Can Happiness Data Help Evaluate Economic Policies?

Similar documents
Gross Domestic Product: What an Economy Produces

Measuring a Nation s Income

Lesson 3. John Maynard Keynes and Fiscal Policy

Macroeconomics Sixth Edition

Macroeconomics. Measuring a Nation s Income. Micro vs. Macro. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: N.

In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions

Measuring a Nation s Income

Reading(Guide:( Due(10/5( 25(points( Read(the(attached(article(on(GDP(first(then(Read(Chapter(9(and(complete(the( following(questions( (

Macroeconomics. Measuring a Nation s Income. Income and Expenditure. The Circular-Flow Diagram. Micro vs. Macro. Principles of

Macroeonomics. Measuring a Nation s Income 8/29/2012. Micro vs. Macro. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions: N.

Welcome to Econ20B The Principle of Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics. Economic Indicators. Reading and using global data sources CPI GDP per Capita Unemployment

How our Current Theory of Economics and Practice of Finance have Unsustainability built in. QCEA Brussels November 2013

The Social Costs of Unemployment: Accounting for Unemployment Duration

The study of happiness & the equity premium controversy

JALAL EL OUARDIGHI & FRANCIS MUNIER FACULTÉ DES SCIENCES ECONOMIQUES ET DE GESTION UNIVERSITÉ DE STRASBOURG

EC2032 Macroeconomics & Finance

1 TEN PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS

Intrinsic vs instrumental value of health gains

Economic Changes and Cycles

Trends in Financial Literacy

MACROECONOMIC MEASUREMENT: ENVIRONMENTAL AND SOCIAL DIMENSIONS Macroeconomics In Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Policymaking for Health Care and the Environment. Chapter 19

Southborough Advisory Committee - Review of Cash Reserve Policy. Cash Reserve Policy

Examining the Relationship between Household Satisfaction and Pollution

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Economic Changes and Cycles

Nutrition and productivity

Life Satisfaction and Preferences over Economic Growth and Institutional Quality

Measuring Well-Being: the pursuit of happiness. Brian Gaffney Chief Executive Health Promotion Agency for Northern Ireland

Explaining the Easterlin paradox

Answers to Chapter 10 Review Questions

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

The Knowledge Problem

At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following:

1. Introduction to Macroeconomics

The Effects of Income Losses and Gains on Happiness: Do Temporary Trends Matter? An Exploratory Note

How Is Global Trade Financed? (EA)

Macroeconomics. for AS Level. 2nd Edition. Andrew Threadgould

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Economic Standard of Living

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

Lecture 3 ( 3): April 20 and 22, 2004 Demand, Supply, and Price Stiglitz: pp

14.02 Principles of Macroeconomics Problem Set 1 Solutions Spring 2003

Final. Mark Scheme ECON2. Economics. (Specification 2140) Unit 2: The National Economy. General Certificate of Education (A-level) January 2013 PMT

Female Labor Force Participation Ali Alkhamis

Assessment of Active Labour Market Policies in Bulgaria: Evidence from Survey Data

RICHARD A. EASTERLIN. Is Reported Happiness Five Years Ago Comparable to Present Happiness? A Cautionary Note

How s Life in Costa Rica?

Limits to Growth. Objective for this session. Highlights of Life Conference 2013 Dublin

ECON 1100 Global Economics (Fall 2013) The Distribution Function of Government portions for Exam 3

NATIONAL ACCOUNTS AND THE MEASUREMENT OF WELL-BEING

State what can be inferred and what cannot be inferred from Table 1 with regards to UK s trade balance. [2]

How s Life in South Africa?

Economic Standard of Living

Public spending on health care: how are different criteria related? a second opinion

Introduction to the national economy

Chapter 22. Modern Business Cycle Theory

ECON Drexel University Summer 2008 Assignment 2. Due date: July 29, 2008

Poverty, Inequity and Inequality in New Zealand

Economic Standard of Living

Income Inequality and Poverty (Chapter 20 in Mankiw & Taylor; reading Chapter 19 will also help)

Happiness, self-rated health, and income inequality: Evidence from nationwide surveys in Japan

Macroeconomics. Note: Lectures cannot be reprinted or distributed without express written consent of Erik Hurst. 1

Economic Standard of Living

Social impacts of the inflation

Gross National Happiness as an Answer to the Easterlin Paradox?

