The Asymptotic Shapley Value for a Simple Market Game

Similar documents
ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Counting Basics. Venn diagrams

Math489/889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Homework 5

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 3

Section 7.5 The Normal Distribution. Section 7.6 Application of the Normal Distribution

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

MA : Introductory Probability

Competitive Outcomes, Endogenous Firm Formation and the Aspiration Core

1 Shapley-Shubik Model

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

Notes, Comments, and Letters to the Editor. Cores and Competitive Equilibria with Indivisibilities and Lotteries

PhD Qualifier Examination

On the Lower Arbitrage Bound of American Contingent Claims

Probability. An intro for calculus students P= Figure 1: A normal integral

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

AUCTIONEER ESTIMATES AND CREDULOUS BUYERS REVISITED. November Preliminary, comments welcome.

Case Study: Heavy-Tailed Distribution and Reinsurance Rate-making

Revenue Equivalence and Income Taxation

Liquidity and Risk Management

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Central Limit Theorem (cont d) 7/28/2006

SYLLABUS AND SAMPLE QUESTIONS FOR MSQE (Program Code: MQEK and MQED) Syllabus for PEA (Mathematics), 2013

Introduction Random Walk One-Period Option Pricing Binomial Option Pricing Nice Math. Binomial Models. Christopher Ting.

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

Arbitrage in Trading Networks

Lecture 8. The Binomial Distribution. Binomial Distribution. Binomial Distribution. Probability Distributions: Normal and Binomial

Efficiency in Decentralized Markets with Aggregate Uncertainty

FURTHER ASPECTS OF GAMBLING WITH THE KELLY CRITERION. We consider two aspects of gambling with the Kelly criterion. First, we show that for

A folk theorem for one-shot Bertrand games

Bargaining and Competition Revisited Takashi Kunimoto and Roberto Serrano

Chapter 7. Sampling Distributions and the Central Limit Theorem

Monetary union enlargement and international trade

Homework Assignments

1 Implied Volatility from Local Volatility

Robust Trading Mechanisms with Budget Surplus and Partial Trade

2011 Pearson Education, Inc

Markov Chains (Part 2)

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Chapter 1. Bond Pricing (continued)

Math-Stat-491-Fall2014-Notes-V

Mathematics in Finance

ECON 214 Elements of Statistics for Economists 2016/2017

Two hours. To be supplied by the Examinations Office: Mathematical Formula Tables and Statistical Tables THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER

The Binomial Distribution

On the existence of coalition-proof Bertrand equilibrium

BROWNIAN MOTION Antonella Basso, Martina Nardon

Discrete Random Variables

Discrete Random Variables

The assignment game: Decentralized dynamics, rate of convergence, and equitable core selection

Week 7. Texas A& M University. Department of Mathematics Texas A& M University, College Station Section 3.2, 3.3 and 3.4

Discrete Random Variables and Probability Distributions. Stat 4570/5570 Based on Devore s book (Ed 8)

The ruin probabilities of a multidimensional perturbed risk model

Rolodex Game in Networks

Math Week in Review #10. Experiments with two outcomes ( success and failure ) are called Bernoulli or binomial trials.

A Decentralized Learning Equilibrium

Solutions of Bimatrix Coalitional Games

Money and Search - The Kiyotaki-Wright Model

There are no predictable jumps in arbitrage-free markets

Extensive-Form Games with Imperfect Information

CIVL Discrete Distributions

2.1 Mathematical Basis: Risk-Neutral Pricing

Chapter 7. Sampling Distributions and the Central Limit Theorem

THE LINK BETWEEN ASYMMETRIC AND SYMMETRIC OPTIMAL PORTFOLIOS IN FADS MODELS

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Chapter 7 1. Random Variables

Probability Distributions for Discrete RV

ECON 214 Elements of Statistics for Economists

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Tutorial 11: Limit Theorems. Baoxiang Wang & Yihan Zhang bxwang, April 10, 2017

Math 489/Math 889 Stochastic Processes and Advanced Mathematical Finance Dunbar, Fall 2007

