 8833.93 4612.56 A) Inversion of Female s Engel curve of clothes expenditures. B) Inversion of Male s Engel curve of clothes expenditures. (C) At the household level, prediction errors are the difference between observed private expenditures and predicted private expenditures. (D) At the individual level, private expenditures of the dominated are given by the minimum of predicted private expenditures for the female (A) and for the male (B).

Private expenditures of the 'dominated' Private expenditures of the «poor» individual in the HH (fp) b/ Definition 2 20000 15000 10000 LINEAR Whathever the Definition of Public and Ethical rule 5000 0 Household Private Expenditures 0 20000 40000 P10 P90 Premier concours national d'agrégation de l enseignement supérieur Hélène Couprie

Private expenditures of the 'dominated' Private expenditures of the 'dominated' Private expenditures of the 'dominated' a/ Definition 1 25000 b/ Definition 2 20000 20000 15000 15000 10000 10000 5000 5000 Household Private Expenditures 0 0 10000 20000 30000 40000 50000 P10 P90 c/ Definition 3 15000 10000 5000 Household Private Expenditures 0 0 10000 20000 30000 40000 P10 P90 Parameter Std err. T-stat a -51.87462 76.20604-0.680715 b 107.0113 59.00481 1.813603 c -19.73361 41.47523-0.475793 Household Private Expenditures 0 0 10000 20000 30000 P10 P90 Effect of Inequality in individual incomes (γ)

Needs Merit Definition 1 M-stat S-stat P-value (concavi ty) P-value (linearit y) M-stat P-value S-stat (concavit y) P-value (linearit y) Whole sample 1.9494 1.9494 0.7981 0.9592 2.3418 3.6009 0.3538 0.0273 Between P10 and P90 1.9494 1.9494 0.5176 0.7673 0.7238 3.6009 1.0000 0.0202 Definition 2 Whole sample 2.2499 2.2499 0.4221 0.6660 2.9457 2.9457 0.0686 0.1325 Between P10 and P90 2.2499 2.2499 0.2044 0.4388 2.9457 2.9457 0.0470 0.0919 Definition 3 Private sharing concavity test Whole sample 1.8520 2.1709 0.7943 0.7346 2.1081 6.4056 0.3492 0.0001 Between P10 and P90 1.5495 1.8564 0.5571 0.5604 2.1081 6.4056 0.2222 0.0001

No. There is no apparent link between HH income and intra-household inequalities So, it appears useless to observe individualized incomes to realized comparisons of income distributions in France (ordinal criterion only)). More surprising maybe: CONCLUSION Is intra-household power more balanced in poor households? Wage inequalitites between spouses do not have a singificant effect on expenditures of the assignable good Real need to multiply these kind of analysis in order to check the robustness of such a result

Another related work : Do couples really cooperate? Experimental evidence 100 Couples from Toulouse recruited via articles in the newspapers 5 different games : 1) Prisonner dilemna 2) Risk aversion (Holt and Laury) 3) Bargaining game 4) Distribution choice 5) Joint lotery choice