Federal Spending to Top a Record $4 Trillion in FY2017

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Deficit Day to Bankruptcy Day

CHAPTER 1 Introduction

Searching for a QALY threshold range: Some research based policy lessons

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

October Virtue in action. Domestic Policy and Election 2004: A Look at Issues that Hit Home. fostering citizenship through character education

CHAPTER 2. A TOUR OF THE BOOK

January 6, 2013 Heads, You Win. Tails, You Win, Too. By ROBERT H. FRANK

Basic Tools of Finance (Chapter 27 in Mankiw & Taylor)

MEASURING WHAT MATTERS TO PEOPLE. Martine Durand OECD Chief Statistician and Director of Statistics

Economics 345 Applied Econometrics

Incorporating Equity Metrics into Regulatory Review. SRA/RFF Conference, June 2009 Matthew D. Adler, University of Pennsylvania Law School

EconS Utility. Eric Dunaway. Washington State University September 15, 2015

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Textbook Media Press. CH 28 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

40 Best Things Ed Seykota Ever Said

1 of 24. Modern Macroeconomics: From the Short Run to the Long Run. 2 of 24. They could not have differed more sharply on economic theory and policy.

Business Cycles II: Theories

Economic Impacts of Basic Income in Korea --Multiplier and Redistribution effect

Julio Videras Department of Economics Hamilton College

YOUGOV / SUNDAY TIMES SURVEY Fieldwork July 19-20, 2007; sample 1,664 For detailed tables, click here

Does a carbon policy really burden low-income families?

Dott. Ing. Gianluca di Castri, FwAICE CCE/ICECA. Equitable payment and performance related payment in engineering and construction 1

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Cambridge Assessment International Education Cambridge International General Certificate of Secondary Education. Published

EC989 Behavioural Economics. Sketch solutions for Class 2

Edexcel (B) Economics A-level

2016 State of Poverty in Ohio Report Release. Philip Cole, Executive Director Ohio Association of Community Action Agencies March 23, 2017

South Carolina s Tax System: Damning with Faint Praise

Transcription:

Can Happiness Data Help Evaluate Economic Policies? Robert MacCulloch Matthew Abel Chair of Economics Graduate School of Management Auckland University Business School Presentation to the NZ Treasury 17 th August, 2016

The goal of public policy should be to increase social welfare, at least according to most economists. In the 18 th Century, Bentham argued that welfare is best measured by summing up the utility or happiness of individuals. But economists have traditionally refrained from trying to measure happiness directly. Instead they have been trained to infer preferences from observed choices - so watch what people do, not listen to what is said.

Happiness researchers depart from this tradition. They are especially interested in self-reports of well-being. For example, the US General Social Survey has a question that asks: Taken all together, how would you say things are these days - would you say that you are very happy, pretty happy, or not too happy? This question is used to proxy for what economists call utility.

Happiness answers are correlated with left versus right frontal brain activity.

How will an economic policy affect social welfare? Politicians can rely solely on their own discretion to make this kind of judgment or they can instead seek the advice of the Treasury, whose traditional approach has been to get estimates of the costs and benefits of the proposed policy. To do so, it would first need to know how behaviour is affected.

An Example: Are the Reserve Bank s Loan to Value Ratio (LVR) restrictions good for social welfare? Restricting the extent of high LVR lending has seen average LVRs in bank mortgage books gradually decline, with the proportion of high LVR mortgage loans on bank balance sheets falling from 21 percent to 14 percent. Grant Spencer, RBNZ, 2015. Maybe behaviour has been influenced by LVR restrictions, but we still don t know if they have raised welfare, which would require using a theory of how the economy works.

Estimating the welfare effects of many policies has proved difficult in particular, ones relating to public goods. A possible solution is to use surveys whereby people are asked questions like: What is the most you would be willing to pay each year through higher taxes, prices, or user fees to improve environmental services? But doubt has been cast on the numbers obtained from these kinds of willingness to pay or contingent valuation surveys, like the $32 billion per year set aside for the preservation of the whooping crane. See Peter Diamond and Jerry Hausman Contingent Valuation: Is Some Number Better than No Number?, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1994.