Incentive Compatibility: Everywhere vs. Almost Everywhere

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium

Money Inventories in Search Equilibrium

Introduction to Probability

Gathering Information before Signing a Contract: a New Perspective

The rth moment of a real-valued random variable X with density f(x) is. x r f(x) dx

Week 2 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Hypothesis Testing and Confidence Intervals

Problem Set 3: Suggested Solutions

Distribution of the Sample Mean

OPTIMAL PORTFOLIO CONTROL WITH TRADING STRATEGIES OF FINITE

Lecture 10: Market Experiments and Competition between Trading Institutions

Term Structure of Credit Spreads of A Firm When Its Underlying Assets are Discontinuous

Finite Memory and Imperfect Monitoring

Valuation of performance-dependent options in a Black- Scholes framework

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.gn] 13 Aug 2018

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Prediction Market Prices as Martingales: Theory and Analysis. David Klein Statistics 157

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

Deriving the Black-Scholes Equation and Basic Mathematical Finance

Simulation Wrap-up, Statistics COS 323

An introduction to game-theoretic probability from statistical viewpoint

Diploma in Business Administration Part 2. Quantitative Methods. Examiner s Suggested Answers

MATH 3200 Exam 3 Dr. Syring

An Adaptive Learning Model in Coordination Games

The Normal Approximation to the Binomial

Equilibrium payoffs in finite games

The Core of a Strategic Game *

Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers

The discounted portfolio value of a selffinancing strategy in discrete time was given by. δ tj 1 (s tj s tj 1 ) (9.1) j=1

Transcription:

The Asymptotic Shapley Value for a Simple Market Game Thomas M. Liggett, Steven A. Lippman, and Richard P. Rumelt Mathematics Department, UCLA The UCLA Anderson School of Management The UCLA Anderson School of Management 11 Westwood Plaza Box 951481 Los Angeles, CA 995-1481, USA Email: tml@math.ucla.edu, slippman@anderson.ucla.edu, drumelt@anderson.ucla.edu December 23, 27 This work was sponsored in part by NSF Grant DMS-3-1795 Keywords Shapley Value; Core; Many Players JEL Classification Numbers: C71 and D41 file name: ETDec237.tex 1

Abstract We consider the game in which b buyers each seek to purchase 1 unit of an indivisible good from s sellers, each of whom has k units to sell. The good is worth to each seller and 1 to each buyer. Using results from Brownian motion, we find a closed form solution for the limiting Shapley value as s and b increase without bound. This asymptotic value depends upon the seller size k, the limiting ratio b/ks of buyers to items for sale, and the limiting ratio [ks b]/ of the excess supply relative to the square root of the number of market participants. 2

1 Introduction In this note we consider a simple market game with many symmetric buyers and sellers and obtain a new asymptotic result regarding the Shapley value of this game. The approach used to establish our result is related to classical limit theorems on convergence to tied down Brownian motion (the Brownian bridge. Shapley and Shubik [5] initiated the program of comparing the core, competitive outcome, and Shapley values in symmetric games with many players. Since then, it has been established that the Shapley value of a game and the competitive outcome are identical with a continuum of non-atomic players ([1]. However, in an atomistic game this equivalence need not hold. This is easily shown by the simple market game described in the next paragraph. In our simple market game each of s sellers possesses k units of an indivisible good to sell, and the good is worth to each seller. There are b buyers each seeking to purchase 1 unit, and the good is worth 1 to each buyer. (Here k,s, and b are positive integers. This is the simplest game that captures trade in a market with many agents. When k > 1, each seller is a store with k units for sale. Suppose that in this market game there are 1 million sellers, 1 millon plus 1 buyers, and k = 1 so each seller has one object to sell. The core and the competitive equilibrium of this game entail a price of 1 because demand for the good exceeds the amount available for sale. If we add just two more sellers, the competitive price drops from 1 to. By contrast, the Shapley value is near 1/2 in both cases. This example exhibits a sharp discontinuity in the competitive equilibrium of this atomistic market game. It also suggests that the Shapley value presents a smooth equilibrium without any such discontinuity. Traditionally, this smoothing effect has been viewed as the natural result of the Shapley value s origins in cooperative game theory, involving the balancing of probabilities of various coalitions being formed. However, recently there has been considerable interest in non-cooperative rationales for the Shapley value. Two influential examples are Gul s [2] model of random bilaterial contracting and Hart and Mas-Colell s [3] model of sequential bilateral offers. While the behavior of the Shapley value is clear when there are a small numbers of players, its behavior is neither well understood nor, in general, easy to compute as the number of players grows very large. Shapley and Shubik [5] analyzed this problem with k = 1 for two special cases and provided asymptotic results. In the first case the ratio b/s of buyers to sellers is fixed at b/s = α > 1: as the number of players increases, the Shapley value converges to 1 and coincides with the core. When b/s = α < 1, the Shapley value converges to, as does the core. In the 3

second case they analyzed, the excess of buyers over sellers is fixed so b/s α = 1: the Shapley value converges to 1/2 regardless of the value of the fixed excess. The core produces a price of 1 when the fixed excess is positive and a price of when it is negative. With a fixed excess of, the core contains all prices in the range [,1]. In this note we show that the asymptotic Shapley value for this market game is not restricted to the values, 1/2, and 1; instead, all values between and 1 are possible. Let M b+s denote the size of the market, and let d ks b denote the excess supply. We provide a closed form expression for the limit of the Shapley value of this game as a function of u lim b,s d/ M. As long as the difference d between units for sale and buyers grows in proportion to the square root of the size of the market, the asymptotic Shapley value (for each unit can take on any intermediate value between and 1. 2 The Closed Form Solution We now present a closed form solution that gives the asymptotic Shapley value as s and b increase to. A particularly interesting aspect of our solution is that for each price p between and 1, there are growth rates for s and b such that the Shapley value converges to p. This stands in stark contrast to the other solution concepts which yield prices of, 1, or an indeterminate price (or all prices between and 1. To begin, set k = 1, where k is the number of units each seller possesses, and let V (b,s denote the Shapley value for a seller in this game (naturally, the value added by all players is v min(b,s so that each buyer s Shapley value is [v sv (b,s]/b. To compute V (b,s, consider those permutations of the players in which a given seller is the i + 1 st player. There is some number j of buyers amongst the first i players in the permutation whence there are i j sellers amongst the first i players. This seller s value added is 1 if the number j of buyers is strictly greater than the number i j of sellers: the seller s value added is 1 if and only if 2j > i. Clearly, the probability that this seller is the i + 1 st player is 1/(. The product ( b( s 1 ( j i j / s+b 1 i of binomial coefficients is the probability that the first i players in a permutation has j buyers and i j sellers given that the i+1 st player is a seller. Consequently, V (b,s can be written as V (b,s = 1 s+b 1 i= ( b s 1 j( i j. 2j>i ( s+b 1 i When the ratio b/ks of buyers b to objects ks available for sale converges to 1, the limit of the Shapley value V (b,s converges to the expression with the integral given given in (1. This is not intuitive. Nevertheless, upon reflection, it is unsurprising that the asymptotic Shapley value 4

is closely related to tied down Brownian motion. To see the connection between V (b,s and tied down Brownian motion, fix k = 1, let b and s be given, define M = b+s, and suppose that b/s converges to α. For each of the ( M s permutations of the M players, think of the player in the j th position as having arrived at time j/m. Define the random variable X j to be 1 when the player in the j th position is a buyer and 1 when the player in the j th position is a seller so that in the limit E(X j = (α 1/(α+1. The Shapley value is the fraction of time that an arriving seller finds S n = M j=1 X j positive. If the X j were independent, then {S n : n =,1,...,M} appropriately scaled would (by Donsker s Theorem converge to Brownian motion. But for each and every permutation of the M players S M = b s and, of course, the X j are not independent. Instead, {S n : n =,1,...,M} converges to tied down Brownian motion. More generally, when each seller is a store of integer size k with k 1, a similar argument to the one above reveals that the expression for V (s,b, the Shapley value for each seller (who has k units for sale, is V (b,s = 1 s+b 1 i= (k+1j>ik Theorem: Suppose b,s so that b/ks α. Then (a If α < 1, then V (b,s. (b If α > 1, then V (b,s k. (c If α = 1, suppose that ( b s 1 j( i j min{k,j (i jk}. ks b u. ( s+b 1 i and V (b,s k 2 2π V (b,s k k2 2π x 2 u 2 + kx 2 e x2 /2 dx if u, (1a x 2 u 2 + kx 2 e x2 /2 dx if u. (1b Proof : We first write V in terms of a simple random walk. Take < p < 1, let X 1,X 2,... be independent identically distributed Bernoulli random variables with P(X i = 1 = p, P(X i = = q = 1 p, 5