Example 1: Valuing the Environment A person s level of happiness can be measured and correlated with the level of pollutants in the area where they live and with their income: Happiness i c t = - a. Pollution c t + b. Income i c t + c. Personal Characteristics i c t + ε i c t for individual, i, living in county, c, at time, t This allows Simon Luechinger in Valuing Air Quality Using the Life Satisfaction Approach, Economic Journal, 2009, to calculate the amount of income needed to compensate a person for lower environmental quality. He estimates that an increase in sulphur dioxide emissions of 1 μg/m 3 makes people feel worse off by an amount equivalent to a 1.5% decline in their household income.

Example 2: Cigarette Taxes Should cigarette taxes be increased? Studies often estimate that cigarette purchases fall when prices rise. But will welfare rise or fall? - If people are rational then welfare may fall. Since the cigarettes which they enjoy become more expensive. - However if people have self-control problems then welfare may rise. since higher cigarette taxes may force them to stop smoking, which would be a good thing.

Setting Taxes on Cigarettes - An Answer using Happiness Data Happiness data are available for both smokers and non-smokers in the US and can be correlated with cigarette tax data from the US states. Cigarette tax changes should only affect the happiness of smokers: Happiness i s t = - a. Tax s t - b. Smoker i s t + c. Tax s t * Smoker i s t + d. Personal Characteristics i s t + ε i s t for individual, i, living in state, s, at time, t Jonathan Gruber and Sendhil Mullainathan, BE Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 2005, find that the happiness of smokers is raised, compared to non-smokers, the higher are taxes on cigarettes, presumably by helping them to give up.

Example 3: The Welfare State Can happiness data help inform a government facing the question of whether to cut unemployment benefit generosity? Economists have found evidence suggesting that if unemployment benefits are reduced then the unemployment rate may fall. However, like the smoking example above, the welfare effects are uncertain. There are conflicting forces arguing both sides of this issue, with lots of associated costs and benefits.

For the unemployed On the positive side, to the extent that unemployment falls as a result of benefit cuts, then the unemployed may find it easier to get a job, leaving them happier. On the negative side, those still unable to find work may become more miserable due to a drop in their benefits. For the employed On the positive side, they may spend less time out of work if they lose their job in the future, due to the expected reduction in unemployment related to the benefit cuts. Their taxes may also be reduced. On the negative side, their welfare may drop, since the risk of becoming unemployed in the face of less generous benefits now involves a greater personal cost.

Average Life Satisfaction of the Employed and Unemployed in Europe from 1975 to 2010 across 1,111,826 individuals Happiness 3.30 3.10 2.90 Employed 2.70 2.50 Unemployed 2.30 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Unemployed Employed Source: Di Tella, MacCulloch and Oswald, Review of Economics and Statistics, 2003.

We correlated these happiness responses of Europeans with the level of GDP per capita, unemployment benefits, and the inflation and unemployment rates in their countries across several decades: Happiness i c t = a. GDP per capita c t + b. Benefits c t - c. Unemployment c t - d. Inflation c t + Personal Characteristics i c t + ε i c t for individual, i, living in country, c, at time, t This regression can also be run separately for the unemployed and the employed.

How Happiness is Correlated with GDP per capita, Benefits, and the Unemployment and Inflation rates 2 1.5 1 0.5 0-0.5 GDP per capita Benefit replacement rate Unemployment rate Inflation rate -1-1.5-2 -2.5 Note: The vertical axis reports coefficients from a well-being regression across 271,244 Europeans from 1975 to 1992. Standard errors are 0.4 for GDP, 0.2 for Benefits, 0.7 for Unemployment and 0.5 for Inflation. Well-being is measured by the question: On the whole, are you very satisfied, fairly satisfied, not very satisfied or not at all satisfied with the life you lead?

But will happiness data ever be used in practice? They are already being used in New Zealand, by the government s Pharmaceutical Management Agency. PHARMAC chooses which drugs to subsidise using a number of criteria, one of which is QALYs or Quality Adjusted Life Years. These measurement units weight the time spent in different happiness / quality of life states. When combined with a measure of cost, one can rank drugs according to which are cheap (i.e., low cost per QALY) and which are expensive (i.e., high cost per QALY). We use cost-utility analysis rankings which consider effects on quality of life (e.g., ability to work / perform usual activities, pain / anxiety, mobility) as well as effects on the duration of life. PHARMAC, 2011.