and let S m = X 1 + + X m be the corresponding partial sums. Setting N = 1, we see that P(S b = j S N = i = P(S b = jp(s s 1 = i j P(S N = i Therefore, V (b,s = 1 s+b 1 = 1 N + 1 = 1 N i= i= (k+1j>ik ( b j p j q b j( s 1 i j p i j q s 1 i+j ( b s 1 j( i j = ( N = ( i p i q N i N. i min{k,j (i jk}p(s b = j S N = i { } E min{k,(k + 1S b ik};(k + 1S b > ik S N = i, { } E min{k,y (b,s,p};y (b,s,p > S N = (N + 1p dp, (2 where Y (b,s,p = (k + 1S b k (p. Here a is the greatest integer a, and E(X;A means E(X1 A if X is a random variable and A is an event. Note that Y (b,s,p depends on p in two ways explicitly in the second term, and implicitly through the distribution of the X i s in the first. The central limit theorem asserts that S b bp Npq N (, kα, kα + 1 where denotes convergence in distribution and N(µ,σ 2 is the normal distribution with mean µ and variance σ 2. A consequence of this is that the following conditional distribution is also asymptotically normal, but with a smaller variance: ( ( Sb bp kα S N = (N + 1p N, Npq (kα + 1 2. (3 This is a special case of Theorem 4 of [4], but can be checked directly by writing P(S b = l S N = m = P(S b = l P(S N b = m l, P(S N = m and applying Stirling s formula to the binomial coefficients that appear in the second factor above for m = (N + 1p and l = bp + y Npq. Specifically, one obtains P(S N b = m l P(S N = m This factor converts one normal density into the other. kα + 1e y2 (kα+1/2. By (3, the integrand in (2 tends to if α < 1, to k if α > 1, and to kp(z u p/(qk 6

if α = 1, where Z denotes a standard normal random variable. By the bounded convergence theorem, this gives parts (a and (b of the theorem. If α = 1, it gives V (b,s k 1 P(Z u p/(qkdp. Now take u (the case u is similar. An interchange of the order of integration gives 1 as required. P(Z u p/(qkdp = 1 1 2π u p/(qk e x2 /2 dxdp = 1 kx 2 /2 2π u 2 dx + kx 2e x2 Note that V (b,s is the value per seller. The equilibrium market price for each unit of the item is V (b,s/k. In a large market, the closed form solution reveals that when < u <, lim b,s V (b,s/k is strictly increasing in k, with limit 1/2: when there is an excess supply (ks > b, larger stores induce an increase in the equilibrium market price. (The opposite is true when < u <. References [1] Aumann, R. J.: Values of markets with a continuum of traders, Econometrica 46, 611-646 (1975. [2] Gul, F.: Bargaining foundations of Shapley value, Econometrica 57, 81-95 (1991. [3] Hart, S., Mas-Colell, A.: Bargaining and value, Econometrica 64, 357-38 (1996. [4] Liggett, T. M.: An invariance principle for conditioned sums of independent random variables, J. Math. Mech. 18, 559-57 (1968. [5] Shapley, L. S., Shubik, M.: Pure competition, coalitional power, and fair division, Int. Econ. Rev. 1, 337-362 (1969. 7