Happiness Data may also be used to measure the welfare effects of many other policies: - Sugar taxes? - Gambling / Sky City pokies?

Problems with Happiness Data 1. Which measure of well-being should one use? (a) evaluation: a global judgment on how close we are to the good life (e.g., On the whole, are you satisfied with the life you lead? ) (b) experience: feelings over short periods of time (e.g., Are you happy these days? ) (c) eudemonic: realization of a person s potential and degree to which their life has meaning and purpose (e.g., To what extent do you get a chance to learn new things? ).

2. Most happiness studies make strong assumptions about cardinality. That is, they assume that one person s happiness score can be compared with another person s. However, it may not be valid to do so: some people may exaggerate their true level of well-being, whereas others may report modestly. For example, Bill Gates may report that an extra $1m increases his well-being by only 0.1 happiness units on a 1-10 scale, whereas a poor person may say it will increases theirs by 8 units. but maybe Gates is just being modest.

3. How does one deal with adaptation?

Happiness Data and Public Policy in NZ Our vision is to be a world-class Treasury working for higher living standards for New Zealanders. By living standards we mean much more than just income or GDP. It includes a broad range of material and non-material factors which impact on well-being. The five key focus areas that Treasury suggests are economic growth, reducing macroeconomic vulnerability, sustainability for the future, growing social capital, and increasing equity... Traditional text book economics assumes: Happiness = f ( GDP ) The Treasury appears to be taking more of a Gross National Happiness approach: Happiness = f ( GDP, equity, sustainability, social cohesion, risk )

Ben S. Bernanke, University of South Carolina Commencement Address, May 8, 2010 on The Economics of Happiness When thinking about the sources of psychological well-being, economists have tended to focus on the promotion of economic, growth. [But] this traditional perspective on happiness is not as narrow and Scrooge-y as you might think. If I were to ask what you value in life besides goods & services you might begin with your health. Well, richer countries have more resources to devote to medical care, good nutrition & sanitation [leading to] generally better health indicators than poor countries. Another thing that most people value is a clean environment. Air & water quality are not included in GDP. But again, rich nations have more resources to devote to maintaining the environment & tend to have better air & water quality than poor & middle-income nations. Again, these linkages, together with the benefits of enjoying a wide variety of goods and services, are the reason that economic policymakers - at the behest of the public - usually put heavy emphasis on job creation and growth.

[GDP] does not allow for the health of our children, the quality of their education, or the joy of their play. It does not include the beauty of our poetry or the strength of our marriages, the intelligence of our public debate or the integrity of our public officials. It measures neither our courage, nor our wisdom, nor our devotion to our country. It measures everything, in short, except that which makes life worthwhile and it can tell us everything about America except why we are proud that we are Americans. Senator Robert Kennedy on GDP

Some Political Economy Issues Lets assume: Gross National Happiness = a. GDP + b. Equity + c. Sustainability + d. Social cohesion + e. Risk How are the weights, a, b, c, d and e, chosen? One view: Politicians are elected to decide what weights should be applied to each of these variables.

Another view: We can use happiness data to run regressions of the form: Gross National Happiness i c t = â. GDP c t + b. Equity c t + ĉ. Sustainability c t +. Personal Characteristics i c t + ε i c t for individual, i, in country, c, and time, t. That is, we can now estimate the weightings, â, b,, which people actually place on these factors and help inform politicians as to the true weights in their country s social welfare function. Weightings differ across countries. For example, whereas European happiness falls when inequality rises, happiness in the US is unaffected. See Alesina, Di Tella and MacCulloch, Inequality and Happiness: Are Europeans and Americans Different?, Journal of Public Economics, 2004. For NZ evidence, see Kevin Jia and Conal Smith, Subjective Wellbeing in NZ.

Conclusion Imagine a government facing some controversial policy questions, like whether it should cut the level of unemployment benefits. Or whether it should raise cigarette taxes. Or spend funds on some form of environmental protection. Will social welfare rise as a result? Will some groups be winners and other groups losers? Happiness data offer a new way to make these kinds of evaluations. These data allow us to track the well-being of the whole population, and also sub-groups like the employed and unemployed, the poor and rich, left-wingers and right-wingers, and correlate the results with relevant policy changes.